Packaging Industrialization and Selling It: State-Guaranteed Export Financing and Nationalist...

45
Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”, 1 Packaging Industrialization and Selling It: State-Guaranteed Export Financing and Nationalist Industrialization, 1920-1940 Paper for the History Project “Institutions, Credit, and the State” Conference Ted Fertik * September, 2014 In the eyes of contemporaries and of historians, what characterizes the international economy of the interwar period is above all its distance from the international economy of the years before 1914. 1 The rise of protectionism in the 1920s and its effects on the volume of world trade; the collapse of the Gold Standard and competitive devaluations in the 1930s; the generalized sense that another war was likely and the consequent need for economic policies geared towards national defense: all of these developments could be and frequently were grouped under the heading of “economic nationalism”. 2 In the parlance of contemporary scholars, for whom it has become axiomatic that the pre-war period was a precocious era of globalization, the second Thirty Years War was the 20 th century’s moment of “de-globalization” * Ph.D. Candidate, History Department, Yale University. Thanks to Adam Tooze, Naomi Lamoreaux, Tim Guinnane, Grey Anderson, and Gabe Winant for many helpful brainstorming conversations. All mistakes – and they are surely legion – are the author’s. 1 The most famous statement from the interwar period is J. M. Keynes, The Economic Consequences of the Peace (New York: Harcourt, Brace & Howe, 1920). The most important recently scholarly statements are Kevin H O’Rourke and Jeffrey G Williamson, Globalization and History: The Evolution of a Nineteenth-Century Atlantic Economy (Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press, 1999); Michael D. Bordo, Alan M. Taylor, and Jeffrey G. Williamson, eds., Globalization in Historical Perspective (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2003); Barry Eichengreen, Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996). 2 For representative contemporary reflections, see the views collected in Joseph M. Pavloff, Prosperity; Economic Nationalism or Internationalism (New York: Foreign Policy Association, 1929). For the most thoughtful recent reflection on the varieties of interwar economic nationalism in relation to the world economy, see Henryk Szlajfer, Economic Nationalism and Globalization: Lessons from Latin America and Central Europe (Brill Academic Pub, 2013).

Transcript of Packaging Industrialization and Selling It: State-Guaranteed Export Financing and Nationalist...

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

1

Packaging Industrialization and Selling It:

State-Guaranteed Export Financing and Nationalist Industrialization, 1920-1940

Paper for the History Project “Institutions, Credit, and the State” Conference

Ted Fertik*

September, 2014

In the eyes of contemporaries and of historians, what characterizes the international

economy of the interwar period is above all its distance from the international economy of the

years before 1914.1 The rise of protectionism in the 1920s and its effects on the volume of world

trade; the collapse of the Gold Standard and competitive devaluations in the 1930s; the

generalized sense that another war was likely and the consequent need for economic policies

geared towards national defense: all of these developments could be and frequently were

grouped under the heading of “economic nationalism”.2 In the parlance of contemporary

scholars, for whom it has become axiomatic that the pre-war period was a precocious era of

globalization, the second Thirty Years War was the 20th century’s moment of “de-globalization”

* Ph.D. Candidate, History Department, Yale University. Thanks to Adam Tooze, Naomi Lamoreaux, Tim Guinnane, Grey Anderson, and Gabe Winant for many helpful brainstorming conversations. All mistakes – and they are surely legion – are the author’s. 1 The most famous statement from the interwar period is J. M. Keynes, The Economic Consequences of the Peace (New York: Harcourt, Brace & Howe, 1920). The most important recently scholarly statements are Kevin H O’Rourke and Jeffrey G Williamson, Globalization and History: The Evolution of a Nineteenth-Century Atlantic Economy (Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press, 1999); Michael D. Bordo, Alan M. Taylor, and Jeffrey G. Williamson, eds., Globalization in Historical Perspective (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2003); Barry Eichengreen, Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996). 2 For representative contemporary reflections, see the views collected in Joseph M. Pavloff, Prosperity; Economic Nationalism or Internationalism (New York: Foreign Policy Association, 1929). For the most thoughtful recent reflection on the varieties of interwar economic nationalism in relation to the world economy, see Henryk Szlajfer, Economic Nationalism and Globalization: Lessons from Latin America and Central Europe (Brill Academic Pub, 2013).

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

2

or “globalization backlash”, when globalization’s losers mobilized politically to root out the

institutional foundations of 19th century international society. While capturing a certain truth

(world trade did shrink; the international capital market did collapse; immigration barriers did

increase), this schema has always had an element of implausibility. Were the economic policies

of the 1920s and 1930s really “anti-global”? Were even arch-nationalist leaders really seeking to

sever their economic ties to other parts of the world?

Then and now, the term “autarky” has been trotted out to serve as a catchall for the

impulse motivating the making of economic policy across the world between the wars. This is a

distorting caricature. Much closer to the truth is the sentiment captured in a speech of the

Brazilian president Getulio Vargas, who, at the groundbreaking of the state-owned steel mill that

bears his name, articulated a desire for his country to cease to be a “semicolonial agrarian

country, importer of manufactures and exporter of raw materials,” and become one “able to meet

the exigencies of an autonomous industrial life”.3 Present also at this ceremony were the

American engineers who had designed and supervised construction of the mill and officials of

the U.S. government lending agency that had financed it; the plant and machinery inside the mill

had been built in American factories. This configuration was not accidental nor even awkward.

Indeed it was by design. The “industrialization of agrarian countries”4 was not a revolt against

the international economy, but an effort on the part of those countries to negotiate a different

relationship to it – one that would guarantee their sovereignty, rather than threaten it; one which,

in keeping with the promise of the Fourteen Points (if not their intention!) would entitle them to

3 Vargas at Volta Redonda in 1943, quoted in Morris Llewellyn Cooke, Brazil on the March: A Study in International Cooperation (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1944), 55–56. 4 Wilhelm Röpke, International Economic Disintegration (W. Hodge and Company, Limited, 1942).

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

3

an equal membership in the society of nations.5 For countries experiencing a shortage of capital

and technical expertise, and an absence of capital goods industries, industrialization was not an

ambition that could be realized without cooperation from the advanced capitalist countries.

