What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stock markets? Relative roles of own volatility and...

25
Our reference: ECOFIN 451 P-authorquery-v9 AUTHOR QUERY FORM Journal: ECOFIN Please e-mail or fax your responses and any corrections to: E-mail: [email protected] Article Number: 451 Fax: +353 6170 9272 Dear Author, Please check your proof carefully and mark all corrections at the appropriate place in the proof (e.g., by using on-screen annotation in the PDF file) or compile them in a separate list. Note: if you opt to annotate the file with software other than Adobe Reader then please also highlight the appropriate place in the PDF file. To ensure fast publication of your paper please return your corrections within 48 hours. For correction or revision of any artwork, please consult http://www.elsevier.com/artworkinstructions. Any queries or remarks that have arisen during the processing of your manuscript are listed below and highlighted by flags in the proof. Click on the ‘Q’ link to go to the location in the proof. Location in Query / Remark: click on the Q link to go article Please insert your reply or correction at the corresponding line in the proof Reference(s) given here were noted in the reference list but are missing from the text – please position each reference in the text or delete it from the list. The reference given here is cited in the text but is missing from the reference list – please make the list complete or remove the reference from the text: “Nielsen and Olsen (2001)”, “Hammoudeh et al. (2004)”, “Hammoudeh and Choi (2006)”, “Kodres and Pristsker (1998), Patev and Kanaryan (2003), Karunanayake (2010), Kremer and Nautz (2012), Froot et al. (1992), Choe et al. (1999) and Avramov et al. (2006)”. Please complete and update the reference given here (preferably with a DOI if the publication data are not known): “Zheng and Zuo (2014)”, “Yao et al. (2013)”, “Demirer et al. (2013)”. For references to articles that are to be included in the same (special) issue, please add the words ‘this issue’ wherever this occurs in the list and, if appropriate, in the text. Q1 Please confirm that given names and surnames have been identified correctly. Q2 The country name has been inserted for the affiliations ‘b’ and ‘c’. Please check, and correct if necessary. Q3 Refs. “Kodres and Pristsker (1998), Patev and Kanaryan (2003), Karunanayake (2010), Kremer and Nautz (2012), Froot et al. (1992), Choe et al. (1999) and Avramov et al. (2006)” are cited in the text but not provided in the reference list. Please provide them in the reference list or delete these citations from the text. Q4 Ref. “Hammoudeh and Choi (2006)” is cited in the text but not provided in the reference list. Please provide it in the reference list or delete this citation from the text. Q5 Ref. “Hammoudeh et al. (2004)” is cited in the text but not provided in the reference list. Please provide it in the reference list or delete this citation from the text. Q6 Ref. “Nielsen and Olsen (2001)” is cited in the text but not provided in the reference list. Please provide it in the reference list or delete this citation from the text. Q7 Uncited references: This section comprises references that occur in the reference list but not in the body of the text. Please position each reference in the text or, alternatively, delete it. Any reference not dealt with will be retained in this section. Page 1 of 2

Transcript of What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stock markets? Relative roles of own volatility and...

Our reference: ECOFIN 451 P-authorquery-v9

AUTHOR QUERY FORM

Journal: ECOFIN Please e-mail or fax your responses and any corrections to:

E-mail: [email protected]

Article Number: 451 Fax: +353 6170 9272

Dear Author,

Please check your proof carefully and mark all corrections at the appropriate place in the proof (e.g., by using on-screenannotation in the PDF file) or compile them in a separate list. Note: if you opt to annotate the file with software other thanAdobe Reader then please also highlight the appropriate place in the PDF file. To ensure fast publication of your paper pleasereturn your corrections within 48 hours.

For correction or revision of any artwork, please consult http://www.elsevier.com/artworkinstructions.

Any queries or remarks that have arisen during the processing of your manuscript are listed below and highlighted by flags inthe proof. Click on the ‘Q’ link to go to the location in the proof.

Location in Query / Remark: click on the Q link to goarticle Please insert your reply or correction at the corresponding line in the proof

Reference(s) given here were noted in the reference list but are missing from the text – please positioneach reference in the text or delete it from the list.

The reference given here is cited in the text but is missing from the reference list – please make thelist complete or remove the reference from the text: “Nielsen and Olsen (2001)”, “Hammoudeh et al.(2004)”, “Hammoudeh and Choi (2006)”, “Kodres and Pristsker (1998), Patev and Kanaryan (2003),Karunanayake (2010), Kremer and Nautz (2012), Froot et al. (1992), Choe et al. (1999) and Avramovet al. (2006)”.Please complete and update the reference given here (preferably with a DOI if the publication data arenot known): “Zheng and Zuo (2014)”, “Yao et al. (2013)”, “Demirer et al. (2013)”.For references to articles that are to be included in the same (special) issue, please add the words ‘thisissue’ wherever this occurs in the list and, if appropriate, in the text.

Q1 Please confirm that given names and surnames have been identified correctly.Q2 The country name has been inserted for the affiliations ‘b’ and ‘c’. Please check, and correct if necessary.Q3 Refs. “Kodres and Pristsker (1998), Patev and Kanaryan (2003), Karunanayake (2010), Kremer and

Nautz (2012), Froot et al. (1992), Choe et al. (1999) and Avramov et al. (2006)” are cited in the textbut not provided in the reference list. Please provide them in the reference list or delete these citationsfrom the text.

Q4 Ref. “Hammoudeh and Choi (2006)” is cited in the text but not provided in the reference list. Pleaseprovide it in the reference list or delete this citation from the text.

Q5 Ref. “Hammoudeh et al. (2004)” is cited in the text but not provided in the reference list. Please provideit in the reference list or delete this citation from the text.

Q6 Ref. “Nielsen and Olsen (2001)” is cited in the text but not provided in the reference list. Please provideit in the reference list or delete this citation from the text.

Q7 Uncited references: This section comprises references that occur in the reference list but not in the bodyof the text. Please position each reference in the text or, alternatively, delete it. Any reference not dealtwith will be retained in this section.

Page 1 of 2

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

North American Journal ofEconomics and Finance

What drives herding in oil-rich, developing1

stock markets? Relative roles of own volatility2

and global factors3

Mehmet Balcilara, Rıza Demirerb, Shawkat Hammoudehc,∗Q1

a Department of Economics, Eastern Mediterranean University, via Mersin 10, Famagusta, T. R. North4

Cyprus, Turkey5b Department of Economics & Finance, Southern Illinois University Edwardsville, Edwardsville, ILQ26

62026-1102, United States7c Lebow College of Business, Drexel University, Philadelphia, PA 19104, United States8

9

a r t i c l e i n f o10

11

JEL classification:12

C3213

G1114

G1515

Keywords:16

Herding17

Smooth transition regime switching18

Gulf Arab stock markets19

a b s t r a c t

The main goal of this paper is to formally establish the volatility-herding link in the developing stock markets of the oil-rich GCCcountries by examining how market volatility affects herd behav-ior after controlling for global factors. Using a regime-switching,smooth transition regression model (STR), we find significant evi-dence of herding in all Gulf Arab stock markets, with the marketvolatility being the more paramount factor governing the switchesbetween the extreme states of non-herding and herding. The globalvariables comprised of the U.S. stock market performance, the priceof oil and the US interest rate as well as the risk indexes includingthe CBOE Volatility Index (VIX) and the St. Louis Fed’s FinancialStress Index (FSI) are found to be significant factors governing thetransition to herding states. The findings stress the effect of con-tagion in financial markets, despite the restrictions established bythe GCC policymakers in order to protect their markets.

© 2014 Published by Elsevier Inc.

1. Introduction20

The literature on herd behavior in financial markets has been expanding rapidly in recent years,21

partly due to the prolonged market crisis that was originated in the U.S. financial markets and later22

∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 610 949 0133; fax: +1 215 895 6975.E-mail address: [email protected] (S. Hammoudeh).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.0091062-9408/© 2014 Published by Elsevier Inc.

Original text:
Inserted Text
givenname
Original text:
Inserted Text
surname
Original text:
Inserted Text
givenname
Original text:
Inserted Text
surname
Original text:
Inserted Text
givenname
Original text:
Inserted Text
surname
Original text:
Inserted Text
Famagusta
Original text:
Inserted Text
Cyprus, via Mersin 10,
Original text:
Inserted Text
62026-1102
Original text:
Inserted Text
Business Drexel
Original text:
Inserted Text
19104
Original text:
Inserted Text
Transition Regime Switching
Original text:
Inserted Text
Stock Markets
Original text:
Inserted Text
countries. by
Original text:
Inserted Text
+610 949 0133; fax: +215

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

2 M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

spread to global markets.1 Although earlier studies establish a logical link between market volatility23

and herd behavior (e.g. Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, & Welch, 1992; Christie & Huang, 1995), none of the24

studies in the literature have empirically examined the relative roles of a market’s own volatility and25

external factors in driving market states where herd behavior is observed. This is especially of concern26

for developing markets that are more prone to global effects. Given the suggestion in the literature27

that herd behavior might contribute to market volatility and pricing inefficiencies (e.g. Bikhchandani28

et al., 1992; Nofsinger & Sias, 1999 and more recently Blasco, Corredor, & Ferreruela, 2012), examining29

the relative roles of domestic market volatility and external factors in developing stock markets can30

provide additional valuable insight to policy makers regarding the development of market mechanisms31

to mitigate the negative effects resulting from herd behavior.32

Earlier studies including Christie and Huang (1995) and Chang, Cheng, and Khorana (2000) suggest33

that investors will be more likely to suppress their own beliefs and copy the behavior of others during34

periods of market stress, implying that market volatility is an important factor that may trigger herding.35

Regime-based tests of Balcilar, Demirer, and Hammoudeh (2013) suggest that market states during36

which herd behavior is observed are indeed associated with crashes and extreme volatility periods.37

Focusing on extreme market movements, studies including Kodres and Pristsker (1998), Patev and38

Kanaryan (2003) and Karunanayake (2010) reiterate that bad news and financial crises contribute toQ339

market volatility and herd behavior.2 Similarly, Kremer and Nautz (2012) argue that herding intensity40

depends on stock characteristics including past returns and volatility in an asymmetric way, that is,41

rising stock volatility leads to increased sell herding while buy herding measures decrease. Overall,42

there is sufficient evidence in the literature associating market volatility with herd behavior, with the43

relationship displaying an asymmetric pattern relative to the sign of the market direction. However,44

the mechanism in which a market’s own volatility influences herd behavior is yet to be explored.45

Furthermore, considering the fact that emerging markets are especially prone to global factors, a46

study that formally distinguishes between a market’s own volatility and global factors provides a new47

perspective to investor behavior in developing markets that has not been presented in prior studies.48

There are several contributions of this study. First, we explore the relative roles of a market’s own49

volatility and global factors in driving herd behavior in developing stock markets, with a focus on50

the cash- and oil-rich Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) stock markets – Abu Dhabi, Dubai, Kuwait,51

Oman, Qatar and Saud Arabia. Prior studies in the literature base their tests on the assumption of a52

link between a market’s own volatility and herd behavior without explicitly modeling the volatility-53

herding link in their models. Therefore, this study extends the literature on herding by formally54

exploring the role of a market’s own volatility on herd behavior. Second, this study contributes to the55

literature on emerging markets from a new perspective by exploring the effects of the global financial56

environment on herd behavior after controlling for the local volatility factor in the stock market. Sep-57

arating the local and external factors in the model can provide valuable insight to the mechanism in58

which herd behavior develops in a stock market and aid policy makers in their regulatory tasks. Third,59

unlike prior studies in the literature, we propose a smooth transition regime-switching model where60

regime transitions are modeled in a smoothly time-varying framework as a function of a transition61

variable that governs the switching mechanism. The smooth transition regime-switching approach is62

flexible and switching is not abrupt or sharp as in the Markov switching models as will be explained63

later in the paper. Regime-switching is governed by an unobservable Markov chain process and there-64

fore, one can never be sure whether a particular regime has occurred at a particular time; but only65

assign probabilities to its occurrence. From a practical perspective, the smooth transition regression66

(STR) model provides a more realistic approach to herding tests as heterogeneous agents in the market67

with a diverse set of beliefs are unlikely to respond simultaneously to news or economic signals, thus68

leading to non-synchronized responses. Therefore, the herding tests based on the STR model for these69

markets allow one to gain insight into the factors driving herding behavior from a unique perspective70

1 Philippas et al. (2013), Lee et al. (2013), Yao et al. (2013), Zheng and Zuo (2014) and Demirer, Kutan, and Zhang (2013),among others.

