The role of the service sector in the process of industrialization

31
THE ROLE OF THE SERVICE SECTOR IN THE PROCESS OF INDUSTRIALIZATION by Mukesh Eswaran and Ashok Kotwal University of British Columbia 1st June, 2000

Transcript of The role of the service sector in the process of industrialization

THE ROLE OF THE SERVICE SECTOR IN THE

PROCESS OF INDUSTRIALIZATION

by

Mukesh Eswaran and Ashok Kotwal

University of British Columbia

1st June, 2000

INTRODUCTION

² Is high agricultural output (per capita) a help ora hindrance to industrialization?

{ The historical evidence is mixed: the Industrial

Revolution in Britain; Canadian development andthe Staple Theory of Growth.

{ Matsuyama (1992) gives examples of agricul-turally deprived countries that became leading in-

dustrial nations

² Trade-o®: high per capita agricultural output im-plies high wages but it also means high domestic

demand for industrial goods.

{ high wages work against the emergence of an in-

dustrial sector that could withstand internationalcompetition.

{ high domestic demand is conducive to the emer-gence of an industrial sector in a closed economy

² The land-surplus countries of North America de-veloped through growth ¯nanced by primary ex-

ports

{ Staple Theory of Growth argues that primary

exports spearhead growth of industrialization

² Matsuyama (1992) provides model capturing thetrade-o® stemming from high agricultural produc-

tivity.

{ in a closed economy, high agricultural output

aids industrialization through the creation of in-

dustrial demand and, once an industrial sector

is created, industrial productivity grows through

learning-by-doing.

{ in an open economy, on the other hand, a coun-

try with comparative advantage in agricultural

goods may never industrialize unless government

protects its nascent industry

² Matsuyama's model does not explain how indus-trialization occured in some countries despite fee-

ble attempts at protecting its nascent industry

(e.g., Canada); his model embodies the linkages

from the demand side but not those on the supply

side

² We build a model that explicitly takes into ac-count the supply side linkages that the Staple

Theory deems important

{ speci¯cally, we focus on the role of the service

sector in the process of industrialization.

{ we focus on non-traded services (e.g., construc-

tion, transportation, distribution, credit and in-

surance)

{ many of these are both consumer and producer

services; `construction' includes the construction

of both homes and factories, `transportation' moves

both passengers and cargo

² Expansion of the service sector bene¯ts the in-dustrial sector by (i) enabling greater specializa-tion and division of labour [Jones and Kierzowski(1988 ), Francois(1990)], and (ii) by lowering thee®ective costs of service inputs to industrial pro-duction; we focus on the latter.

{ the greater the variety of competing services,the lower are the e®ective costs. This is becausegreater variety a®ords greater °exibility to pro-ducers in minimizing the cost of producing a givenlevel of output.

{ income growth, whether as a result of primaryexport growth or some other exogenous reason,will lead to a larger service sector and hence to anindustrial sector that is better able to withstandinternational competition.

² Thus a primary exporting economy can industri-alize without having to resort to protection.

{ this part of our paper can be viewed as a modelof the Staple Theory.

² We show that the three-sector model yields inter-esting results:

(a) growth in the primary sector productivity of

a small open economy (SOE) may lead to the

emergence of a domestic industrial sector

(b) a decline in its terms of trade may lead to the

emergence of a domestic industrial sector even

when comparative advantage remains with agri-

culture

(c) industrialization will be accompanied by a sharp

increase in the welfare of the representative con-

sumer (RC)

(d) between two SOEs, the one with the smaller

land-to-labour ratio could achieve a higher welfare

for its RC.

THE MODEL

² It is assumed that services are non-tradeable, whilethe outputs of agriculture and manufacturing are

tradeable.

² Factor endowments of the LDC: land and labour.Let L0 denote the labour force ( population) and

H0 its stock of land.

{ land distribution is egalitarian: agent owns an

amount (H0=L0).

Consumption Side

² Preferences are non-homothetic

{ consumers spend all of their income on food

(grain) until they have had a su±cient amount,

G, and at higher levels of income they spend all of

their additional income on manufactures (M)and

an aggregate of services (S).

² The preferences over M and S of a consumer

who has had G units of grain to consume is rep-

resented by the utility function:

U(M;S) =M1¡®S®; 0 < ® < 1: (1)

The aggregate S comprises a bundle of n ser-

vices, Si; i = 1;2; :::; n, (such as transportation,

refrigeration, etc.).

² We assume that the aggregator S is given by theconstant elasticity form:

S =

24nX

i=1

(Si)®

351=®

: (2)

{ hereafter, this aggregate input is referred to as

`Service'.