Countries like China, Turkey, and Brazil not only required this cooperation, they fully expected

they would get it, and on favorable terms. The title of Sun Yat-sen’s sprawling 1920 manifesto –

“The International Development of China” – sums up the spirit animating these projects.

It is common to assume that the advanced capitalist countries must have been opposed to

these developments. Not only did industrialization in non-industrial countries hold out the

prospect of the loss of the “core’s” oligopoly on advanced industrial technology, it also looked

like the potential loss of significant export markets through a process of import substitution.

Voices opposed to these projects did exist. If opponents were unable to prevent programs of

international cooperation, they were far from powerless to shape them. Furthermore, in a

moment when much of the commodity producing world was either in or on the brink of default

on its sovereign debt, proposals for extending long-term credit on favorable terms smacked of

financial extravagance; those who were in the habit of preaching deflation in response to

economic crisis saw in proposals for industrialization abroad nothing but the fiscal incontinence

they were determined to stanch at home. But the opponents consistently lost the argument.

Instead, national economic units formed of heavy industrial concerns, engineers, and national

5 The desire for industrialization was thus an element of a “condition of globality” confronting everyone in the world, because of the fact that the world had already been effectively globalized. Every part of the world already had ties to the rest of the world strong enough that developments in one part of the world affected the rest of it. On the trajectory of the global condition generally, see Charles Bright and Michael Geyer, “Benchmarks of Globalization: The Global Condition, 1850-2010,” in A Companion to World History, ed. Douglas Northrup (Chichester: Wiley-Blackwell, 2012). On the global dynamics of contestation between those societies in a position to impose order on the rest of the world and those who struggled for autonomy within those ordering projects, see Charles Bright and Michael Geyer, “Regimes of World Order: Global Integration and the Production of Difference in Twentieth Century World History,” in Interactions: Transregional Perspectives on World History, ed. Jerry H. Bentley, Renate Bridenthal, and Anand A. Yang (Honolulu: University of Hawai’i Press, 2005).

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

4

governments actively competed with each other to supply countries bent on nationalist

industrialization with a package of official loans, first-rate technical advising, and specialized

capital goods at competitive prices. This paper attempts to explain why.

The focus here is on integrated iron and steel works, which were an indispensible

component of every single industrialization program of the interwar period. Incredibly large and

technically complex installations, they were uniformly beyond the reach of even organized

combinations of domestic capital and state apparatuses in developing countries. Given the tight

connection between metallurgy and raw materials, modern steel production was also a focal

point for arguments about “have” and “have-not” countries in the interwar period, as leadership

in this strategic industry – and therefore in industrial might generally – appeared closely tied to

the accidents of which societies happened to be sitting on top of large quantities of coking coal.

But by the interwar period a combination of declining costs for transporting fuels and

breakthroughs in the utilization of lower grade raw materials meant that steel production was

increasingly capable of being done anywhere in the world. Thus making steel in places far from

its traditional heartlands was an increasingly viable economic proposition by the 1920s and

1930s, and it looked that way both to political, business, and military leaders in developing

countries, and to industrialists and officials in the core countries.

What follows is an attempt to sketch the dynamics by which countries set on paths of

statist, nationalist industrialization secured the resources they needed from abroad to inaugurate

their national steel industries. The first section looks at the origins and subsequent evolution of

the institutional apparatuses that were assembled in Britain, Germany and the U.S. to facilitate

the sort of international economic cooperation that industrializing countries were seeking. The

second section traces the negotiations between China, Turkey, and Brazil and the three

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

5

industrialized countries over the terms of the latter’s support for the development of modern steel

industries in the former. The focus in the paper – dictated by the sources I have so far assembled

– is on the rich countries. It should be clear from what follows that the focus in no way implies

that it was the rich countries that were calling all of the shots. The evidence suggests that power

political considerations were also close to the fore: the U.S., Britain, and Germany were most

interested in extending official credit for industrialization projects to countries they considered in

some way strategic. But it is equally clear that programs of international economic cooperation

were strategic in a different sense. Officials, businessmen, and observers all thought that they

were witnessing a sea change in international economic relations. This transformation was in part

a result of a worldwide surge in nationalist sentiment. It was also occasioned by technological

shifts that made it easier and cheaper to produce a variety of goods far from raw materials and

supplies of skilled labor. The consequence of this shift, however, was a growing conviction that

prosperity for the industrialized countries would in the future increasingly depend on their

supplying the industrializing countries with the capital goods necessary for industrialization in

the rest of the world.

I. “Staatliche Exportkreditversicherung”

The First World War was massively disruptive to the international economy. In the

course of attempting to stitch back together what the war had rent, international economic actors,

especially exporters, encountered a novel set of problems. Before the war exporters had

purchased, for a premium, insurance policies from private insurers that protected them against

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

6

the particular risks associated with selling goods overseas, especially risks tied to shipping.6

Exporters who sold their goods on credit – as many did – had also been able to insure themselves

against the risk of non-payment by their foreign buyers, a risk that was calculated on the basis of

the creditworthiness of the purchaser. After the war, private insurance companies declined to

reenter this market, on the grounds that political conditions in many importing countries had

elevated the risk of non-payment beyond the level that insurance companies could profitably

price. For many exporters, the unavailability of such an insurance policy rendered them unable to

accept foreign orders, especially large ones on long credit terms.

Had economic conditions been otherwise normal, governments might have felt that this

was a problem they could ignore. This was of course not the case, and after the war many

countries felt immense pressure to bolster domestic employment through whatever means they

could mobilize. In 1919 the U.K. government became the first to establish a public system of

export credit insurance as a comparatively low-cost way to stimulate the export trade. Politicians

considered it a business-like program, designed to correct a market failure. They intended for it

to provide guarantees to reputable exporters selling to otherwise creditworthy borrowers. Given

the range of options available for stimulating exports, official credit guarantees were far less

likely to elevate international antagonisms than, say, a devaluation.