2 The literature also examines the effect on volatility of investors that imitate other investors’ trades (Froot, et al. 1992; Choe,et al., 1999; Avramov, et al. 2006).

Original text:
Inserted Text
Bikhchandani et al., 1992; Christie and Huang
Original text:
Inserted Text
and Sias
Original text:
Inserted Text
Blasco et al.,
Original text:
Inserted Text
Chang et al.
Original text:
Inserted Text
Balcilar et al.
Original text:
Inserted Text
- rich
Original text:
Inserted Text
-
Original text:
Inserted Text
Demirer et al.

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx 3

that has not been done in the literature. The STR model not only accounts for direct effects of the global71

factors on herding behavior, but also provides insight into the variables that govern transitions into72

herding regimes. By doing so, this study contributes to the literature on herding, volatility transmission73

and international asset pricing.74

Our tests yield novel findings regarding the integration of the developing GCC markets with75

global markets with important implications for international diversification. First, herd behavior76

in these markets is a dynamic phenomenon, but not observed in all periods and it evolves in a77

smooth regime-switching fashion. Among the five GCC markets under consideration, Dubai, Kuwait,78

Qatar, and Saudi Arabia are unique with strong and persistent herding almost in all periods. Sec-79

ond, own volatility is the most significant factor driving regime switches between the extreme80

states of non-herding and herding, establishing a direct link between market volatility and herd81

behavior. This finding is consistent with Hammoudeh and Choi (2006) wherein market volatility Q482

in these markets is largely explained by local market factors. Finally, we find that shocks in global83

factors significantly contribute to investor herding in the GCC stock markets, despite the restric-84

tion to access by foreign investors into some of these markets. Global factors including the U.S.85

stock market performance, the price of oil and the US interest rate as well as risk indexes includ-86

ing the VIX and the FSI are found to be significant factors governing the transitions to herding87

states. Interestingly, this evidence comes despite the fact that most GCC markets protect them-88

selves from foreign investors by putting up barriers to entry of foreign investors, partly in the89

hope of reducing the impact of global volatilities on their markets and partly as a matter of90

sovereignty.91

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly summarizes previous studies.92

Section 3 provides description of the data and the benchmark model used in herding tests, while93

Section 4 presents the STR models that are used to test the relative impacts of volatility and global94

effects on herd behavior. Section 5 presents the empirical results and Section 6 concludes the paper95

and discusses implications of the findings.96

2. Previous studies97

Earlier studies in the herding literature start with Christie and Huang (1995) and Chang et al. (2000)98

who report partial evidence of herd behavior in several advanced and developing Asian markets, except99

the U.S. Later studies focus mostly on emerging markets and provide support for herd behavior in a100

number of developing markets including China (Hsieh, Yang, Yang, & Lee, 2011; Lee, Chen, & Hsieh,101

2013; Tan, Chiang, Mason, & Nelling, 2008; Yao, Ma, & He, 2013), Taiwan (Demirer et al., 2010), Gulf102

Arab stock markets (Balcilar et al., 2013), among others. On the other hand, in other recent studies,103

Chiang and Zheng (2010), Economou, Kostakis, and Philippas (2011) and Philippas, Economou, Babalos,104

and Kostakis (2013) report evidence of herd behavior in advanced markets as well. In a recent study,105

Balcilar et al. (2013) propose a regime-switching alternative to the standard testing methodology and106

document evidence of herding in the GCC stock markets during the high and crash volatility states.107

On the other hand, a number of studies on the developing Gulf Arab stock markets have focused108

on the integration of these rapidly developing markets with global markets. Studies including109

Hammoudeh and Li (2008), Yu and Hassan (2008), Marashdeh and Shrestha (2010), Ravichandran110

and Maloain (2010), Cheng, Jahan-Parvar, and Rothman (2010) and more recently Demirer (2013)111

examine the interaction of these markets with global markets from a portfolio diversification point112

of view. The literature in general documents that these markets are partially integrated with global113

markets, suggesting the potential for international diversification benefits for global investors. How-114

ever, the literature on the interaction of these markets with global markets has not yet been extended115

to the herding context. Furthermore, none of the herding tests in the literature differentiate the effect116

of a market’s own volatility from that of global factors in their tests. This paper contributes to the117

literature on developing markets by examining herd behavior in an environment characterized by118

structural breaks, external factor effects and smooth transition regime-switching governed by a tran-119

sition or switch variable. To our knowledge, this is the first study that utilizes formal tests and selection120

criteria to identify the variables that govern the transition between non-herding and herding regimes.121

Original text:
Inserted Text
Tan et al., 2008; Hsieh et al., 2011; Lee et al., 2013 and Yao et al.,
Original text:
Inserted Text
Economou et al.
Original text:
Inserted Text
Philippas et al.
Original text:
Inserted Text
Eitrheim and Terävirta, 1996, Krolzig, 1997, Lakonishok et al., 1992,
Original text:
Inserted Text
Marashdeh et al. (2010),
Original text:
Inserted Text
Cheng et al.

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

4 M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

3. Data and testing methodology122

Several methodologies that utilize price data in herding tests have been proposed in the literature.3123

A popular methodology applied in the herd literature originates from an earlier model by Christie and124

Huang (1995) that was later improved by Chang et al. (2000). The methodology employed in this125

literature focuses on the dispersion of returns in a portfolio of assets with similar characteristics.126

The dispersion of returns in a portfolio is measured by the cross-sectional absolute deviation (CSAD)127

of individual stock returns around the market return, and displays the pattern of return dispersions128

during periods of large market movements. The dispersion of returns is defined as129

CSADt = 1n

n∑

i=1

|Ri,t − Rm,t (1)130

where n is the number of stocks in the portfolio and Ri,t and Rm,t are the return on stock i and the131

market portfolio for period t, respectively. The testing methodology uses the conditional Capital Asset132

Pricing Model (CAPM) as the base model and detects the presence of herd behavior by focusing on133

possible non-linearity in the asset pricing model. For this purpose, Chang et al. (2000) develop the134

following benchmark model135

CSADt = ˛0 + ˛1|Rm,t | + ˛2R2m,t + εt (2a)136

where a significant and negative ˛2 estimate is used as support for the presence of herding behavior.137

This specification, although static in nature, has been applied to herding tests in a number of recent138

studies including Philippas et al. (2013), Lee et al. (2013) and Yao et al. (2013).139

Following prior studies in the literature on the interaction between the GCC stock markets and140

global factors (e.g. Balcilar & Genc, 2010; Khalifa, Hammoudeh, & Otrano, 2013), we augment the141

benchmark model in Eq. (2a) with two global variables, i.e. the oil price and the S&P 500 index, which142

are documented to significantly interact with GCC stock returns to estimate143

CSADt = ˛0 + ˛1|Rm,t | + ˛2R2m,t + ˛3R2

US,t + ˛4R2Ot + εt (2b)144

where RUS,t and RO,t are the returns on the S&P 500 index and US price of WTI crude oil for period t,145

respectively. The augmented model is motivated by a number of studies in the international asset pri-146

cing literature including Stulz (1984, 1995) and Karolyi and Stulz (2003), suggesting that the domestic147

CAPM specification would be incorrect if there are additional risk factors perceived by local investors148

that might contribute to stock returns beyond what can be explained by the domestic market factor149

only. In the case of GCC stock returns, prior studies including Balcilar and Genc (2010) and Khalifa150

et al. (2013) document the presence of global effects on these markets. Therefore, the augmented151

model avoids any specification errors in the domestic pricing model and allows one to examine the152

effects of shocks in global factors on investor behavior in GCC markets. Therefore, in Eq. (2b), estimat-153

ing significant and negative values for ˛3 and ˛4 suggests that large movements in the global factors154

significantly contribute to herding in the GCC markets even after controlling for the domestic market155

factor.156

The dataset consists of weekly closing price series for all stocks listed on five GCC stock exchanges157

including those of Saudi Arabia, Dubai, Abu Dhabi, Kuwait, and Qatar which have consistent and158

adequate data series. These data are sourced from Thompson/Reuters. We use the weekly data in159

our tests because the GCC markets follow different trading days and weekends from the Western160

markets (i.e. Fridays are part of the weekends in the GCC countries and their markets are closed on161

those days). Therefore, in order to avoid any un-synchronization due to differences in trading days,162

we utilize weekly stock returns using Tuesdays as the base day in our weekly return calculations. This163

day avoids the second effect in both groups of markets. As explained earlier, one of the contributions164

of the model used in this analysis is to separate the effect of the market’s own volatility from external165

factors. For this purpose, as will be explained in more detail in Section 4, we also utilize a number of166

3 Demirer, Kutan, and Chen (2010) provide a comparison of the testing methodologies that utilize return data in their tests.

Original text:
Inserted Text
CSAD
Original text:
Inserted Text
i,t and Rm,t
Original text:
Inserted Text
CSAD
Original text:
Inserted Text
Khalifa et al., 2013 and Balcilar and Genc, 2010
Original text:
Inserted Text
CSAD
Original text:
Inserted Text
US,t and RO,t
Original text:
Inserted Text
Demirer et al (2010)

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx 5

Table 1Descriptive statistics.

Mean S.D. Min Max n Sample period

Abu DhabiRm 0.200% 3.230% −13.870% 16.670% 541

5/29/2001–3/6/2012CSAD 6.230% 4.570% 0.430% 27.480% 541�2

t (Rm) 0.0011 0.0009 0.0002 0.0048 541Dubai

Rm 0.120% 4.870% −21.860% 15.510% 4141/13/2004–3/6/2012CSAD 4.900% 2.230% 1.690% 13.680% 414

�2t (Rm) 0.0025 0.002 0.0009 0.0145 414

KuwaitRm 0.180% 2.240% −13.100% 7.960% 819

12/5/1995–3/6/2012CSAD 6.410% 3.740% 1.690% 29.670% 819�2

t (Rm) 0.0005 0.0006 0.0001 0.0068 819Qatar

Rm 0.280% 4.330% −24.050% 14.370% 4591/14/2003–3/6/2012CSAD 3.880% 1.860% 0.740% 16.570% 459

�2t (Rm) 0.0019 0.0023 0.0005 0.0175 459

Saudi ArabiaRm 0.200% 3.480% −23.220% 13.710% 855

1/17/1995–3/6/2012CSAD 3.470% 2.140% 1.070% 22.800% 855�2

t (Rm) 0.0013 0.0021 0.0002 0.0204 855

Global variablesDollar Index Return 0.010% 0.690% −3.950% 3.070% 894

1/17/1995–3/6/2012

S&P 500 Return 0.120% 2.510% −15.770% 12.370% 894Crude oil return (WTI) 0.190% 5.470% −37.010% 25.180% 894FSI 0.037 1.021 −1.256 5.429 894T-Bill Rate (TB3) 3.032 2.079 0.010 6.230 894VIX 21.735 8.408 9.900 67.640 894

Note: This table reports the descriptive statistics for daily market index returns and cross sectional return dispersions acrossall listed stocks in each exchange, respectively. CSAD is the cross-sectional absolute deviation of returns as a measure of returndispersion. n is the number of observations. FSI is the St. Louis Federal Reserve’s Financial Stress Index, TB3 is the U.S. three-month Treasury bill rate, VIX is the CBOE Volatility Index, and WTI is West Texas Intermediate price. The global variables are usedaccording to their stationarity or lack thereof. Bahrain is not included because its data starts in 2009. �2

t (Rm) is the estimate of theconditional return variance estimated as the recursive one-step ahead forecast from a generalized autoregressive conditionalheteroskedasticity (GARCH) model with GARCH (1,1) specification.