² Grain is the numeraire. Denote the income of

a RC by y. If y � G, the consumer's demand

for the goods, denoted, respectively, by Gd,Md,and SCdi = 0; i = 1;2; :::; n; are

Gd = y; Md = 0; SCdi = 0; i = 1;2; :::; n: (3)

If y > G, the consumer's demand function forgrain is given by Gd = G; those for manufacturesand the various services are given by the solutionto:

maxM;fSig

U(M;S) s:t: y¡G ¸ PmM+nX

j=1

pjSj ;

(4)where Pm is the price of manufactures and pj ; j =1; 2; :::n; is the price of the jth service. Sincemanufactures are tradeable but services are not,Pm is given by the world market while the pj areendogenously determined.

² The consumer's demand functions, SCdi andMd,respectively, can be shown to be:

SCdi =(pi)

¡µPnj=1(pj)

1¡µ®(y ¡G); i = 1; 2; :::; n;

Md = (1¡ ®)(y ¡G)=Pm; (5)

where µ ´ (1¡ ®)¡1.

{ the consumer spends a fraction ® of her incomein excess of G on services and the rest on manu-factures.

Production Side

² Grain production requires land (Hg) and labour(Lg), and the production function is Cobb-Douglas:

Gs = A(Lg)°(Hg)

1¡°; 0 < ° < 1; (6)

where A denotes the total factor productivity inagriculture.

² Manufacturing uses labour (Lm) and Service (Sm)in ¯xed proportions:

Ms = BminfLm; Sm=¹g; (7)

where B is the total factor productivity in man-ufacturing and ¹ (> 0) is the Service-to-labourratio.

² The agricultural and manufacturing sectors areperfectly competitive.

² If w denotes the wage rate of labour, v the land

rental rate, and pS the price of the aggregate

service, the cost function for grain is:

CG(w;v;G) = KGw°v1¡°G; (8)

where KG ´ °¡°(1¡ °)¡(1¡°)=A, and that formanufactures is

CM(w;pS ;M) = (1=B)(w+ ¹pS)M: (9)

² The price, pS, of Service in terms of those of theindividual services is:

pS =

0@nX

i=1

(pi)¡®µ

1A¡1=(®µ)

: (10)

{ we can interpret pS as the price index of all

services.

² If the manufacturing sector produces an outputMs, the conditional demand for Service is ¹Ms=B,

and the conditional demand, SMdi , for service i;

i = 1; 2; :::; n; can be derived as:

SMdi = ¹

Ms

B

(pi)¡µ

³Pnj=1(pj)

¡®µ´1=®: (11)

² Each service is produced by a single producer, andthe service sectors are monopolistically competi-

tive.

{ services are produced using only labour and pro-

duction requires the incurrence of a ¯xed cost, F

(in units of labour), and ¾ units of labour to pro-

duce one unit of any service.

{ the price of each service will not equal MC

because the service industry is monopolistically

competitive.

² If the aggregate income of the economy is Y ,the aggregate demand, SAdi , for service i; i =

1; 2; :::; n; from consumers and manufacturing is

given by

SAdi =

2664®(Y ¡GL0)Pnj=1(pj)

1¡µ +(¹=B)Ms

³Pnj=1(pj)

¡®µ´1=®

3775 (pi)

¡µ:

(12)

² Themonopolistic producer of service i; i = 1;2; :::; n;solves

maxpi

(pi ¡ ¾w)SAdi ¡wF: (13)

{ as is standard in models of monopolistic com-

petition [Dixit and Stiglitz (1977)], each producer

is assumed to take the expression in the square

bracket of (12) as parametric.

{ the optimal price for service i; i = 1; 2; :::; n; is

pi = ¾w=®; (14)

a standard result which says that each producer

marks up the price over MC by the factor (1=®¡1).

{ if LDC does not produce manufactures, the sec-

ond term in (12) will be absent, but the optimal

price of service stays the same.

² The price of the aggregate service, pS, given by(10) reduces to

pS =¾w

®n1=(®µ): (15)

{ the larger the number of services available, the

lower is the price of Service

THE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM

Specialization in Agriculture

² Suppose LDC specializes in agriculture

- consumption of manufactures are ¯nanced by

grain exports, and services are produced only for

consumption.

² Must determine the allocation of labour betweenthe agricultural and service sectors, the factor

prices, the number of services produced, and the

consumption levels of grain, services, and manu-

factures.

² Since only agriculture uses land, we will haveHg =H0 in equilibrium.