Over the course of the 1920s, in cooperation with U.K. exporters, the British officials in

charge of what became the Export Credits Guarantee Department developed a range of products

designed to meet specific business needs. The ECGD had a mandatory advisory board that

consisted of “businessmen and bankers”, and this board had to approve any guarantees that the

Department extended. The basic concept was that, for a premium, His Majesty’s Government 6 Of course, it was actually the importer who paid this cost, reflected in the notion of “C.I.F. – cost + insurance + freight.”

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

7

would, under specific conditions, pledge to pay the exporter (or the exporter’s bank) up to 60%

of the value of defaulted payments. Although not without opponents, who disliked the

possibilities for official favoritism inherent to such a body, the ECGD continually had its

mandate renewed, and its balance sheet increased. It appears never to have lost money for the

government.

In the 1930s the officials in charge of the ECGD, who interfaced regularly with British

Chambers of Commerce both at home and abroad, commercial secretaries, and exporters

themselves, began to note the increasing prevalence of what they called “public works” contracts

in export markets. These ranged from ports and railroads to electrical installations and steel

works. They were, in other words, the component parts of national economic plans. U.K.

exporters, in turn, began to organize themselves into consortia to compete for these “really large

contracts”.7 The ECGD for its part noted that British firms were not especially competitive in

their bids for these contracts, especially compared to the Germans. Though the Brits might

attribute German success to all manner of nefarious deeds, they were aware that there were a

number of obstacles to British success that were under their control. Among these was the

determination of the Treasury, representing creditor interests, to use British influence to press

debtor countries to resume or continue payments on their sovereign debt as a condition for the

extension of any official credits. Increasingly, officials in the Foreign Office, the Department of

Overseas Trade, and the ECGD concluded that the future of British exports lay with capital

goods producers, since the will to import substitution in much of the world meant that

Manchester cottons (for example) would soon lose their customers. Sympathizing with the

myriad conditions beyond the control of developing countries – particularly the collapse in 7 “Development of British interests in China”, reporting a conversation with Charles Mitchell of Dorman, Long & Co. May 20, 1932. FO 371/16226, F4077/1309/10.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

8

commodity prices that had done so much to weaken their foreign exchange positions – British

officials recognized that in their determination to pursue their industrialization programs,

countries like Turkey would find another willing international partner if the British chose to stay

out. They concluded that they should base their assessment of the credit risk not on the status of

countries’ sovereign debt or commercial arrears, but on the likelihood that the regime in question

would persist, and the existence of a strong national interest on the part of the developing

countries in keeping faith with their international partners, so as to win further favorable

treatment in future negotiations.

The German system of governmental export credit insurance had a more complex

institutional development, in part because of the seismic shocks to the German banking system

during the Depression. Of the three countries in question, in the 1920s Germany felt the need to

export most acutely, given the high levels of imports on which German industry was dependent,

and the need to run a trade surplus in order to generate currency for reparations payments. State

support for exports was thus given more freely in Germany than in the U.K. or the U.S. From

1926 the German government, acting through the Economic Ministry, authorized the Hermes

Kreditversicherung AG and the Frankfurter Allgemeine Versicherung AG to assume guarantees

“in the name of the Reich” of the risk of non-payment on export sales to governments and

publicly-owned businesses. A year previous the German government had decided to grant

enormous guarantees to German exporters for sales to the Soviet Union.8 In 1928, Krupp

approached the Economics Ministry to inform them that it was forming consortia along with the

8 Rolf-Dieter Müller, Das Tor Zur Weltmacht: Die Bedeutung Der Sowjetunion Für Die Deutsche Wirtschafts- Und Rüstungspolitik Zwischen Den Weltkriegen, Wehrwissenschaftliche Forschungen. Abteilung Militärgeschichtliche Studien 32 (Boppard am Rhein: H. Boldt, 1984); Manfred Pohl, Geschäft Und Politik: Deutsch-Russisch/sowjetische Wirtschaftsbeziehungen (Mainz: v. Hase & Koehler Verlag, 1988); Peter Danylow and Ulrich S. Soénius, eds., Otto Wolff: Ein Unternehmen zwischen Wirtschaft und Politik (München: Siedler Verlag, 2005).

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

9

Vereinigte Stahlwerke and Otto Wolff for sales of railway equipment and other large orders to

government-owned businesses in a number of export markets.9 By 1930, the Frankfurt insurer

had gone bankrupt, and Hermes had been largely nationalized. Both the Reich and German

exporters found this public-private partnership too limiting for the scale of deals they were

contemplating. Provisions were made for a standardized guarantee contract under the auspices of

the Deutsche Revisions- und Treuhand A.G. (DRT), a state-owned auditing firm.10 The contract

covered all sales contracts with “foreign states and foreign public bodies” (ausländische Staaten

und ausländische öffentliche Körperschaften) or “government business” (Regierungsgeschäfte)

for short, provided the sale was for RM 5 million (approx. $2 million) or more, or had a credit

term of two years or more.11 The German government recognized special risks associated with

these sorts of deals, in particular the ever-present possibility that foreign governments could, by

law or by fiat, simply decide not to pay.12 The Reich constituted an intergovernmental committee

– the Export-Garantie-Auschuss für Regierungsgeschäfte – consisting of high-ranking officials

from the Economic and Finance ministries, the DRT, the nationalized Dresdner Bank, and,

typically, officials from the Foreign Office responsible for the countries in question. The

committee met monthly to consider requests from German firms for guarantees. It was very well

aware that some of the biggest future business would be in sales not just of machinery and

equipment, but contracts for the design and erection of entire plants.