global factors that serve as potential transition variables to govern the switching mechanism between167

non-herding and herding market states since these factors may indirectly drive investor sentiment in168

the GCC markets.169

Table 1 provides the summary statistics and the sample periods for each GCC market as well as the170

global factors utilized. We use a generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (GARCH)171

model to estimate the conditional variance values which are later utilized as a proxy for market172

volatility in each GCC stock market.4 In order to generate the market volatility data, we use a recursive173

estimation scheme and obtain the conditional variances, which are denoted as �2t (Rm), at time t. In174

other words, the generated conditional variances are the one-step ahead forecasts from the GARCH175

(1,1) models fitted to observations 1,2, . . ., t − 1. Figs. 1–5 provide the plots of the generated conditional176

volatilities as well as the CSAD values for each GCC market. Interestingly, the figures suggest a close177

association between the return dispersion values and the market volatility estimates, particularly for178

Abu Dhabi and Dubai.179

Examining the return values, all GCC markets yield positive average returns during their sample180

periods, with the highest value for Qatar reflecting its growing oil and natural gas fortunes and the181

lowest for Dubai possibly due to the recent real estate market’s crash and its dependence on tourism.182

The high level of return in GCC markets relative to the S&P 500 index, with the exception of Dubai, is183

4 GARCH (1,1) specification is used in the estimation of conditional volatility terms.

Original text:
Inserted Text
Statistics
Original text:
Inserted Text
Period
Original text:
Inserted Text
5/29/2001-3/6/2012 Rm0.200%3.230%-13.870%
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Dubai1/13/2004-3/6/2012 Rm0.120%4.870%-21.860%
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Kuwait12/5/1995-3/6/2012 Rm0.180%2.240%-13.100%
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Qatar1/14/2003-3/6/2012 Rm0.280%4.330%-24.050%
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Saudi Arabia1/17/1995-3/6/2012 Rm0.200%3.480%-23.220%
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Global Variables1/17/1995-3/6/2012
Original text:
Inserted Text
-3.950%3.070%894
Original text:
Inserted Text
-15.770%
Original text:
Inserted Text
Crude Oil
Original text:
Inserted Text
-37.010%
Original text:
Inserted Text
FSI0.0371.021-1.2565.429894
Original text:
Inserted Text
Original text:
Inserted Text
Note: The
Original text:
Inserted Text
GARCH(1,1)
Original text:
Inserted Text
-1.
Original text:
Inserted Text
GARCH(1,1)

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

6 M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

Fig. 1. CSAD and market volatility used in STR herding model for Abu Dhabi stock market.

associated with relatively higher levels of volatility in general. In the case of return dispersion (CSAD)184

values, stock returns in Saudi Arabia and Qatar display the lowest cross-sectional dispersion possibly185

due to the government’s use of their own domestic stock shares to stabilize their own markets (BalcilarQ5186

et al., 2013; Hammoudeh et al., 2004).187

4. Testing the effects of market volatility and global factors on herding behavior188

One of the weaknesses of the standard testing model employed in the literature is that the model is189

static in nature, with the model parameters assumed to be constant over time. Therefore, the bench-190

mark model in Eq. (2a) and the augmented model in Eq. (2b) fail to capture the dynamic relation191

between market conditions and herd behavior. On the other hand, returns and related time series192

data from financial markets are well known to display nonlinearities which manifest themselves in193

various forms such as asymmetric responses and adjustments during crises and recovery periods,194

responses to market shocks depending on the size and sign of the shocks, etc. A number of studies195

including Tyssedal and Tjostheim (1988), Hamilton (1988), Schwert (1989), Pagan and Schwert (1990),196

Sola and Timmermann (1994), Schaller and van Norden (1997), Kim, Nelson, and Startz (1998), Kim197

and Nelson (1998), and Mayfield (1999) document that nonlinear features in financial data are well198

captured by regime switching models. Following these observations, Balcilar et al. (2013) address the199

shortcoming in the benchmark specification by proposing a regime-based model of return dispersions200

where market regimes are identified in terms of the level of volatility. Their tests indeed distinguish201

Original text:
Inserted Text
Market Volatility
Original text:
Inserted Text
Herding Model for Abu Dhabi Stock Market
Original text:
Inserted Text
Schaller
Original text:
Inserted Text
(1997), Kim et al. (1998)

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx 7

Fig. 2. CSAD and market volatility used in STR herding model for Dubai stock market.

between herding and non-herding market regimes and confirm that herd behavior is observed during202

high market volatility states only.203

Despite its advantages, the Markov-switching (MS) models assume that the regime-switching is204

governed by an unobservable Markov chain process and therefore, one can never be sure whether205

a particular regime has occurred at a particular time; but only assign probabilities to its occurrence.206

Moreover, the MS models imply sharp regime switching, and therefore utilize a limited number (usu-207

ally two) of regimes in their specifications. However, this assumption might be too restrictive when208

the transition between the regimes is not discrete jumps, but rather gradual changes or in the form209

of a continuum of regimes. Another attractive specification that smoothly captures herding or non-210

herding over the different market phases in a consistent way with the return and volatility structure of211

returns is the smooth transition regression (STR) model in the spirit of Teräsvirta and Anderson (1992),212

Granger and Teräsvirta (1993), and Teräsvirta (1994, 1998). The STR models have the advantage of213

allowing for a smooth or gradual change from one state (e.g. non-herding) to another (e.g. herding)214

where the transition can be captured in the form of a continuum of regimes (Teräsvirta, 1998). From215

a practical perspective, one can argue that heterogeneous agents in the market with a diverse set of216

beliefs are unlikely to respond simultaneously to news or economic signals. Furthermore, a number217

of factors including differences in applicable transaction costs, heterogeneity in investors’ objectives218

due to differences in investment horizons, geographical location, and a variety of different risk profiles219

as Peters (1994) suggests, may lead to non-synchronized responses by agents to market shocks. From220

Original text:
Inserted Text
Market Volatility
Original text:
Inserted Text
Herding Model for Dubai Stock Market

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

8 M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

Fig. 3. CSAD and market volatility used in STR herding model for Kuwait stock market.

this perspective, one can argue that a dynamic model of herding which allows for smooth transitions221

or continuum of states between two extreme market states (non-herding and herding states) provides222

a more realistic setup in herding tests and can better capture the role of market factors on transitions223

to herding states.224

Following the arguments presented above, we propose a dynamic regime-switching specification,225

similar to Balcilar et al. (2013) which not only distinguishes between herding and non-herding mar-226

ket regimes but also allows the cross regime switches to be governed by the market volatility and the227

global factors. On the other hand, Balcilar et al. (2013) assumes the constant transition probabilities228

across the market regimes, and therefore does not provide insights to how the market’s own volatility229

drives the transitions across the herding and non-herding regimes. Furthermore, unlike Balcilar et al.230

(2013) we focus on the role of the global factors in driving herding regimes in the developing GCC mar-231

kets and providing insight into the integration of these markets with global markets from a different232

methodological approach, and we additionally examine the role of volatility. Another distinction of this233

paper which is also methodological is the use of an STR model that provides a more realistic approach234

to the herding tests than in the previous paper. The methodology in Balcilar et al. (2013) implies that235

the herding regime may be related to the volatility, but does not allow a direct way to incorporate236

this implication into the model. Additionally, the methodology used here allows a smooth transition237

between the regimes as well as determining how fast the markets adjust toward a new state. The het-238

erogeneous agents in the markets with a diverse set of beliefs are unlikely to respond simultaneously to239

Original text:
Inserted Text
Market Volatility
Original text:
Inserted Text
Herding Model for Kuwait Stock Market
Original text:
Inserted Text
towards a

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx 9

Fig. 4. CSAD and market volatility used in STR herding model for Qatar stock market.

news or economic signals, thus leading to non-synchronized and non-herding responses, and also mak-240

ing the STR model a more realistic approach. Therefore, this study offers several novelties compared to241

Balcilar et al. (2013) and contributes both to the literature on financial integration as well as to herding.242

For this purpose, we estimate the following two-state STR model of the cross-sectional absolutedispersions as warranted by the data

CSADt = [˛0,1 + ˛1,1|Rm,t | + ˛2,1R2m,t + ˛3,1R2

US,t + ˛4,1R2O,t] + [˛0,2 + ˛1,2|Rm,t | + ˛2,2R2

m,t

+ ˛3,2R2US,t + ˛4,2R2

O,t]G(st, �, c) + εt (3)

where εt ∼ iid(0, �2) is a sequence of iid random variables and G(st, � , c) is the transition function243

(bounded by 0 and 1) that controls the regime shift mechanism as a smooth and continuous function244

of the realized values of the continuous transition variable st. In this specification, � > 0 is the slope245

of the transition function that controls the speed of switching and c is the threshold parameter for246

switching between herding and non-herding regimes. Thus, CSAD is modeled to evolve through a247

smooth transition between regimes depending on the sign and magnitude of past realizations of the248

transition variable st. The nonlinearities are obtained by conditioning the regression parameters ˛i,j,249

i = 0, 1, . . ., 4, j = 1, 2 to change smoothly with st in such a way that the variable st is the transition variable250

governing switching from the linear regime (Regime 1) to the nonlinear regime (Regime 2). Indeed,251

st may be set to d-lagged values of a variable, where d indicates the number of periods the transition252

variable leads the switch in regime dynamics. As will be discussed in the empirical results section,253

Original text:
Inserted Text
Market Volatility
Original text:
Inserted Text
Herding Model for Qatar Stock Market
Original text:
Inserted Text
CSAD
Original text:
Inserted Text
]   
Original text:
Inserted Text
t
Original text:
Inserted Text
i,j, i = 0,1,…,4, j = 1,2

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

10 M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

Fig. 5. CSAD and market volatility used in STR herding model for Saudi Arabia stock market. Note: (a) Plots the CSAD definedin Eq. (1). (b) Plots the market volatility, i.e., the conditional standard deviation of market return, which is used as transitionvariable in the STR model in. The shaded regions in (a) and (b) correspond to regimes where herding is supported with negativesignificant coefficients on squared returns in Eq. (3).

we find that regime switches may indeed be quite gradual, heavily driven by the market volatility,254

supporting the description by Christie and Huang (1995) that associates herding with higher market255

volatility.256

Teräsvirta and Anderson (1992) specify the transition function G(·) by using two alternative forms,257

namely the logistic smooth transition regression (LSTR) model and the exponential smooth transition258

regression (ESTR) model. In the LSTR model, G(·) is defined by a logistic function in the form259

G(st, �, c) = [1 + exp {−�(st − c}]−1, � > 0 (4)260

On the other hand, in the ESTR framework, G(·) is captured by an exponential function261

G(st, �, c) = 1 − exp{−�(st − c)2}, � > 0 (5)262

In both equations, � is the speed of transition between regimes and c indicates the halfway point or263

the threshold between the two regimes. Eq. (3) combined with Eq. (4) produces the LSTR model, while264

Eq. (3) combined with Eq. (5) yields the ESTR model. In the STR models, expansion and contraction are265

representations of two different economic phases, but transition between the two regimes is smooth,266

controlled by st (Sarantis, 2001). The LSTR and ESTR models describe different dynamic behavior.267

The LSTR model allows the expansion and contraction regimes to have different dynamics, whereas268

the ESTR model suggests that the two regimes have similar dynamics (Sarantis, 2001). We also take269

Original text:
Inserted Text
Market Volatility
Original text:
Inserted Text
Herding Model
Original text:
Inserted Text
Stock Market. Note: Figure (a) plots
Original text:
Inserted Text
Figure (b) plots
Original text:
Inserted Text
in Figures
Original text:
Inserted Text
, 
Original text:
Inserted Text
, 

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx 11

note that when � → ∞, the model degenerates into the conventional threshold model which has270

discrete instant regime switching. On the other hand, when � → 0, the model degenerates to the271

linear regression model (Teräsvirta & Anderson, 1992). The procedure for constructing an appropriate272