{ the remunerations of labour and land, respec-

tively, are given by their marginal products in the

grain sector, which depend on Lg:

w(Lg) = A°(H0=Lg)1¡°; v(Lg) = A(1¡°)(Lg=H0)°

(16)

For a given Lg, the aggregate income in the econ-

omy given by

Y (Lg) = L0w(Lg) +H0v(Lg): (17)

At this income level, the aggregate demand for

labour from the service sector, LdS(Lg; n), is given

by

LdS(Lg; n) = nF +®2

w(Lg)[Y (Lg)¡GL0]: (18)

² The labour market clearing condition may thenbe written as:

Lg +LdS(Lg; n) = L0: (19)

{ the solution to (19) determines the labour em-

ployed in agriculture, Lg(n), as a function of the

number of services being produced.

² To determine the number of services produced,invoke zero pro¯t condition in each service sector.

{ setting pi = ¾w=® for all i in the objective func-

tion of (13), the zero pro¯t condition becomes:

®¾[Y (Lg(n)) ¡GL0]n¾µw(Lg(n))

¡ F = 0: (20)

{ this condition determines the number of ser-

vices, n¤, that will be provided in equilibrium.

{ the per capita income in this equilibrium is given

by y = Y (Lg(w(n¤))=L0. Each agent's con-

sumption of (imported) manufactures and domes-

tic services can now be obtained.

² The supposition that the LDC specializes in agri-culture may be incorrect.

{ if so, at the equilibrium computed above, man-

ufactures can be can pro¯tably produced, that is,

Pm will exceed the LDC's MC of producing man-

ufactures.

{ if this is so, the economy is necessarily diversi-

¯ed and the GE has to be computed anew.

Diversi¯ed Economy

² Let G(Lg) denote the amount of grain producedby LDC when Lg workers are employed in agricul-ture.

{ the di®erence between the production and con-sumption of grain, [G(Lg) ¡ L0G], is exportedand these exports will ¯nance the import of anamount, [G(Lg) ¡ L0G]=Pm, of manufactures.Consumers spend on manufactures a fraction (1¡®) of their income in excess of G, that is, theyconsume an amount (1¡ ®)[Y (Lg) ¡GL0]=Pmof manufactures.

{ the di®erence between domestic consumptionand imports of manufactures yields the amount ofmanufactures, Ms(Lg), that is domestically pro-duced:

Ms(Lg) =n(1¡ ®)[Y (Lg)¡GL0]¡ [G(Lg)¡L0G]

o

(21)where, for brevity, only Lg has been retained asan argument on the left hand side.

² For a diversi¯ed economy, the demand for serviceswill come from consumers and from the manufac-turing sector.

{ if Ms(Lg) is the output of manufactures, theservice sector demand for labour now becomes:

LdS(Lg; n) = nF+®2

w(Lg)[Y (Lg)¡GL0]+¾

Ms(Lg)

Bn1=(®µ):

(22)

² Manufacturing demands labour directly for pro-duction and also indirectly, through its use of ser-vices.

{ if Lm(Lg) is the amount of direct labour de-manded by this sector when its output isMs(Lg),from ¯xed coe±cient production function it fol-lows that Lm(Lg) =Ms(Lg)=B.

² The labour market clearing condition which re-places (19) now is given by

Lg + LdS(Lg; n) +Lm(Lg) = L0: (23)

As before, the solution to the above equation

yields the amount of labour employed in agricul-

ture in terms of the number of services, Lg(n).

² The equilibrium value of n is obtained from the

zero pro¯t condition for service producers:

1=(®µ)¾

"®2(Y (Lg(n))¡GL0)n¾w(Lg(n))

+ ¹Ms(Lg(n))

Bn1=®

#¡F =

(24)

As before, all the endogenous variables of interest

can now be obtained.

RESULTS

² We present some simulation results of the modelset out above. Intuition is robust.

² First consider the e®ects of (exogenous) agricul-tural productivity growth on the GE.

{ Figure 1 (a) depicts the e®ect on the utility

of a RC. Parameters are such that even at low

values of the agricultural TFP, A, the LDC has

comparative advantage in agriculture.

{ as A increases, the RC spends her higher in-

come on imported manufactures and nontraded

services.

{ at a su±ciently high value of A, the economy

acquires comparative advantage in manufactur-

ing.

{ the higher consumer income increases the va-

riety of services produced, as seen from Figure 1

(b).

{ this reduces manufacturing costs, as the greater

variety of services reduces the price of Service

(Fig.1 (c)).

{ cost reduction enables the manufacturing sec-

tor to come into existence, despite international

competition.

{ this contrasts with the result of Matsuyama's

(1992) learning-by-doing model, where agricul-

tural productivity growth in a SOE can only re-

duce the growth rate of industry

{ Figure 1 (d) shows extreme scenario where the

SOE reverses its comparative advantage and be-

comes an industrial exporter.

² Transition is accompanied by a discrete increasein the RC's utility.