Like the British, but more so, the German state apparatus for supplying capital goods to

industrializing countries concerned itself as little as possible with that country’s overall credit 9 Krupp Abteilung Ost to Dr. Heintze, Reichswirtschaftsministerium. Nov. 12, 1928. R3101/18897. 10 Joachim Christopeit, Hermes-Deckungen: Inhalt Und Funktion, Stellung Im System Der Exportförderung, Wirtschaftspolitische Bedeutung Mit Rechtsvergleichender Bewertung (München: C. H. Beck, 1968). 11 Hermes continued to offer guarantees for foreign government contracts smaller than this, but the total amounts guaranteed were considerably smaller. 12 Ernst Hellmut Vits, “Ausfuhrförderung Durch Staatliche Exportgarantien in Deutschland Und Anderen Ländern,” Bank-Archiv: Zeitschrift Für Bank- Und Börsenwesen 24 (1934): 201–4.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

10

position. Instead it focused on the quality of security on offer from the foreign government for

the deal in question. Where the Germans felt that the security was good – including where

repayment could be linked to the barter arrangements that the Nazi regime established with so

many of its foreign customers and suppliers – they were liberal in extending guarantees to their

exporters. Unlike the British, whose law prohibited the use of the export credits apparatus for

arms sales, the German government actively used the same facilities for the sale of military

equipment13, and once the war began these sales dominated the work of the Export-Garantie-

Ausschuss. In the context of debates around the extent to which Nazi Germany was a command

economy, the supply of export credit guarantees lends weight to the view that in many regards

the Nazi regime chose to rely on subsidies and inducements rather than force in order to align the

incentives of German industry with the regime’s overall goals.14 If anything, it is clear that

German firms required no motivation from the Reich to pursue the large contracts that overseas

government business offered in the 1930s. But because such contracts were competitive, German

industry actively sought assistance from the German government in order to offer the best

possible terms to their foreign customers. It was generally the view of both the British and the

Americans that the German apparatus was by far the most highly developed. Whether this was

because liberal scruples about state support for industry were weaker in Germany, or because

through the Depression the German government had acquired such large ownership stakes in key

German industrial concerns, or because the need to promote exports was felt most powerfully in

Germany, the result was close working relationships between Germany’s largest industrial firms

and the German state in the field of large-scale capital goods exports.

13 C. M. Leitz, “Arms Exports from the Third Reich, 1933-1939: The Example of Krupp,” The Economic History Review, 51, no. 1 (Feb., 1998): 133–54. 14 Christoph Buchheim and Jonas Scherner, “The Role of Private Property in the Nazi Economy: The Case of Industry,” The Journal of Economic History 66, no. 2 (June 1, 2006): 390–416.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

11

The Export-Import Bank of the United States was established in 1934 with the initial

purpose of matching the export credit insurance that European governments since World War I

had been offering to their manufacturers.15 The first instantiation of the Bank was designed to

facilitate American exports to the Soviet Union. But the utility of the device for general business

purposes was quickly recognized, and, under the supervision of the ubiquitous Jesse Jones, in

1936 Congress gave a newly chartered bank wide latitude in providing insurance and granting

credits to foreign buyers of American goods. Export credit was sold to the Congress on grounds

intelligible to Wisconsin school analysts of American foreign economic relations: American

producers needed foreign markets to prosper; foreign competitors were using cutthroat methods

to undersell American producers in those markets; American producers should be able to count

on their government doing everything in its power to defend their access to those markets.16 In

the context of the Depression and New Deal recovery programs, ExIm – after a short stint under

Roosevelt’s ultra-protectionist foreign trade adviser George Peek – was of a piece with the

various “state capitalist” business promotion devices of Jesse Jones’s Reconstruction Finance

Corporation, in which it was housed until the 1940s.17 From 1935 ExIm was given a new

director, Warren Lee Pierson, who supported pairing the bank’s export-promotion mandate with

support for developmentalist programs in recipient countries.

15 Stella K. Margold, Export Credit Insurance in Europe Today: A Study of the Sixteen European Export Credit Insurance Systems for the Formulation of a Pattern for an Entirely Government Operated or Partially Government Controlled Plan (Washington, D.C: GPO, 1934). 16 Lloyd C Gardner, Economic Aspects of New Deal Diplomacy (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1964). 17 For the RFC and “state capitalism”, see James Stuart Olson, Saving Capitalism: The Reconstruction Finance Corporation and the New Deal, 1933-1940 (Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press, 1988). Also Jordan A. Schwarz, The New Dealers: Power Politics in the Age of Roosevelt, (New York: Knopf, 1993). On ExIm’s early connection to the more nationalist-isolationist side of New Deal foreign economic policy, and its role in the “Peek-Hull” debates, see Frederick C Adams, Economic Diplomacy: The Export-Import Bank and American Foreign Policy, 1934-1939 (Columbia: University of Missouri Press, 1976). Also Stephan Haggard, “The Institutional Foundations of Hegemony: Explaining the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934,” International Organization 42, no. 1 (Jan. 1, 1988): 91–119, esp. pp. 113-117.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

12

ExIm had numerous differences from its British and German counterparts. The German

need to export in order to generate foreign exchange for required imports was altogether absent

from the U.S. context. Exports in general made up such a small percentage of U.S. national

income – trifling in comparison to Britain or Germany – that proposals to revive the U.S.

economy through export promotion were always borderline ridiculous.18 Furthermore

agricultural commodities still loomed massively in total U.S. exports, whereas they were almost

completely absent in the commodity composition of German and British foreign sales. The

domestic orientation of U.S. recovery policy was shared by the domestic orientation of U.S.

capital goods producers – especially steelmakers – whose efforts to develop foreign markets

were often lackluster, content as they were with the tariff-protected domestic market.19 ExIm was

further constrained by historic ties between Wall Street and the U.S. State Department, which

gave U.S. foreign economic policy a distinctly pro-creditor bias. In contrast, Germany, which in

the 1920s became the world’s biggest debtor, had little in the way of creditor interests to defend

in overseas markets. The U.S. State Department consistently constrained the ambitions of ExIm

officers and their allies in the Treasury Department, arguing that official U.S. loans to foreign

governments would eliminate any incentive for those governments to negotiate agreements for

the resumption of debt service on their defaulted bonds.20 Lastly the U.S. export promotion

program had to face down a U.S. Congress genetically inclined to favor producer interests,