STR model for a specific variable is comprised of three following stages.273

4.1. Testing for linearity274

For a set of transition variables s1t, s2t, . . ., smt one has to first establish whether linearity is rejected275

for any of the transition variables sjt, j = 1, 2, . . ., m. Unfortunately, the linearity restriction that � = 0276

cannot be tested directly since � and c are unidentified and are also nuisance parameters under the null277

hypothesis of linearity. Luukkonen, Saikkonen, and Teräsvirta (1988) suggests taking the Taylor series278

expansion of G(·) with respect to st and constructing LM type tests in the exponential regression equa-279

tions. For the k-th order Taylor expansions (k = 1, 2, 3, 4), the LM tests can be computed as F type tests by280

setting all parameters to zero where skt exists as a variable multiplying xt =

(1, |Rm,t |, R2

m,t, R2US,t, R2

O,t

)′.281

The resulting tests are denoted as LMk for k = 1, 2, 3, 4. Luukkonen et al. (1988) argue that LM1 and LM3282

tests have power against the LSTR alternative, while LM2 and LM4 tests have power against the ESTR283

alternatives. A rejection of any of the denoted LMk tests establishes evidence against the linearity in284

favor of the STR model.285

4.2. Selecting the transition variable286

Teräsvirta (1994) shows that the LM3 tests also have power against the ESTR alternatives and can287

be used to select the best fitting transition variable. The test is performed in the following regression:288

CSADt = ˇ′0xt + ˇ′

1xtst + ˇ′2xts

2t + ˇ′

3xts3t + ut (6)289

where the null of linearity involves the joint restrictions H0 : ˇ1 = ˇ2 = ˇ3 = 0. An appropriate transition290

variable can be determined by first computing the LM3 tests for a set of transition variables s1t, s2t, . . .,291

smt and selecting the transition variable as the one with the smallest p-value of the test.292

4.3. Selecting the form of the transition function293

Having rejected linearity, the choice between the LSTR and ESTR model is then conducted by294

applying the following sequence of nested tests (Teräsvirta, 1994) to Eq. (6)295

H03 : ˇ3 = 0, (7a)296

H02 : ˇ2 = 0|ˇ3 = 0 (7b)297

H01 : ˇ1 = 0|ˇ2 = ˇ3 = 0, (7c)298

A standard procedure, as discussed in Teräsvirta and Anderson (1992), is then followed in the299

selection of the appropriate STR model. There are three possible sequential outcomes:300

i. The rejection of H03 : ˇ3 = 0 implies the selection of the LSTR model.301

ii. If H03 is not rejected, then we proceed to test H02 : ˇ2 = 0|ˇ3 = 0. Rejection of H02 implies the302

selection of the ESTR model.303

iii. If H02 is not rejected, then we proceed to test H01 : ˇ1 = 0|ˇ2 = ˇ3 = 0. A rejection of H01 implies304

selection of the LSTR model.305

As a general selection procedure, if the p-value of the test corresponding to H02 is the smallest, an306

ESTR model is selected; while in all other cases an LSTR model is selected. Escribano and Jordá (1999)307

propose a somewhat different selection procedure based on testing two separate hypotheses within308

Eq. (6) and following equation:309

CSADt = ˇ′0xt + ˇ′

1xtst + ˇ′2xts

2t + ˇ′

3xts3t + ˇ′

4xts4t + ut (7)310

Original text:
Inserted Text
and Anderson
Original text:
Inserted Text
...,
Original text:
Inserted Text
...,
Original text:
Inserted Text
γ = 0
Original text:
Inserted Text
Luukkonen et al.
Original text:
Inserted Text
(
Original text:
Inserted Text
)'
Original text:
Inserted Text
CSAD
Original text:
Inserted Text
where
Original text:
Inserted Text
...,
Original text:
Inserted Text
p-value
Original text:
Inserted Text
β3
Original text:
Inserted Text
β2=β3
Original text:
Inserted Text
0implies
Original text:
Inserted Text
H02:β2=0β3=0.
Original text:
Inserted Text
H01:β1=0β2=β3=0.
Original text:
Inserted Text
p-value
Original text:
Inserted Text
CSAD

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

12 M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

In Escribano and Jordá procedure, H0E : ˇ2 = ˇ4 = 0, and H0L : ˇ1 = ˇ3 = 0 are tested in Eqs. (6) and311

(7), respectively, and LSTR (ESTR) model is selected if the minimum p-value is obtained for H0L (H0E).312

On the other hand, various authors (Eitrheim & Terävirta, 1996; Granger & Teräsvirta, 1993; Sarantis,313

2001; Teräsvirta, 1994) argue that if this sequence of tests is strictly applied, then it may lead to wrong314

conclusions since the higher order terms of the Taylor expansion used in the derivation of these tests315

are ignored. Thus, it is recommended to first compute the p-values for all the F-tests of (i)–(iii) above316

and proceed with the choice of the appropriate STR model based on the lowest p-value or the highest317

F-statistic.318

Regarding the selection of the potential transition variables to be used in the STR specification of319

Eq. (3), we identify six variables that we believe would potentially have a role in driving herd behavior320

in the GCC stock markets:321

1. Domestic market volatility. Following studies that suggest a link between market volatility and herd322

behavior (e.g. Blasco et al., 2012), we include in our models the domestic market volatility (measured323

as the conditional variance of the market return).324

2. Oil price. The economies of GCC markets are highly sensitive to the price of crude oil as most GCC325

countries are net exporters and their stock markets and investments are fueled by oil revenues and326

petrodollars. It is possible that the oil price directly feeds herding tendencies in these markets.327

3. U.S. market return. As experienced during the 2008 global financial crisis, developments in the328

U.S. market can potentially lead to major movements in developing stock markets, either through329

contagion effects or through the activities of international investors. Therefore, it can be argued330

that herd behavior is partially driven by developments in the U.S. stock market.331

4. Three-month T-Bill rate (TB3). GCC countries officially or effectively peg their currencies to the U.S.332

dollar which might lead these markets to be somewhat sensitive to changes in the U.S. T-bill rate.333

Furthermore, the U.S. Treasuries have often been considered a safe haven for global investors dur-334

ing market crisis periods. At times of market stress, investors move away from volatile developing335

markets and currencies and shift their funds into safer assets including the USD-denominated Trea-336

sury securities. Therefore, the T-bill rate can be considered as a variable which may capture this337

sentiment across investors, particularly during periods of market stress. This applies in particular338

to the GCC central banks that park their foreign reserves in those securities.339

5. The dollar exchange rate index. Following a similar argument as in (4), it is possible that movements340

in the value of the U.S. dollar against major currencies reflect investors’ risk appetite as investors341

often move in and out of the USD-denominated assets in response to changes in risk appetite. This342

leads to a possible link between the movements in the U.S. dollar and herd behavior in developing343

markets. The dollar exchange rate has special importance in the GCC countries because they peg344

their currencies officially or effectively to the US dollar.345

6. Global risk measures. These measures encompass risk indexes including the CBOE volatility index346

(VIX), often termed as the fear index, and St. Louis Federal Reserve’s financial stability index (FSI).347

These two indexes are included in the model in order to control for investors’ perception of risk and348

financial distress in the equity market.349

Thus, the set of transition variables in Eqs. (4) and (5) is defined as {USD Return, VIX Return, SP500350

Return, WTI Return, FSI Return, TB3}.5351

5. Empirical results352

In this section, we first start with the LM-STR tests for linearity of CSAD, second we identify the353

appropriate transition variable and finally we proceed with the hypothesis tests to choose between the354

LSTR and ESTR models as explained in the previous section.6 Once we select the appropriate STR model,355

we then estimate this model. The STR models are nonlinear regression models and are estimated with356

5 The unit root tests indicate that TB3 is integrated of degree one, therefore its first difference is used in the estimation.6 The results for the static models in Eqs. (2a) and (2b) are not reported for brevity and are available upon request.

Original text:
Inserted Text
0are
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0L (H
Original text:
Inserted Text
Granger and Teräsvirta, 1993; Teräsvirta, 1994; Eitrheim and Teräsvirta, 1996; Sarantis, 2001
Original text:
Inserted Text
Domestic
Original text:
Inserted Text
volatility.
Original text:
Inserted Text
);2.Oil price.
Original text:
Inserted Text
U.S. market return.
Original text:
Inserted Text
Three
Original text:
Inserted Text
(TB3).
Original text:
Inserted Text
securities5.
Original text:
Inserted Text
index.
Original text:
Inserted Text
(4),
Original text:
Inserted Text
Global risk measures.

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx 13

nonlinear least squares method. As will be discussed later in this section, the static linear models given357

in Eqs. (2a) and (2b) are rejected by the LM-STR tests against the STR alternatives. Furthermore, our358

tests indicate that the p-values of the LM3 are the smallest for all GCC markets when the conditional359

variance �t2(Rm) is used as the transition variable, suggesting that the STR model with market volatility360

as the transition variable provide the best explanatory power as will be discussed later.361

5.1. Testing for linearity and model selection362

We begin our analysis by testing for linearity against STR alternatives with a possible set of potential363

transition variables that may govern the regime-switching mechanism. The F variants of the four LM-364

STR linearity tests, explained in Section 4.1, are reported in Table 2 along with their p-values given in365

parenthesis. In order to establish evidence in favor of a smooth transition regime-switching model,366

one has to reject at least one of the four LM-STR tests. We should note at this point that LM-STR367

tests are based on linearized regression models where the transition function does not directly exist.368

Therefore, it does not matter whether the alternative is an LSTR or ESTR model. However, the LM1 test369

has good power against the LSTR alternative, the LM2 and LM4 tests have good power against ESTR370

alternative, and the LM3 tests have good power against both the LSTR and ESTR alternatives (van Dijk,371

Teräsvirta, & Franses, 2002).372

Once a particular transition variable is selected from the list of the potential variables, the next373

step is to test for the presence of nonlinear dynamics in the data given the transition variable. It is of374

interest to test whether nonlinearity adds any explanatory power to the static, constant coefficient375

model in Eq. (2b). Note that rejection of linearity implies that the herding relationship follows a regime376

switching (nonlinear) form and statistical inferences that are based on linear models are likely to be377

misleading. Therefore, due to the time-varying feature of the herding model, the tests based on the378

assumption of the linear single regime model may fail to detect herding behavior since it may not379

be observed in all periods. If linearity is rejected given a particular transition variable, it implies that380

the selected transition variable sufficiently captures the nonlinearity in return dispersions (CSAD),381

and thus can be interpreted as a variable that governs the smooth regime-switching variable, i.e. a382

variable that leads to a switch from a linear regime (Regime 1) to a nonlinear regime (Regime 2), and383

vice versa.384

The findings reported in Table 2 indicate that all LM-STR tests reject linearity for all GCC markets in385

favor of the STR model, when the market volatility defined as the conditional variance of the market386

return �t2(Rm) is the transition variable. Moreover, the rejection is highly significant with all p-values387

well below the 1% level, implying the presence of strong nonlinearity that can be adequately captured388

by the STR model. For example, in the case of Abu Dhabi which is known for its conservative governance389

of its financial markets, the LM2, LM3 and the LM4 tests reject linearity when the USD and FSI are the390

transition variables, and all STR-LM tests reject linearity when TB3 is the transition variable. This391

finding implies that USD, FSI, and TB3 may also generate smooth regime switching for Abu Dhabi.392

However, in the case of Dubai, which depends heavily on tourism and real estate sectors, only the LM2393

test rejects linearity when USD is the transition variable. However, linearity is not rejected for Dubai394

when SP500, VIX, WTI, TB3 and FSI are used as transition variable. Linearity is rejected by all LM-STR395

tests for Kuwait when USD, SP500, VIX, and WTI are used as transition variables. Similarly, for Qatar,396

all STR-LM tests reject linearity when TB3 is the transition variable, but linearity is not rejected when397

USD, SP500, VIX, WTI, and FSI are used as transition variable. In the case of Saudi Arabia, the LM1 and398

LM2 tests reject linearity, when USD and SP500 are the transition variables when only LM1 rejects399

linearity with TB3 as the transition variable.400

Examining the findings for the other global factors, when USD is the transition variable, linearity is401

rejected for all markets except Qatar whereas when the SP500 index is the transition variable, the tests402

reject linearity for Kuwait and Saudi Arabia. In the case of VIX, this risk measure is found to capture403

regime-switching dynamics only for Kuwait; while WTI captures the same effect for Kuwait and Saudi404

Arabia. Finally, using FSI as the transition variable, linearity is rejected for Abu Dhabi and Saudi Arabia.405

In the case of the US interest rate TB3, we find that this variable captures regime-switching dynamics406

for Abu Dhabi and Qatar, and to some extent for Saudi Arabia.407

Original text:
Inserted Text
(van Dijk et al., 2002).
Original text:
Inserted Text
vice-versa.