{ when the manufacturing sector becomes viable,

its demand for services augments that from con-

sumers, leading to a discrete increase in the va-

riety of the services produced and an increase in

the RC's utility.

{ further e®ect: the larger volume and variety of

services draw away labour from agriculture, in-

creasing its marginal product and the utility of a

consumer.

² Even while exporting manufactures, the SOE con-tinues to produce some agricultural output

{ further increases in agricultural productivity raise

the RC's utility as expected.

{ however, the higher wages shrink the size of

the manufacturing sector (consistent with Mat-

suyama's claim) and thereby reduce the industrial

demand for services. So variety of services pro-

duced declines.

² After the transition, increases in agricultural pro-ductivity increase the domestic consumption of

manufactures while domestic production declines.

So, exports of manufactures decline (Fig. 1 (d)).

{ when agricultural productivity is su±ciently high,

the economy's comparative advantage reverts back

to agriculture.

² The discrete increase in the RC's utility, as shownin Fig. 1 (a), is caused by the emergence ofthe industrial sector rather than by the reversalin comparative advantage.

{ it is very likely that the emergence of a domesticindustrial sector is not accompanied by a reversalof comparative advantage but only by a reductionin the imports of manufactures (Fig. 2(b)).

² When agricultural productivity is su±ciently high,Figure 2(a) shows, paradoxically, that there is adiscrete fall in the consumers' utility.

{ this extreme scenario occurs because the man-ufacturing sector shuts down due to very highwages and there is a discrete decline in the num-ber of (non-traded) services produced, which hurtsconsumers.

{ such an outcome is not possible in standardtrade models of SOEs, where an increase in theproductivity of a domestic sector cannot lower theRC's utility.

² The e®ect of an increase in the relative price ofmanufactures (Pm) on the well being of the RC

is shown in Fig. 3. (Economy with a comparative

advantage in agriculture.)

{ as Pm increases (i.e., the country's terms of

trade decline), the RC's utility ¯rst declines, then

discontinuously increases before continuing to de-

crease again. The discontinuous increase is caused

by the domestic industrialization. Over the entire

range of Pm depicted in the Figure, the economy

is importing manufactures.

{ in the Figure the RC's utility is lower at a point

like Z than at a point like X even though the terms

of trade at Z are less adverse than at X.

{ we cannot infer that a decline in a country's

terms of trade is necessarily to its detriment.

² In a standard trade model, an increase in Pmcould result in an increase in the well-being of

the RC only when it leads to a switch in the coun-

try's comparative advantage. At a point like Z the

country is exporting the agricultural good while at

a point like X it would be exporting manufactures.

{ in our model, by contrast, an increase in Pmcould make the RC better o® despite the fact that

the country continues to export the agricultural

good.

² Figure 4 displays the GE e®ects of increasing land-to-labour ratio.

{ these e®ects are similar to of an agricultural

productivity increase.

{ this peculiar behaviour of the utility of the RC

arises because there exists a range of intermedi-

ate values of the land-to-labour ratio for which

industrialization is viable.

{ industrialization is not possible below this range

because the per capita income is too low, and

above this range because the wage rate is too

high.

{ Sachs-Warner (1995): countries rich in natural

resources tend to grow more slowly than others.

CONCLUSIONS

² In this paper, we have examined how the servicesector impinges on the process of development of

a SOE.

{ the service sector's output is nontraded and pro-

duction exhibits scale economies

{ service sector is a link between consumption and

industrialization.

{ any increase in income leads to an increase in

the consumption demand for, and the variety of,

services; and this leads to a reduction in the cost

of manufacturing goods.

² We have demonstrated that at a high enough levelof agricultural productivity (and hence per capita

income), an industrial sector could become viable

even when the economy remains open.

{ agricultural productivity growth, therefore, can

lead to industrialization.

{ this is our formalization of the Staple Theory of

economic development [Watkins (1963)].

² Wellbeing of a RC can increase through two av-enues: through the increase in the variety (and,

hence, e®ective price) of the services available for

consumption, and the increase in income associ-

ated with a movement of labour out of agricul-

ture.

{ the emergence of an industrial sector adds a

quantum increase in the size of the service sector,

which in turn contributes to a discrete increase in

welfare.

{ the rapid increase in welfare in the East Asian

success stories may be due to causes such as

these.

² The service sector plays the same role in our ¯nd-ing that an adverse change in the terms of trade

for a primary exporting country could result in a

discrete increase in the welfare of a RC.

² We also ¯nd that, between two SOEs, the onewhich is relatively better endowed with land (that

is, with the larger land-to-labour ratio) can be

poorer in per capita terms, ceteris paribus.

² Paper makes stark assumption that industry usesservices as an input but agriculture does not.

{ but it is only essential that industry uses services

more intensively than agriculture.