18 Michael R. Adamson, “‘Must We Overlook All Impairment of Our Interests?’ Debating the Foreign Aid Role of the Export-Import Bank, 1934–41,” Diplomatic History 29, no. 4 (September 1, 2005): 601, doi:10.1111/j.1467-7709.2005.00508.x. 19 Mary A. Yeager, “Trade Protection as an International Commodity: The Case of Steel,” The Journal of Economic History 40, no. 1 (Mar., 1980): 33–42; Richard A. Lauderbaugh, “Business, Labor, and Foreign Policy: U.S. Steel, the International Steel Cartel, and Recognition of the Steel Workers Organizing Committee,” Politics & Society 6, no. 4 (Dec., 1976): 433–57. Digest of Ford, Bacon & Davis Report No. 200, Jun. 21, 1938, pp. 4-5. Box 46, Edward Reilly Stettinius Jr. Papers, 1918-1949, MSS 2723, Small Special Collections Library, Charlottesville, Virginia. 20 Michael R. Adamson, “The Failure of the Foreign Bondholders Protective Council Experiment, 1934-1940,” The Business History Review 76, no. 3 (October 1, 2002): 490, doi:10.2307/4127796; Adamson, ““Must We Overlook All Impairment of Our Interests?,” 604–605.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

13

which could not but see in support for industrial development programs abroad a threat to the

existing export markets of domestic producers – small as they may have been.

Nevertheless by 1940 ExIm officials and their allies – capital goods producers21, New

Deal internationalists – had succeeded in overcoming opposition to the bank engaging in the sort

of cooperative development projects that the British and the Germans had pioneered in the

1930s. Ultimately it was Nazi aggression that turned the tide, as American policymakers feared

that German barter agreements would induce various states in the Americas into closer economic

and ultimately political relations with Germany. But geopolitics was not the only consideration.

The chartering of the ExIm Bank happened at the same moment as a fundamental shift in the

foreign economic policy of the Roosevelt administration was beginning. As Thomas Ferguson

documented in his classic article, by 1934 the Roosevelt administration had begun a move away

from emphatically economically nationalist policies of the early New Deal and toward

international economic liberalization and multilateralism, beginning with the push for the

Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act in 1934.22 Much of the initiative for this shift came from “new

liberal” policy intellectuals, especially Adolf Berle in the State Department and Harry Dexter

White at Treasury, who increasingly pushed for a more pro-active, explicitly anti-imperialist

foreign economic policy. Berle was of course the pathbreaking co-author of The Modern

21 In the records of the Export-Import Bank one occasionally finds statements of this sort in support of the Bank’s facilities from the high echelons of American capitalism: “World trade today is in theory and in fact largely a competition between governments rather than individuals.” Eugene P. Thomas, Westinghouse Air Brake Co. to National Foreign Trade Council, Jun. 21, 1939. USNA RG 59, 1930-1939. Box 5154, Folder 4. 22 Thomas Ferguson, “From Normalcy to New Deal: Industrial Structure, Party Competition, and American Public Policy in the Great Depression,” International Organization 38, no. 1 (Jan., 1984): 41–94. For the purposes of this paper it is not important whether we accept Ferguson’s argument that it was the new influence of multinational firms within the Democratic party coalition that triggered the shift. On how the RTAA actually enabled the executive branch to take some degree of control over the tariff-setting process, see Judith Goldstein and Robert Gulotty, “America and Trade Liberalization: The Limits of Institutional Reform” in International Organization, forthcoming. See also Jeff Frieden, “Sectoral Conflict and Foreign Economic Policy, 1914-1940,” International Organization 42, no. 1 (Jan., 1988): 59–90.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

14

Corporation and Private Property, the fundamental text for all arguments about the socialization

of capital via the public corporation.23 He and White both believed that the world had entered a

new era in financial history, in which private capital could no longer be depended on to supply

the whole of the world’s investment needs. Instead, public investment – at a national and at an

international level – would be required to make up the shortfall.24 Rather than a sign of

capitalism’s decadence, this was instead an opportunity to imbue investment with a public

purpose, namely improving standards of living, and, in the hemispheric context, supporting “the

steady and continued development of the other American countries”.25

These then were the arrangements that the British, German, and American governments

and large exporters developed over the course of the 1920s and 1930s to facilitate the export of

capital goods and to create the conditions for international cooperation in the industrialization of

agrarian countries. The remainder of the essay is devoted to the negotiations between these

different national assemblages and the Chinese, Turkish, and Brazilian governments. Each of

these countries had been on the subordinate end of a relationship to the rich countries that they

called “imperialism”, even as none had been the formal possession of an imperial power. All in

the interwar period sought to forge a new type of economic relationship with the advanced

23 See Howard Brick, Transcending Capitalism: Visions of a New Society in Modern American Thought (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2006), 73–82. 24 See e.g. his testimony before the Temporary National Economic Committee in 1939, entitled “A Banking System for Capital and Capital Credit”, printed in Adolf A. Berle, Jr., New Directions in the New World (New York: Harper & Brothers, 1940). 25 Adolf A. Berle, “The Economic Interests of the United States in Inter-American Relations”, Department of State Bulletin No. 105 (Jun. 28, 1941), p. 760. Berle was the crucial American figure in the development of plans for an Inter-American Bank, which, if it had not been blocked in Congress, would have been the first financial institution of which governments – not central banks – were the shareholders. In this regard it was to have been genuinely multinational. And, as Eric Helleiner has demonstrated, economic development and specifically industrialization of the poorer Latin American countries was a core motivation for the creation of such a bank. See Eric Helleiner, The Forgotten Foundations of Bretton Woods: International Development and the Making of the Postwar Order (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2014), Ch. 2.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

15

capitalist countries. They would not accept any arrangement that appeared to compromise or

undermine their national sovereignty. All three countries were overwhelmingly agrarian, and all

considered industrialization to be the best possible guarantee of their sovereignty and national

autonomy. In their modern histories none of these three countries had been colonized nor had

they been firmly within one imperial power’s sphere of influence. But Atatürk’s Turkey had had

to wage an enormous struggle to secure the international recognition of its sovereignty in 1923.

China had experienced revolutionary conditions – largely the result of popular rebellion against

the Middle Kingdom’s increasing subservience to foreign powers – since the turn of the century.

And in 1930 Brazilians had overthrown their republican government in no small part because

young military officers felt that the dominance of the coffee planting elite was maintaining the

country in a position of dependence on foreign capital. For each country the possibility of

economic dependence leading to political subordination was ever present. Vigilance against it

was an existential need. The biggest threat to their sovereignty was a consortium of the capitalist

powers in a Kautskian ultra-imperialism. The greatest bulwark of that sovereignty was

competition between the capitalist powers for access to their markets – as long as the “gunboat”

option was ruled out. In the interwar period, it was the latter that prevailed.