Pleasecite

this

articlein

press

as:Balcilar,M

.,etal.Wh

atdrives

herd

ing

inoil-rich

,develop

ing

stockm

arkets?R

elativeroles

ofow

nvolatility

and

globalfactors.N

orthA

merican

Journalof

Economics

andFinance

(2014),http

://dx.d

oi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

AR

TIC

LE

IN P

RE

SS

G M

odelEC

OFIN

4511–23

14M

.Balcilaret

al./North

Am

ericanJournalofEconom

icsand

Financexxx

(2014)xxx–xxx

Table 2LM type tests for STR nonlinearity and model identification for the herding models with global factors.Q11

Transition variable

�t2(Rm) USD SP500 VIX WTI FSI TB3

Abu DhabiLM1 15.1097 [0.0000] 1.2617 [0.2791] 0.3094 [0.9074] 1.1058 [0.3562] 0.5408 [0.7454] 1.5712 [0.1664] 5.9810 [0.0000]LM2 8.3891 [0.0000] 2.4518 [0.0072] 1.0113 [0.4324] 0.9885 [0.4522] 1.3544 [0.1984] 2.5277 [0.0056] 3.8309 [0.0001]LM3 5.6729 [0.0000] 2.2044 [0.0056] 0.9426 [0.5162] 0.7273 [0.7575] 1.2934 [0.2011] 1.8072 [0.0308] 4.2541 [0.0000]LM4 4.4478 [0.0000] 2.0216 [0.0056] 1.0541 [0.3960] 0.7845 [0.7336] 1.1571 [0.2873] 1.8663 [0.0129] 3.3636 [0.0000]H01 15.1097 [0.0000] 1.2617 [0.2791] 0.3094 [0.9074] 1.1058 [0.3562] 0.5408 [0.7454] 1.5712 [0.1664] 5.9810 [0.0000]H02 1.5852 [0.1624] 3.6109 [0.0032] 1.7111 [0.1302] 0.8725 [0.4992] 2.1620 [0.0570] 3.4479 [0.0045] 1.6445 [0.1465]H03 0.3450 [0.8855] 1.6780 [0.1381] 0.8089 [0.5436] 0.2196 [0.9541] 1.1670 [0.3242] 0.3953 [0.8521] 4.8223 [0.0003]H0E 0.6399 [0.7798] 1.6698 [0.0847] 1.2499 [0.2563] 0.5926 [0.8205] 0.4098 [0.9421] 2.2620 [0.0136] 3.0312 [0.0010]H0L 1.1250 [0.3410] 1.2015 [0.2871] 1.3118 [0.2207] 0.7123 [0.7132] 1.6862 [0.0808] 2.3342 [0.0107] 2.1715 [0.0183]

DubaiLM1 3.4075 [0.0050] 0.9441 [0.4522] 0.1710 [0.9732] 0.2584 [0.9355] 0.7655 [0.5751] 0.7575 [0.5809] 0.5673 [0.7251]LM2 2.5372 [0.0057] 1.9508 [0.0374] 0.5484 [0.8553] 0.7723 [0.6556] 0.7150 [0.7105] 0.7088 [0.7164] 1.1206 [0.3451]LM3 2.2963 [0.0039] 1.4672 [0.1141] 0.7629 [0.7189] 0.7415 [0.7420] 0.5849 [0.8867] 0.9090 [0.5542] 0.8675 [0.6014]LM4 1.9746 [0.0077] 1.3250 [0.1586] 0.5965 [0.9154] 0.6547 [0.8698] 0.6127 [0.9038] 0.8018 [0.7120] 0.8215 [0.6876]H01 3.4075 [0.0050] 0.9441 [0.4522] 0.1710 [0.9732] 0.2584 [0.9355] 0.7655 [0.5751] 0.7575 [0.5809] 0.5673 [0.7251]H02 1.6400 [0.1483] 2.9348 [0.0129] 0.9259 [0.4640] 1.2853 [0.2693] 0.6676 [0.6482] 0.6632 [0.6516] 1.6691 [0.1409]H03 1.7658 [0.1188] 0.5234 [0.7586] 1.1894 [0.3136] 0.6859 [0.6344] 0.3367 [0.8906] 1.3041 [0.2613] 0.3787 [0.8633]H0E 1.4834 [0.1431] 1.3311 [0.2115] 0.1169 [0.9996] 0.6424 [0.7773] 0.4663 [0.9114] 0.9057 [0.5279] 1.1940 [0.2931]H0L 2.1286 [0.0215] 0.7724 [0.6555] 0.3721 [0.9583] 0.7588 [0.6686] 0.7197 [0.7060] 0.6566 [0.7646] 0.3250 [0.9743]

KuwaitLM1 3.0492 [0.0098] 3.3586 [0.0052] 4.2773 [0.0008] 3.9663 [0.0015] 3.2771 [0.0062] 1.5991 [0.1579] 0.9795 [0.4292]LM2 2.7932 [0.0021] 2.4745 [0.0064] 4.1982 [0.0000] 2.8495 [0.0017] 2.9136 [0.0014] 1.3961 [0.1771] 0.9748 [0.4638]LM3 2.8805 [0.0002] 2.4748 [0.0015] 2.3758 [0.0023] 2.3874 [0.0022] 2.2898 [0.0035] 1.2579 [0.2229] 0.9295 [0.5305]LM4 2.3405 [0.0008] 2.0089 [0.0056] 2.7171 [0.0001] 2.4767 [0.0004] 2.3351 [0.0008] 1.3594 [0.1343] 0.7579 [0.7658]H01 3.0492 [0.0098] 3.3586 [0.0052] 4.2773 [0.0008] 3.9663 [0.0015] 3.2771 [0.0062] 1.5991 [0.1579] 0.9795 [0.4292]H02 2.5087 [0.0289] 1.5784 [0.1637] 4.0387 [0.0013] 1.7152 [0.1286] 2.5193 [0.0283] 1.1913 [0.3116] 0.9702 [0.4350]H03 1.5229 [0.1801] 2.4313 [0.0336] 0.2827 [0.9227] 1.4472 [0.2050] 1.0408 [0.3923] 0.9817 [0.4279] 0.8408 [0.5209]H0E 1.6730 [0.0827] 1.8286 [0.0522] 1.9980 [0.0309] 2.2645 [0.0130] 2.2880 [0.0120] 1.4682 [0.1465] 0.2421 [0.9919]H0L 1.4956 [0.1361] 1.3403 [0.2044] 1.8238 [0.0529] 1.5290 [0.1242] 1.8438 [0.0498] 0.5965 [0.8175] 0.7255 [0.7008]

QatarLM1 11.6081 [0.0000] 0.6132 [0.6898] 0.0937 [0.9932] 1.1887 [0.3137] 0.9255 [0.4641] 1.6610 [0.1427] 2.1283 [0.0610]LM2 7.2924 [0.0000] 0.8141 [0.6152] 0.4683 [0.9103] 0.8403 [0.5899] 1.1053 [0.3563] 1.4374 [0.1609] 1.9793 [0.0339]LM3 5.3427 [0.0000] 1.1210 [0.3344] 0.4732 [0.9535] 0.7252 [0.7594] 0.7547 [0.7281] 1.1516 [0.3075] 1.9286 [0.0190]LM4 4.3336 [0.0000] 1.2062 [0.2441] 0.6614 [0.8642] 0.6034 [0.9109] 0.7908 [0.7256] 0.9928 [0.4696] 2.0493 [0.0050]

Original text:
Inserted Text
Type Tests for STR Nonlinearity and Model Identification
Original text:
Inserted Text
Herding Models with Global Factors
Original text:
Inserted Text
Abu Dhabi
Original text:
Inserted Text
Saudi ArabiaTransition variable
Original text:
Inserted Text
variableσ2t(Rm)USDSP500VIXWTIFSITB3LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM35.6729 [0.0000]
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0E
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0L
Original text:
Inserted Text
DubaiTransition variableσ2t(Rm)USDSP500VIXWTIFSITB3LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM32.2963 [0.0039]
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0E
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0L
Original text:
Inserted Text
KuwaitTransition variableσ2t(Rm)USDSP500VIXWTIFSITB3LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM32.8805 [0.0002]
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0E
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0L
Original text:
Inserted Text
QatarTransition variableσ2t(Rm)USDSP500VIXWTIFSITB3LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM35.3427 [0.0000]
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM

Pleasecite

this

articlein

press

as:Balcilar,M

.,etal.Wh

atdrives

herd

ing

inoil-rich

,develop

ing

stockm

arkets?R

elativeroles

ofow

nvolatility

and

globalfactors.N

orthA

merican

Journalof

Economics

andFinance

(2014),http

://dx.d

oi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

AR

TIC

LE

IN P

RE

SS

G M

odelEC

OFIN

4511–23

M.Balcilar

etal./N

orthA

merican

JournalofEconomics

andFinance

xxx(2014)

xxx–xxx15

Table 2 (Continued)

Transition variable

�t2(Rm) USD SP500 VIX WTI FSI TB3

H01 11.6081 [0.0000] 0.6132 [0.6898] 0.0937 [0.9932] 1.1887 [0.3137] 0.9255 [0.4641] 1.6610 [0.1427] 2.1283 [0.0610]H02 2.7504 [0.0184] 1.0150 [0.4082] 0.8430 [0.5197] 0.4985 [0.7774] 1.2823 [0.2704] 1.2100 [0.3034] 1.8110 [0.1093]H03 1.3808 [0.2302] 1.7215 [0.1283] 0.4884 [0.7850] 0.5045 [0.7729] 0.0763 [0.9958] 0.5932 [0.7052] 1.7919 [0.1131]H0E 1.6605 [0.0876] 1.4128 [0.1716] 0.7833 [0.6450] 0.3409 [0.9695] 0.8486 [0.5819] 0.8032 [0.6257] 2.2987 [0.0123]H0L 3.8493 [0.0001] 0.9066 [0.5269] 0.8164 [0.6129] 0.5514 [0.8531] 0.8879 [0.5445] 1.2175 [0.2773] 2.6142 [0.0043]

Saudi ArabiaLM1 48.5041 [0.0000] 2.2426 [0.0483] 1.1201 [0.3480] 0.9352 [0.4573] 1.5050 [0.1857] 2.1308 [0.0598] 2.3655 [0.0381]LM2 35.8408 [0.0000] 1.5175 [0.1281] 2.0580 [0.0255] 0.9279 [0.5065] 2.0445 [0.0266] 1.6744 [0.0823] 1.6539 [0.0873]LM3 26.4863 [0.0000] 1.1600 [0.2981] 1.3937 [0.1431] 0.6736 [0.8120] 1.5220 [0.0908] 1.7935 [0.0314] 1.3187 [0.1837]LM4 21.2642 [0.0000] 1.2285 [0.2223] 1.4236 [0.1026] 0.5683 [0.9349] 1.2674 [0.1925] 2.0761 [0.0038] 1.1245 [0.3177]H01 48.5041 [0.0000] 2.2426 [0.0483] 1.1201 [0.3480] 0.9352 [0.4573] 1.5050 [0.1857] 2.1308 [0.0598] 2.3655 [0.0381]H02 18.2318 [0.0000] 0.7952 [0.5532] 2.9827 [0.0112] 0.9210 [0.4665] 2.5700 [0.0256] 1.2152 [0.2999] 0.9431 [0.4522]H03 5.7504 [0.0000] 0.4549 [0.8099] 0.0876 [0.9942] 0.1741 [0.9722] 0.4895 [0.7843] 2.0116 [0.0748] 0.6551 [0.6577]H0E 4.1241 [0.0000] 1.2299 [0.2675] 1.6783 [0.0814] 0.5596 [0.8473] 0.8297 [0.6000] 2.5115 [0.0056] 0.7164 [0.7095]H0L 7.1580 [0.0000] 1.3002 [0.2257] 0.7024 [0.7228] 0.1840 [0.9974] 0.9669 [0.4709] 1.8839 [0.0440] 1.1943 [0.2908]

Note: This table reports the F variants of the LM type linearity tests and the p-values given in square brackets, as well as the H01, H02, and H03 tests used in the specification procedures andTeräsvirta (1994); and the H0E and H0L tests used in the procedure of Escribano and Jordá (1999), applied to the global herding model given in Eq. (3). The tests are applied with varioustransition variables’ specifications, which include the conditional variance of the market return (�t

2(Rm), the US dollar exchange rate index return (USD), the S&P 500 stock market indexreturn (SP500), the CBOE Volatility VIX index return (VIX), the West Texas Intermediate crude oil price return (WTI), St. Louis Federal Reserve’s financial stability index return (FSI), andweekly changes in the U.S. 3-month Treasury bill rate.Note: See note to Table 3.