II. International Aid for Nationalist Steel Projects

China

German industry began a concerted push to expand its exports to China beginning in

1930, with the formation of a China Study Commission by the Reichsverband der deutscher

Industrie, the peak association of German industrialists. Individuals representing the full range of

German exporters spent several months in China meeting with officials and businessmen and

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

16

investigating avenues for economic cooperation. Noting the quickening desire for

industrialization, and the Chinese desire for international economic relations with countries who

were committed to the preservation of Chinese sovereignty, the commission saw enormous

potential. It also saw considerable risks, particularly given the limited control that Chiang Kai-

shek’s government exerted in many parts of the country.26 Views within the Guomindang

differed as to the best course of industrial development, and particularly over the roles of the

Chinese state and foreign capital in economic development, but with the Japanese conquest of

Manchuria in 1931, the debate shifted decisively in favor of Chiang Kai-shek and his allies, who

saw national defense as the key desideratum, prioritizing therefore heavy industry, and requiring

large amounts of foreign capital and technical expertise.27 Germany was Chiang’s preferred

trading partner, and it was the German Gutehoffnungshütte steel and engineering concern (GHH)

that positioned itself as the most serious bidder for a project to build a modern, integrated iron

and steel works near Nanjing and develop the coal and iron resources of the Yangzi valley to

supply it.

For the GHH this steel project represented a potentially enormous contract, one that its

officers estimated could give work for years to several thousand of its employees. For German

industry as a whole it could serve as the entering wedge for a German export offensive in China.

For the Chinese it held out the possibility of the rapid development of steelmaking capacity –

easily converted to munitions manufacture – with the assistance of a world-renowned firm whose

only interest was to deliver the works and win a strong position for future bids. It was also an 26 Reichsverbandes der deutschen Industrie, Bericht der China-Studienkommission (Berlin, 1930); William C. Kirby, Germany and Republican China (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 1984), chap. 2. 27 This debate is the principal subject of Margherita Zanasi, Saving the Nation: Economic Modernity in Republican China (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2006). On the various manifestations of a developmentalist mindset in Republican China, see William Kirby, “Engineering China: Birth of the Developmental State, 1928-1937,” in Becoming Chinese: Passages to Modernity and beyond, ed. Wen-Hsin Yeh, Studies on China 23 (Berkeley  ; London: University of California Press, 2000), 137–60, http://site.ebrary.com/lib/yale/Doc?id=10058852.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

17

early test for the expanded apparatus of German export credit insurance, the Export-Garantie-

Ausschuss für Regierungsgeschäfte. As mentioned above, this committee was empowered to

award guarantees of up to 70% of the value of sales contracts to foreign governments, and by

1932 it had already done so to the tune of tens of millions of Reichsmarks.

The negotiations were complicated from the start by the dire financial straits of the

Nanjing regime. Its budget was twice the size of its revenues; with the loss of Manchuria went

most of its industrial capacity and railroad lines and the source – through sales of ores and

manufactured goods to Japan and agricultural products elsewhere – of much of the Chinese

state’s foreign exchange. As always with large sales made on credit spread out over several

years, the risk that the buyer, once delivery had been taken, would simply stop paying, was very

high. That risk was higher still when the buyer was a foreign government, and one for which the

use of force to compel payment was simply out of the question. Vits of the DRT summed up

German officialdom’s reasoning:

On top of the internal political difficulties comes the external political conflict with Manchuria. Finally the Communist threat is not to be underestimated. For all of these reasons the ability to pay of the Nanking regime must be placed in doubt. Furthermore the intention to pay cannot always be considered good. It is therefore advisable to grant Reich's guarantees only for such business for which first class security is pledged. In such cases it can certainly be decided to grant Reich guarantees, [and] in particular efforts must be assured to prevent a complete loss of the Chinese market.28 First class security was indeed the sticking point, since the Chinese were offering nothing

of the sort. An initial proposal to secure Chinese treasury notes with customs revenue was

overruled by the Chinese finance ministry, which had determined that it would never again

pledge customs revenue for debt service, except in the case of national defense (apparently in the

eyes of T. V. Soong, China’s Columbia-educated finance minister, the steel mill did not qualify).

28 Vits memorandum, “Reichsbürgschaften für Lieferungsgeschäfte nach China.” Oct. 25, 1932. BABL R3101/18980.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

18

Instead the Chinese would only agree to issue seven year treasury notes, countersigned by the

Bank of China – essentially, the full faith and credit of the Chinese state. Private bankers close to

the Reich considered such pledges all but worthless. Paul Reusch of the GHH, who, as chair of

the Northwest Group of the Association of German Iron and Steel Industrialists from 1924-1930,

was one of the most powerful figures in all of Weimar Germany, personally appealed to German

officials to secure financing for the deal, warning that “it is to be expected with certainty that this

order will go to England” if the German authorities did not arrange to guarantee the credit.29

German industrialists wanted the German regime to develop facilities for China similar to those

that the Reich had so successfully employed in financing exports to Russia since 1925. But

unlike China, the Soviet Union had “credit to lose”. Unlike the Guomingdang, the Communist

Party of the Soviet Union was indeed “Herr im Hause.”30

Ultimately a guarantee from the German government for this particular project was not

forthcoming. But by 1936, once barter agreements had been struck exchanging Chinese primary

products – especially strategic ores for rearmament like tungsten and antimony – for German

manufactured products, railway construction and complete plants, German exports to China,

backed by export credit guarantees from the German Reich, boomed.31 As in so many parts of

the world, the combination of worldwide economic recovery, a massive armaments boom, and

Germany’s desperate need for foreign exchange relaxed the financial constraints facing

governments. Industrialists and government planners could then overrule bankers and

29 Reusch to Professor Dr. Warmbold (Reichswirtschaftsministerium). Aug. 1, 1932. BABL R3101/18980. 30 Rhodewald (German advisor to the Bank of China) to Ritscher (Dresdner Bank). Nov. 25, 1932. BABL R3101/18980. 31 Kirby, Germany and Republican China; Udo Ratenhof, Die Chinapolitik des Deutschen Reiches 1871 Bis 1945: Wirtschaft, Rüstung, Militär (Boppard am Rhein: Boldt, 1987), 418–423.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

19

government finance ministers, as investment in the name of national defense trumped austerity in

the name of fiscal probity.

China in the interwar period was only a partially sovereign country, and in fact there were

a number of competing power centers, which, if they were not vying for control of the whole of

China, nevertheless were making bids for a sort of regional federated sovereignty. One of the

strongest of these competing power centers was the southern province of Guangdong, whose

ruler Chen Jitang had his own military forces under his direct command. To go with his

independent military strength – the most obvious coordinate of sovereignty – he decided to

couple independent industrial strength. Reflecting again the tight connection between steel and

sovereignty, the Three Year Plan for the industrial development of Guangdong included

construction of a modern, integrated iron and steel works.32

In 1933 the Guangdong regional government hired the American steel engineering firm

of Arthur McKee & Co. to investigate the possibility of constructing a modern iron and steel

works in the province. William Haven, McKee’s vice president for international business, had

designed and overseen construction of the gargantuan works at Magnitogorsk, centerpiece of the

USSR’s first Five Year Plan, and he commanded the trust of the Guangdong government. Haven

undertook surveys of the neighboring coal and iron ore deposits, and made rough estimates of

potential markets for the mill’s products, and concluded that - especially given Chinese tariff

32 C. Y. W. Meng, “Canton’s Three-Year Industrial Plan” The China Weekly Review, Jan. 6, 1934, p. 238. ProQuest Historical Newspapers: Chinese Newspapers Collection (1832-1953). See Alfred H. Y. Lin, “Building and Funding a Warlord Regime: The Experience of Chen Jitang in Guangdong, 1929-1936,” Modern China 28, no. 2 (Apr., 2002): 177–212.There is reason to believe that investment in industrial development in Guangdong between 1929 and 1936 was greater in magnitude than the Central Government’s, which has lately been credited with establishing much of China’s state-owned industrial economy prior to the creation of the PRC in 1949. Emily M. Hill, Smokeless Sugar: The Death of a Provincial Bureaucrat and the Construction of China’s National Economy (Vancouver: UBC Press, 2010), 9–10; Morris L. Bian, The Making of the State Enterprise System in Modern China: The Dynamics of Institutional Change (Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press, 2005).

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

20

autonomy since 192933 - a profitable works could easily be constructed in the province. Reports

from many quarters concurred that the Cantonese were interested in the project not just for its

contribution to regional industrialization, but also for the ease with which such a facility could be

converted to munitions manufacture. Given the escalating Communist insurgency, the looming

possibility of civil war, and the unabating threat of Japanese commercial penetration backed by

military means, the Cantonese government saw a modern steel works as an instrument of

regional-cum-national defense.34

The provincial authorities wished to obtain equipment, technical expertise, and financing

from foreign firms and governments, and they invited British, American, and German firms or

consortia to tender bids. British officials assumed that one of the German firms, whose

government’s facilities for extending long term credit to overseas borrowers they considered

highly developed, would win the contract. On political grounds the local authorities appeared to

favor British or Anglo-American firms. Two British consortia – one led by the multinational H.

A. Brassert & Co35, the other by Ashmore, Benson & Pease, a British engineering outfit – bid for

33 Hill, Smokeless Sugar, 3. 34 The connection between steel and sovereignty can again be seen in a discussion between Chen Jitang and other top Cantonese officials and the British minister in China. The British noted that the Cantonese were “not anxious to pull down the Central government, but they were opposed to the action of the Central Government in favour of . . . Japan . . . Another instance of the lack of good faith shewn by the Central Government was their failure to complete the Anti-Communist campaign. Apparently the existence of the Communist menace gave them an excuse for not showing a bold front to Japan.” Immediately after this discussion of raison d’êtat, the conversation moved to whether the British government would support the steel mill. “Relations between Canton and Nanking governments, etc.” FO 371/19307, F1071/427/10. 35 There is not space in this paper to discuss the career of Hermann Brassert, but it was a remarkable one. He was born in the U.K., studied metallurgy in Germany, cut his teeth in the 1890s supervising the blast furnaces of Carnegie’s Edgar Thomson works, and was credited with developing the techniques that enabled the successful smelting of the famous Mesabi ores. After World War I he established himself as a consulting engineer, and in addition to work for American clients, he was hired by the British government to propose a plan for the reorganization of the entire British steel industry. American bankers enlisted him to consult on the advisability of major American loans to the German steel industry. After his tenure working for the U.K. government he established a permanent presence in the U.K., whose company, although bearing the same name as its American affiliate, operated independently. In 1936 he was hired by Hermann Göring himself – it was reported that they were second cousins – to design and oversee construction of the Reichswerke Hermann Göring, the gargantuan project at

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

21

the project, along with two American (McKee, Fraser & Chalmers) and two German groups

(Krupp and DEMAG). The two British groups along with McKee made the final cut, and the

Cantonese authorities indicated that they would welcome cooperation between the groups. As

with GHH’s efforts to win government backing for their contract with the Nanjing government,

financing was the only difficult aspect of the deal, and the poor quality of the security on offer

was the sticking point. For a project valued at £2 million, the regional authorities initially would

only offer payment out of future profits, “which . . . is nothing more than a promise to pay.”36

Furthermore, the Cantonese were cagey in response to British insistence on approval from the

Nanjing authorities for the project. The British were unsure why, given their general support for