Original text:
Inserted Text
Abu Dhabi
Original text:
Inserted Text
Saudi ArabiaTransition variable
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0E
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0L
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM326.4863 [0.0000]
Original text:
Inserted Text
LM
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0E
Original text:
Inserted Text
H0L
Original text:
Inserted Text
Note:
Original text:
Inserted Text
Trasvirta (1994);
Original text:
Inserted Text
500),the
Original text:
Inserted Text
Note:

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

16 M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

In short, the findings suggest that local market volatility is the only consistent transition variable408

that uniformly rejects linearity for all GCC markets by all LM-STR tests. In the case of global factors409

however, we find that the global factors also contribute to regime switching in GCC markets, but not410

as strong as the local market volatility factor. However, Kuwait and Saudi Arabia are found to be more411

prone to be influenced by global factors. Market volatility, as the most significant transition variable412

explaining regime-switching in all GCC markets, is most likely to be influenced by the changes in413

global factors, thus indirectly reflecting their effects.414

Once nonlinearity is established, we proceed with the selection of the desired transition variable.415

The findings in Table 2 indicate that more than one transition variable can explain the regime-416

switching dynamics in the GCC stock markets. In order to determine the transition variable that417

best explains the regime-switching dynamics, we follow Teräsvirta (1994) and perform the LM3 tests418

in Eq. (6) with the restriction H0 : ˇ1 = ˇ2 = ˇ3 = 0 imposed.7 The variable with the smallest p-value419

or the highest F value is selected as the transition variable that best captures the regime-switching420

dynamics. The reported F test values (p-values) for all potential transition variables are at maximum421

(minimum) uniformly for all GCC markets when the transition variable is the conditional variance of422

the market returns, �t2(Rm). Therefore, we conclude that the market volatility factor best governs the423

regime-switching in all GCC markets, and thus we select it as the transition variable in the rest of our424

analysis.425

Regarding the procedure to determine the form of the transition function G(·) that will be used426

in the herding model, we consider the LSTR form given in Eq. (4) and the ESTR form given in Eq. (5).427

We use the two procedures proposed by Teräsvirta and Anderson (1992) and Escribano and Jordá428

(1999), both explained in Section 4.3, in order to determine the form of the transition function. The429

sequential testing procedure of Teräsvirta and Anderson (1992) selects the ESTR if the F-statistic value430

(the p-value) of the H02 test is the largest (the smallest), and selects the LSTR if the F-statistic value431

(the p-value) of the H01 or H03 test is the largest (the smallest). The results reported in Table 2 have the432

largest F statistic value (the smallest p-value) for the H01 test, uniformly for all GCC markets. Therefore,433

based on the Teräsvirta and Anderson (1992) procedure, the LSTR model is selected for all countries.434

The Escribano and Jordá (1999) procedure confirms this result for all GCC markets except Kuwait for435

which H0E has the smallest p-value and the ESTR model is thus preferred. However, we also choose436

the LSTR model for Kuwait since the p-value of the H01 test is smaller than the p-value of the H0E.437

Therefore, the LSTR model with the smooth transition function given in Eq. (4) is identified as the438

preferred model for all GCC markets.439

In order to further check the robustness of the LM-STR tests, we include in the model several440

combinations of dummies that correspond to spikes in the CSAD values exceeding three standard441

deviations of the mean, with the restriction that no more than 18 dummies will be included in anyQ6442

case.8 None of the combinations of the dummies changes the LM-STR test results. In fact, the inclusion443

of the dummies even enhances the test results in favor of the STR alternatives. The additional LM tests444

using the outlier robust M-estimation method (van Dijk et al., 2002) further suggest that the findings445

in Table 2 are robust. Thus, we conclude that the STR specification for the GCC markets is not spurious446

and corresponds to a true regime-switching model. Once again, the results of the robust tests for each447

country are not included for space considerations and are available upon request.448

Having identified the appropriate STR specification, the parameters of the STR herding model449

described in Eqs. (3) and (5) are estimated using the nonlinear least squares method as the model is450

truly nonlinear in the parameters � and c. The initial estimates of the parameters � and c are obtained451

using a grid search. Given the initial parameter estimates, the BFGS algorithm9 is used to optimize over452

7 Teräsvirta (1994) shows that the LM3 test has power against both the LSTR and ESTR alternatives. Therefore, the form ofthe transition function G(·) does not influence the selection of the transition variable by the LM3 test procedure.

8 It is possible that a regime is spurious and corresponds to few spikes in the data. For instance, Nielsen and Olsen (2001) findthat a third regime for the Danish stock market is a figment of the data which disappears when dummy variables correspondingto few spikes in the data are included. But this is not the case in our STR models which is consistent with the MS models inBalcilar et al. (2013).

9 BFGS refers to the well-known Broyden–Fletcher–Goldfarb–Shanno algorithm.

Original text:
Inserted Text
F- statistic
Original text:
Inserted Text
F- statistic
Original text:
Inserted Text
(van Dijk et al., 2002)
Original text:
Inserted Text
Broyden,-Fletcher-Goldfarb-Shanno

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx 17

Table 3Estimates for the herding models with global factors under smooth transition regime switching.

Abu Dhabi Dubai Kuwait Qatar Saudi Arabia

� 0.0191** (0.0096) 1.9950*** (0.0789) 0.9900*** (0.2384) 8.8650** (3.7720) 1.3250*** (0.2000)c 0.0023*** (0.0003) 0.0015*** (0.0001) 0.0003*** (0.0000) 0.0010*** (0.0002) 0.0008*** (0.0001)˛0,1 −0.0769 (0.0537) 0.0028 (0.0037) 0.0109 (0.0095) 0.0148*** (0.0044) 0.0206*** (0.0009)˛0,2 1.1100*** (0.1826) 0.0367*** (0.0029) 0.0465*** (0.0026) 0.0206*** (0.0034) 0.1291*** (0.0376)˛1,1 4.2300*** (1.5390) 0.0486 (0.1514) 0.9072*** (0.2262) 0.0598 (0.1907) 0.6897*** (0.0424)˛1,2 −31.5900*** (5.2450) 0.3288* (0.1729) 0.0835 (0.5106) 0.3293 (0.2185) −2.2380 (1.3770)

Herding coefficients˛2,1 27.2000*** (5.4800) 3.5710*** (1.3650) 0.8953 (5.7520) 5.6880** (2.4670) 24.0900** (12.2800)˛2,2 −24.3900** (10.4300) −4.0620*** (1.4640) −3.1320*** (0.7410) −6.4480** (2.5570) −2.2300*** (0.3400)˛3,1 28.2600*** (5.3020) 2.6660 (2.2520) 4.8960*** (1.1240) 1.2860 (1.5800) −0.2585 (0.4289)˛3,2 −1.3860 (1.8210) −1.9850 (2.1400) −6.5680*** (1.6570) −1.6920 (1.4630) −52.3700** (21.4100)˛4,1 11.3000*** (1.4620) 0.0967 (0.5186) 0.5066* (0.2960) 0.1119 (0.3274) 0.0087 (0.0991)˛4,2 −1.183* (0.6741) −0.0137 (0.5069) −0.8340** (0.3704) −0.1258 (0.3115) 10.8700 (6.8950)

Fit statistics�1 0.89 0.37 0.44 0.37 0.62�2 0.11 0.63 0.56 0.63 0.38n 541 414 819 459 855n1 484 155 364 172 526n2 57 259 455 287 329

SSR 0.7715 0.1322 0.9910 0.0821 0.1866� 0.0382 0.0181 0.0350 0.0136 0.0149�(st) 0.0009 0.0020 0.0006 0.0023 0.0021AIC −6.5085 −7.9917 −6.6879 −8.5765 −8.4019BIC −6.4132 −7.8750 −6.6189 −8.4686 −8.3353

Note: This table presents the estimates of the regime switching LSTR model given in Eqs. (3) and (5). The heteroskedasticity andautocorrelation consistent (HAC) standard errors are reported in parentheses, which are obtained using the HAC covariancematrix of Newey and West (1987). n is the total number of observations, nk is the number of observations in regime k, �k ispercentage of observations falling in regime k, SSR is the standard error of the regression, � is the standard deviation of theresiduals, �(st) is the standard deviation of the transition variable st , AIC is the Akaike information criterion, and BIC is the LRtest is the linearity test. Standard errors of the estimates are given in parentheses.

* Significance at the 10% level.** Significance at the 5% level.

*** Significance at the 1% level.

� and c and the remaining parameter estimates, ˛i,j, i = 0, 1, . . ., 4, j = 1, 2 are obtained using ordinary453

least squares at each step of the estimation.454

5.2. Results of the STR model455

Table 3 presents our findings for the global LSTR model specified in Eqs. (3) and (5). The estimates for456

each state clearly differentiate each regime in terms of the sign and size of the coefficients. For example,457

we observe significantly higher intercept estimates in the nonlinear regime (Regime 2), implying458

greater dispersion values during this regime. This suggests that returns are more dispersed during459

periods of high volatility. However, examining the relationship between the return dispersion and460

market return values, we find that the herding coefficients (˛2,2) are all negative and highly significant461

at one percent level, suggesting the presence of herd behavior in all GCC markets during the nonlinear462

regime only.10 The only exception to this is Abu Dhabi for which the coefficient is significant but at the463

5% level.11 Interestingly, the results suggest no evidence of herding during the low volatility regime464

10 The nonlinear regime refers to the high volatility regime during which herding is observed. It can also be called the inefficientor non-equilibrium regime as market prices do not reflect the fundamentals during the bubble/crash periods.

11 As discussed later, regime classification for Abu Dhabi indicates that there are only two long periods, one during 2005 andanother during 2008–2009, when this market is in nonlinear herding. There are a few other short periods of herding but theseare not significantly long. This is also reflected in the parameter estimates only significant at the 5% significance level.

Original text:
Inserted Text
Herding Models with Global Factors under Smooth Transition Regime Switching
Original text:
Inserted Text
** (0.0096)1.9950*** (0.0789)0.9900*** (0.2384)8.8650** (3.7720)1.3250***
Original text:
Inserted Text
*** (0.0003)0.0015*** (0.0001)0.0003*** (0.0000)0.0010*** (0.0002)0.0008***
Original text:
Inserted Text
-0.0769
Original text:
Inserted Text
*** (0.0044)0.0206***
Original text:
Inserted Text
*** (0.1826)0.0367*** (0.0029)0.0465*** (0.0026)0.0206*** (0.0034)0.1291***
Original text:
Inserted Text
***
Original text:
Inserted Text
***
Original text:
Inserted Text
***
Original text:
Inserted Text
-31.5900*** (5.2450)0.3288*
Original text:
Inserted Text
-2.2380 (1.3770)
Original text:
Inserted Text
coefficients
Original text:
Inserted Text
*** (5.4800)3.5710***
Original text:
Inserted Text
** (2.4670)24.0900**
Original text:
Inserted Text
-24.3900
Original text:
Inserted Text
-4.0620
Original text:
Inserted Text
-3.1320
Original text:
Inserted Text
-6.4480
Original text:
Inserted Text
-2.2300
Original text:
Inserted Text
***
Original text:
Inserted Text
***
Original text:
Inserted Text
-0.2585
Original text:
Inserted Text
-1.3860 (1.8210)-1.9850 (2.1400)-6.5680
Original text:
Inserted Text
-1.6920 (1.4630)-52.3700
Original text:
Inserted Text
***
Original text:
Inserted Text
*
Original text:
Inserted Text
-1.183* (0.6741)-0.0137 (0.5069)-0.8340
Original text:
Inserted Text
-0.1258
Original text:
Inserted Text
Fit statistics
Original text:
Inserted Text
329
Original text:
Inserted Text
-6.5085-7.9917-6.6879-8.5765-8.4019BIC-6.4132-7.8750-6.6189-8.4686-8.3353Notes:
Original text:
Inserted Text
σ
Original text:
Inserted Text
. The asterisks ***, ** and * represent significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
Original text:
Inserted Text
i,j, i = 0, 1, ..., 4, j = 1,2
Original text:
Inserted Text
only
Original text:
Inserted Text
2008-2009,

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

18 M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

(Regime 1) with none of the estimates for ˛2,1 estimated to be negative and significant. Therefore,465

we conclude that herding is only present in the nonlinear, high volatility regime. These findings are466

consistent with the suggestion in earlier studies including Christie and Huang (1995), Chang et al.467

(2000) and Bikhchandani and Sharma (2001) without regime switching, that investors will be more468

likely to suppress their own beliefs and copy the behavior of others during periods of market stress.469

In the case of global factors, all of the coefficients representing the global factors (i.e. ˛3,j and ˛4,j,470

j = 1,2) in Eq. (3) are found to be negative in the nonlinear regime, whereas these coefficients are mostly471

positive during the linear regime. This suggests that the global factors indeed contribute to herding472

in GCC markets, however, during the nonlinear regime only. Examining the individual markets, we473

observe the strongest results are for Abu Dhabi, Kuwait, and Saudi Arabia. Both the U.S. stock market474

and the oil price are found to significantly contribute to herd behavior in Kuwait, whereas the oil475

price and the U.S. stock market are found to be significant drivers of herd behavior in Abu Dhabi476

and Saudi Arabia, respectively. Finding U.S. and oil market effects for these three countries is not477

surprising as these three countries are major oil-exporters and prominent members of OPEC, making478

their economies highly sensitive to oil prices. Interestingly, none of the global factors are found to479

contribute to herding in Dubai and Qatar. The findings for Dubai can be explained by its relatively480

lesser and decreasing dependence on oil exports and its greater diversification in the real estate and481

tourism sectors. Similarly, the findings for Qatar may be due to the interventions in this market by the482

government through the Qatar Investment Authority (Balcilar et al., 2013). From the perspective of483

financial integration of these markets with global markets, a significant U.S. market effect in the case of484

Kuwait and Saudi Arabia during the high volatility regime provides partial support for the integration485

of these markets with global markets, despite the limited access allowed for foreign investors. This486

suggests that the U.S. market effect is most likely due to contagion effects and is consistent with Khalifa487

et al. (2013) who find evidence of volatility spillover from the U.S. stock market and the oil market to488

GCC stock markets.489

5.3. Timing, frequency, and persistence of market regimes490

Having found evidence of herding in GCC stock markets and partial evidence on global effects, we491

next examine the frequency, persistence, and time evolution of the herding regime in order to gain492

further insight into investor behavior in these markets. Table 3 reports the number of observations in493

each regime (nj, j = 1, 2) and percentage of observations relative to the total number of observations (�j,494

j = 1, 2) for each regime. The percentage of observations classified as falling into the herding regime495

(Regime 2) are 11%, 63%, 56%, 63%, and 62% for Abu Dhabi, Dubai, Kuwait Qatar, and Saudi Arabia,496

respectively. These results imply that more than half of the observations for all GCC markets except497

Abu Dhabi can be classified as falling into the period during which herding is present. Interestingly,498

only a small percentage of observations belong to the herding regime for Abu Dhabi which is fiscally499

governed more conservatively than the other GCC countries. In general, we can conclude that herding500

is a commonly observed phenomenon for four of the GCC markets, with the exception of Abu Dhabi.501

On the other hand, the frequency of the number of observations does not convey any information502

on the duration and timing of the herding and non-herding regimes. Instead, this information can be503

obtained from the regime classification of the periods. Any period where we have st < c is classified504

in the non-herding region or close to the linear non-herding state. Analogously, all observations with505

st > c are assumed to be in the region of nonlinear herding regime or being closer to it. Whether an506

observation belongs to a particular regime is hard to determine unless G(·) = 0 (complete non-herding)507

or G(·) = 1 (complete herding). This is so as the testing methodology uses the signs of the coefficients508

˛2,1 and ˛2,2 in order to label a regime as a herding or non-herding regime and an observation has509

weights from both regimes at points between G(·) = 0 or G(·) = 1. As explained earlier, the STR models510

have the unique feature of smoothly moving from one extreme state to the other and it is normal511

to expect most of the observations to fall into this smooth transition period. The observations in512

the transition period are generated from the coefficients of both extreme regimes, and thus the STR513

model can be thought of as generating a continuum of regimes from two extreme pole regimes. When514

st > c, the weight given to the herding regime will exceed 50% (G(·) > 0.50), and when st < c, the weight515

given to non-herding regime will exceed 50% (1–G(·) > 0.50). The point where st = c, which means that516

Original text:
Inserted Text
, j = 1,2)
Original text:
Inserted Text
j = 1,2)
Original text:
Inserted Text
belongs to

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx 19

G(·) = 0.50, is the halfway between the two poles of the regimes and the observations will receive 50%517

weight from both poles. Thus, we can say that more than half of the time, observations receive more518

weight from the herding regime which can be interpreted as being closer to the extreme herding519

regime.520

A time evolution of the regime classification may well illustrate both the frequency and the per-521

sistence of regimes. Figs. 1–5 plot the CSAD and market volatility, defined as the square root of the522

conditional variance. These figures allow one to examine the dynamic evolution of the market regimes523

over time. In each panel of Figs. 1–5, the observations that are classified in the herding regime are524

shaded. The shaded regions in these figures indicate strong persistence for the herding regime par-525

ticularly for Dubai and Qatar. The least persistent herding regime is observed in Abu Dhabi. There526

are two-year long herding periods observed for Qatar and Dubai. There are several periods where the527

herding regime is observed continuously for more than two years in Kuwait and Saudi Arabia. All these528

results indicate that the herding regime is not only frequent but also quite persistent.529

Panels (b) in Figs. 1 through 5 display market volatility, along with periods where periods of herding530

is indicated with shades. In Fig. 1(a), for example, we see that herding was a persistent phenomenon531

in Abu Dhabi from early 2005 to mid-2005 and from the end of 2008 to mid-2009. This period cer-532

tainly witnessed several crashes and extreme volatilities. In Dubai, Kuwait, Qatar, and Saudi Arabia, the533

periods 2005–2007, 2008, and 2009–2010 are the three periods where herding is detected continu-534

ously and over long periods, as shown in Figs. 2(b)–5(b), respectively. The figures profoundly illustrate535

that the support for herding is stronger and more persistent for the most volatile periods, confirming536

the earlier finding that market volatility is the main factor that drives herd behavior in these mar-537

kets. Overall, among the five GCC markets, Dubai, Kuwait, Qatar, and Saudi Arabia are unique with538

strong and persistent herding almost in all periods. Herding is less frequent for Abu Dhabi, but occurs539

persistently for some periods during 2005–2009.540

5.4. Speed of adjustment between the non-herding and herding regimes541

In Table 3, we also report the slope parameter of the logistic transition function (�), defined in542

Eq. (5), which controls the speed of adjustment from one regime to another. The case when � = 0543

corresponds to a linear model. Lower values of � indicate slower speed of adjustment between regimes.544

Estimates of all � parameters are all significant at the 5% level even though this parameter is usually545

not estimated precisely. This finding reinforces our results of testing for linearity. Estimates of the546

speed parameter are 0.0191, 0.9900, 1.3250, 1.9950, and 8.8650, respectively, for Abu Dhabi, Kuwait,547

Saudi Arabia, Dubai, and Qatar. The regime switching is the fastest in Qatar and the slowest in Abu548

Dhabi. Even though the frequency of regime switching is small in Abu Dhabi, the speed of adjustment549

is the slowest, implying that the frequency of switching and its speed are independent. As indicated550

above, this emirate is run conservatively, follows a moderate economic development and does not551

allow its sovereign wealth fund the Abu Dhabi Investment authority to invest in its domestic market.552

Fig. 6 plots the value of the transition function, evaluated at the estimated parameter values, against553

the transition variable and marks the threshold c with a vertical line in each plot. The visual inspection554

of the figures clearly reveals the fast switching of the transition function from 0 toward 1 for Qatar and555

how slow it is for Abu Dhabi. Indeed, the range of transition function values never comes close to 1556

for Abu Dhabi. As discussed above, the speed of adjustment parameter controls also how observations557

spread between the two extreme regimes of non-herding and herding. The slower the adjustment558

speed, the more likely for observations to remain in the interim regimes as the system stays longer in559

between the two extremes. In order to illustrate this point, we count the percentage of observations560

where G(·)is only 0.15 points away from either 0 or 1. Indeed, the percentage of observations falling561

in the lower end below the value 0.15 is zero percent for Abu Dhabi, Dubai, Kuwait, and Saudi Arabia562

and 3.7% for Qatar. On the other hand, the percentage of observations falling in the upper end above563

0.95 (close to the extreme herding regime) are 0.0%, 1.9%, 6.5%, 4.7%, and 7.7%, respectively for Abu564

Dhabi, Dubai, Kuwait, Qatar, and Saudi Arabia. This implies that most of the observations indeed fall565

into the transition periods, whereas the system stays closer to the extreme herding regime compared566

to the non-herding regime.567

Original text:
Inserted Text
the Figs
Original text:
Inserted Text
2005-2007, 2008, and 2009-2010
Original text:
Inserted Text
)-5(
Original text:
Inserted Text
2005-2009.
Original text:
Inserted Text
indicates slower
Original text:
Inserted Text
towards

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

20 M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

Fig. 6. Transition function against the transition variable in the smooth transition regime switching herding mode. Note: Eachgraph plots the logistic transition function G(st , � , c) given in Eq. (5), evaluated at the estimated parameter values, against thetransition variable st . The vertical line in gray color in each graph is drawn at the estimated value of the threshold parameter cwhich corresponds to G(.) = 0.50. Above 0.50, the market is in the herding regime.

6. Implications and conclusions568

This paper contributes to the literature on herding and international finance by examining the569

relative roles of a market’s own volatility and global factors in driving herd behavior in developing570

markets, with a focus on the cash- and oil-rich GCC stock markets (Abu Dubai, Dubai, Kuwait, Qatar571

Original text:
Inserted Text
Function against the Transition Variable in the Smooth Transition Regime Switching Herding Mode. Note:
Original text:
Inserted Text
G(.) =
Original text:
Inserted Text
Conclusions
Original text:
Inserted Text
- rich

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx 21

and Saud Arabia). By doing so, this study establishes a direct link between market volatility and herd572

behavior which is only assumed in standard tests. Furthermore, unlike prior studies in the literature,573

we propose a smooth transition regime-switching model (STR) where regime transitions are modeled574

in a smoothly time-varying framework as a function of a transition variable that governs the switching575

mechanism. The STR specification provides a more realistic setup for herding tests as it allows for576

smooth transitions or continuum of states between non-herding and herding states and thus provides577

further insight to the role of market factors on transitions to herding states.578

Our results have four distinct features: First, herd behavior is a dynamic phenomenon but not579

observed in all periods and it evolves in a smooth regime switching fashion. Among the five GCC580

markets, Dubai, Kuwait, Qatar, and Saudi Arabia are unique with strong and persistent herding almost581

in all periods. Herding is less frequent for economically conservative Abu Dhabi, but occurs persistently582

for some periods during 2005–2009. The regime switching is the fastest in the fast growing Qatar and583

the slowest in Abu Dhabi. Even though the frequency of regime switching is small in Abu Dhabi,584

the speed of adjustment is also the slowest, implying that the frequency of switching and its speed585

are independent. The findings, however, show that the regime switching is not swift in all five GCC586

markets, probably due to restrictions on foreign investments and other institutional factors in those587

countries. Second, market volatility is the most significant variable driving regime switching between588

the extreme states of non-herding and herding.589

This finding establishes a direct link between market volatility and herd behavior and is consistent590

with earlier studies including Christie and Huang (1995) and Chang et al. (2000), suggesting that591

investors will be more likely to suppress their own beliefs and copy the behavior of others during592

periods of market stress. Finally, shocks in global factors significantly contribute to investor herding593

in the GCC stock markets despite the restriction to access by foreign investors in some of these markets.594

Global factors including the U.S. stock market performance, the price of oil and the US interest rate595

as well as risk indexes including the VIX and the FSI are found to be significant factors governing the596

transition to herding states. Interestingly, this evidence comes despite the fact that most GCC markets597

protect themselves from foreign investors by putting up barriers to entry of foreign investors, partly598

in the hope of reducing the impact of global volatilities on their markets and partly as a matter of599

sovereignty. This finding stresses the effect of contagion in financial markets despite the restrictions600

established by policy makers in order to protect developing markets.601

Uncited references Q7602

Krolzig (1997), Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1992) and Wermers (1999).603

Acknowledgements604

We would like to thank the Guest Editors, Shawkat Hammoudeh and Duc Kuong Nguyen, the Editor,605

Hamid Beladi, and a reviewer for thoughtful comments and suggestions.606

References607

Balcilar, M., & Genc, I. (2010). The links between crude oil prices and GCC stock markets: The time varying Granger causality608

tests. In EMU Economic Research Center, Working Paper, No: 2010-001.609

Balcilar, M., Demirer, R., & Hammoudeh, S. (2013). Investor herds and regime-switching: Evidence from Gulf Arab stock markets.610

Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 23, 295–321.611

Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., & Welch, I. (1992). A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational612

cascades. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 992–1026.613

Bikhchandani, S., & Sharma, S. (2001). Herd behavior in financial markets: A review. IMF Staff Papers, 47, 279–310.614

Blasco, N., Corredor, P., & Ferreruela, S. (2012). Does herding affect volatility? Implications for the Spanish stock market.615

Quantitative Finance, 12(2), 311–327.616

Chang, E. C., Cheng, J. W., & Khorana, A. (2000). An examination of herd behavior in equity markets: An international perspective.617

Journal of Banking and Finance, 24(10), 1651–1699.618

Cheng, A., Jahan-Parvar, M. R., & Rothman, P. (2010). An empirical investigation of stock market behavior in the Middle East and619

North Africa. Journal of Empirical Finance, 17, 413–427.620

Chiang, T. C., & Zheng, D. (2010). An empirical analysis of herd behavior in global stock markets. Journal of Banking and Finance,621

34(8), 1911–1921.622

Original text:
Inserted Text
2005-2009.
Original text:
Inserted Text
Shrestha, 2010, Schaller and Van Norden, 1997, Van Dijk et al., 2002 and Wermers, 1999
Original text:
Inserted Text
Acknowledgement
Original text:
Inserted Text
tests. EMU
Original text:
Inserted Text
Center Working
Original text:
Inserted Text
&
Original text:
Inserted Text
&

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

22 M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx

Christie, W. G., & Huang, R. D. (1995). Following the pied piper: Do individual returns herd around the market? Financial Analyst623

Journal, 1995(July–August), 31–37.624

Demirer, R., Kutan, A., & Chen, C. (2010). Do investors herd in emerging stock markets? Evidence from the Taiwanese market.625

Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 76, 283–295.626

Demirer, R. (2013). Can advanced markets help diversify risks in Frontier markets? Evidence from Gulf Arab Stock Markets.627

Research in International Business and Finance, 29, 77–98.628

Demirer, R., Kutan, A., & Zhang, H. (2013). Do ADR investors herd? Evidence from advanced and emerging markets. InternationalQ8629

Review of Economics and Finance (in press).630

Economou, F., Kostakis, A., & Philippas, N. (2011). Cross-country effects in herding behaviour: Evidence from four south European631

markets. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 21(3), 443–460.632

Eitrheim, O., & Terävirta, T. (1996). Testing the adequacy of smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of Econometrics,633

74, 59–75.634

Escribano, A., & Jordá, O. (1999). Improved testing and specification of smooth transition regression models. In P. Rothman (Ed.),635

Nonlinear time series analysis of economic and financial data (pp. 289–319). Boston: Kluwer.636

Granger, C. W. J., & Teräsvirta, T. (1993). Modelling nonlinear economic relationships. Oxford: Oxford University Press.637

Hamilton, J. D. (1988). Rational-expectations econometric analysis of changes in regime: An investigation of the term structure638

of interest rates. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 12, 385–423.639

Hammoudeh, S., & Li, H. (2008). Sudden changes in volatility in emerging markets: The case of Gulf Arab stock markets.640

International Review of Financial Analysis, 17, 47–63.641

Hsieh, M., Yang, T., Yang, Y., & Lee, J. (2011). Evidence of herding and positive feedback trading for mutual funds in emerging642

Asian countries. Quantitative Finance, 11(3), 423–435.643

Karolyi, A., & Stulz, R. (2003). Are financial assets priced locally or globally? In G. Constantinides, G. Constantinides, et al. (Eds.),644

Handbook of the economics of finance. Amsterdam: North-Holland.645

Khalifa, A., Hammoudeh, S., & Otrano, E. (2013). Patterns of volatility transmissions within regime switching across GCC and646

global markets. International Review of Economics and Finance, 29, 512–524.647

Kim, C., & Nelson, C. R. (1998). Testing for mean reversion in heteroskedastic data II: Autoregression tests based on Gibbs-648

sampling-augmented randomization. Journal of Empirical Finance, 5, 385–396.649

Kim, C., Nelson, C. R., & Startz, R. (1998). Testing for mean reversion in heteroskedastic data based on Gibbs-sampling-augmented650

randomization. Journal of Empirical Finance, 5, 131–154.651

Krolzig, H. M. (1997). Markov switching vector autoregressions. Modelling, statistical inference and application to business cycle652

analysis. Berlin: Springer.653

Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. V. (1992). The impact of institutional trading on stock prices. Journal of Financial Economics,654

32, 23–43.655

Lee, C., Chen, M., & Hsieh, K. (2013). Industry herding and market states: Evidence from Chinese stock markets. Quantitative656

Finance, 13(7), 1091–1113.657

Luukkonen, R., Saikkonen, P., & Teräsvirta, T. (1988). Testing linearity against smooth transition autoregressive models.658

Biometrika, 75, 491–499.659

Mayfield, E. S. (1999). Estimating the market risk premium Working Paper. Harvard Business School.660

Marashdeh, H., & Shrestha, M. B. (2010). Stock market integration in the GCC countries. International Research Journal of Finance661

and Economics, 37, 102–114.662

Newey, W., & West, K. (1987). A simple positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance663

matrix. Econometrica, 55, 703–708.664

Nofsinger, J., & Sias, R. (1999). Herding and feedback trading by institutional and individual investors. Journal of Finance, 54,665

2263–2295.666

Pagan, A. R., & Schwert, G. W. (1990). Alternative models for conditional stock volatility. Journal of Econometrics, 45, 267–290.667

Peters, E. E. (1994). Fractal market analysis: Applying chaos theory to investment and economics. John Wiley and Sons.668

Philippas, N., Economou, F., Babalos, V., & Kostakis, A. (2013). Herding behavior in REITs: Novel tests and the role of financial669

crisis. International Review of Financial Analysis, 29, 166–174.670

Ravichandran, K., & Maloain, A. M. (2010). Global financial crisis and stock market linkages: Further evidence on GCC market.671

Journal of Money, Investment and Banking, 16, 46–56.672

Sarantis, N. (2001). Nonlinearities, cyclical behaviour and predictability in stock markets: International evidence. International673

Journal of Forecasting, 17, 459–482.674

Schaller, H., & van Norden, S. (1997). Regime switching in stock market returns. Applied Financial Economics, 7, 177–191.675

Schwert, G. W. (1989). Business cycles, financial crises, and stock volatility. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy,676

31, 83–126.677

Sola, M., & Timmermann, A. (1994). Fitting the moments: A comparison of ARCH and regime switching models for daily stock returns.678

London Business School, Centre for Economic Forecasting. Discussion Paper No. DP 6-94.679

Stulz, R. (1984). Pricing capital assets in an international setting: An introduction. Journal of International Business Studies, Winter,680

55–73.681

Stulz, R. (1995). The cost of capital in internationally integrated markets: The case of Nestlé. European Financial Management,682

(March), 11–22.683

Tan, L., Chiang, T. C., Mason, J. R., & Nelling, E. (2008). Herding behavior in Chinese stock markets: An examination of A and B684

shares. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 16, 61–77.685

Teräsvirta, T. (1994). Specification, estimation and evaluation of smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of the American686

Statistical Association, 89, 208–218.687

Teräsvirta, T. (1998). Modeling economic relationships with smooth transition regressions. In A. Ullah, & D. E. A. Giles (Eds.),688

Handbook of applied economic statistics (pp. 507–552). New York: Dekker.689

Teräsvirta, T., & Anderson, H. M. (1992). Characterizing nonlinearities in business cycles using smooth transition autoregressive690

models. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 7, S119–S136.691

Original text:
Inserted Text
Journal, July-August1995
Original text:
Inserted Text
&
Original text:
Inserted Text
Advanced Markets Help Diversify Risks in Frontier Markets
Original text:
Inserted Text
Investors Herd? Evidence from Advanced and Emerging Markets
Original text:
Inserted Text
& Finance2013forthcoming
Original text:
Inserted Text
In Nonlinear Time Series Analysis of Economic and Financial Data
Original text:
Inserted Text
Boston, 1999
Original text:
Inserted Text
an
Original text:
Inserted Text
Herding and Positive Feedback Trading for Mutual Funds in Emerging Asian Countries
Original text:
Inserted Text
Economics of Finance
Original text:
Inserted Text
Mean Reversion in Heteroskedastic Data Based on Gibbs-Sampling-Augmented Randomization
Original text:
Inserted Text
Switching
Original text:
Inserted Text
Statistical Inference and Application to Business Cycle Analysis
Original text:
Inserted Text
Impact
Original text:
Inserted Text
evidence
Original text:
Inserted Text
premium. Working Paper
Original text:
Inserted Text
Market Analysis: Applying Chaos Theory to Investment and Economics
Original text:
Inserted Text
1994
Original text:
Inserted Text
19845573Winter
Original text:
Inserted Text
1995 March

Please cite this article in press as: Balcilar, M., et al. What drives herding in oil-rich, developing stockmarkets? Relative roles of own volatility and global factors. North American Journal of Economicsand Finance (2014), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2014.06.009

ARTICLE IN PRESSG ModelECOFIN 451 1–23

M. Balcilar et al. / North American Journal of Economics and Finance xxx (2014) xxx–xxx 23

Tyssedal, J. S., & Tjostheim, D. (1988). An autoregressive model with suddenly changing parameters and an application to stock692

market prices. Applied Statistics, 37, 353–369.693

van Dijk, D., Teräsvirta, T., & Franses, P. H. (2002). Smooth transition autoregressive models – A survey of recent developments.694

Econometric Reviews, 21, 1–47.695

Wermers, R. (1999). Mutual fund trading and the impact on stock prices. Journal of Finance, 54, 581–622.696

Yao, J., Ma, C., & He, W. P. (2013). Investor herding behaviour of Chinese stock market. International Review of Economics and Q9697

Finance (in press).698

Yu, J. S., & Hassan, M. K. (2008). Global and regional integration of the Middle East and North African (MENA) stock markets.699

Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 48(3), 482–504.700

Zheng, T., & Zuo, H. (2014). Reexamining the time-varying volatility spillover effects: A Markov switching causality approach. Q10701

North American Journal of Economics and Finance (in press).702

Original text:
Inserted Text
models-a survey
Original text:
Inserted Text
forthcoming
Original text:
Inserted Text
The Quarterly
Original text:
Inserted Text
(forthcoming)