Chiang Kai-shek’s government, they should finance a project “which might one day quite

possibly be turned to military use against Nanking”.37 The British continually drew attention to

the “unsatisfactory political situation”, by which they meant the high probability that the current

regime in Guangzhou would not last, and that the obligations incurred in financing the steel mill

would be repudiated.38 Knowing that neither the contracting firms nor private banks (the British-

owned Hong Kong & Shanghai Bank was keen on the proposal and willing to participate

financially) would be willing to bear all of the risks on their own, the Brassert-led consortium

thought it necessary to obtain official British backing through the ECGD. And yet despite the the center of the Nazi autarky drive; in turn Brassert established a Berlin office as well. In the 1930s his firm could be found in connection with iron and steel projects in at least 15 countries. 36 Commercial Secretary, Hong Kong to the DOT, reporting a conversation with Lund. Mar. 22, 1934. FO 371/18145, F2853/2346/10. 37 FO to ECGD, Nov. 3, 1934. FO 371/18146, F6562/2346/10. 38 In contemplating this possibility, Lund had informed the British that “the site of the iron-works was within easy range of a foreign gunboat”. His interlocutor replied that “any thought of security of this nature should be eliminated from consideration as physical enforcement of rights was most likely to be a boomerang disastrous to all foreign interests.” Lund conversation with British commercial secretary at Hong Kong, Mar. 22, 1934. FO 371/18146, F2853/2346/10. Lund also had conversations with Japanese businessmen, who resented being excluded from the proposal. He wondered aloud whether Japanese participation might not increase the security of the project, as Japan would “endeavour to safeguard any anything in which it had an interest.” Pelham (British Trade Commissioner in Hong Kong) to Beale (Commercial Counsellor in Shanghai), reporting a conversation with Lund. May 1, 1934. FO 371/18146, F4810/2346/10.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

22

patent shakiness of the proposal, British officials were determined to stay in the field, since

Haven was reporting that the new American Export-Import Bank was eager to offer the Chinese

financing on favorable terms.39 The British spoke of the “advertisement value” of such a project;

they appreciated the determination of the regional government to press ahead with its

industrialization schemes, and saw the likelihood of large contracts in the future going to

whichever nation’s firms supplied the desired steel mill. The British interest in the project

coincided with the ECGD’s focus beginning in 1934 on the export of capital goods as a field of

large and increasing importance to British manufacturing.40

At the end of 1934, the British authorities remained unsatisfied with the security on offer,

and declined to extend official credit guarantees. But with the American firms failing to obtain

financing from their government as well, the Brassert consortium, represented by Knut Lund, a

Norwegian engineer of many years’ experience in China, pressed on with its negotiations.41 By

1935 Lund had obtained concessions from the authorities in the form of agreement to a dual

administration of the plant on which the creditors would be represented directly, a larger initial

payment, a new and more detailed survey of the raw materials and the plant siting, and the

possibility of exiting the deal should the new survey turn up discouraging results or should the

political outlook deteriorate. In April 1936 Lund signed a contract with the provincial authorities

39 American documents show that the Export-Import Bank, whose Vice-President at the time was a veteran of the Soviet Five Year Plan and an enthusiast for industrial planning, was keen on the proposal, especially as it faced pressure from the Cleveland Chamber of Commerce. But the U.S. State Department was adamant about not extending new credits to the Chinese when numerous existing commercial accounts were in arrears. American officials affected hurt at the apparent lack of gratitude shown by the Chinese for the American defense of the Open Door. In more materialist terms, exports being so much smaller as a percentage of U.S. national income than in Britain or Germany, U.S. export promotion had not reached a remotely comparable intensity to that of its European competitors. 40 “A Short History of the Export Credits Guarantee Department”, pp. 8-11. ECG 5/2. 41 Lund was in fact the China hand for the firm Perin & Marshall, an American steel engineering firm that had been active in Asia at least since Charles Page Perin went to undertake surveys and consult for the Tata steel works in India in 1906. I have not found any documents explaining why Lund’s American principals did not attempt to compete for this bid.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

23

reflecting these terms on behalf of Brassert & Co. Technical experts from the U.K. arrived

shortly thereafter to begin the new and more detailed survey. No financial commitment from

U.K. authorities was yet forthcoming, but they encouraged Brassert & Co. to continue their

efforts and left open the possibility of credit guarantees if and when conditions improved.

Negotiations did not stop when Chiang forcibly removed Chen Jitang in 1936. Remarkably,

efforts continued even after the Japanese invaded mainland China in the summer of 1937.

Japanese bombs were being dropped on Cantonese factories as the British experts were

conducting their surveys. In fact, the new Cantonese authorities came to recognize that British

losses in Shanghai and the Yangzi Valley increased the potential importance of southern China

to the future of British access to Chinese markets. Employing Lund as their trusted intermediary,

the military officials running Guangdong began to formulate proposals for Sino-British

cooperation in the development of mines and industry in Guangdong province. Evincing a

willingness to depart from the statist principles that had guided their industrialization efforts

earlier in the decade, Cantonese officials now suggested establishing a company under Chinese

law that would have a 51% Chinese participation and a 49% British and Hong Kong

participation, which would take over all existing government-owned factories, finance

construction of the iron and steel works, and underwrite the development of coal mines.

Cantonese authorities alerted the British that "the industrialization of this province will come in

great momentum in the very near future. Whoever sees the opportunity and takes part in it will

reap the profit himself and at the same time be doing his part to make this world a better world to

live in."42 The British view was that this volta-face from the policy of boycotting all British

goods of a decade before was a play to increase British capital’s stake in southern China in the 42 Y. C. Koo (Kwangtung [Guangdong] Provincial Bank to Blunt, (British Consul-General at Canton), Feb. 25, 1938. FO 371/22156, F3716/2796/10.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

24

hope that this would increase Britain’s willingness to defend southern China against Japanese

invasion.43 Chiang Kai-Shek himself, who previously had been content to temporize, presumably

because he thought the Guangdong steel project would compete with the steel works he still

hoped to build near Nanjing, now instructed the Cantonese authorities to speed construction

along.44 The British repeatedly encouraged Lund to continue these discussions, and made official

pledges of diplomatic support, but were clear that the government would make no financial

commitments until political and military conditions improved, and that support from the British

military for private investments was out of the question.

Lund and the British authorities were in complete agreement that on the other side of the

war, which must at some point end, rapid industrial growth in China was a near certainty. Of

course with war and Japanese occupation continuing until 1945, construction on the steel works

never began. But already in 1943 Lund was conferring with British officials about

comprehensive plans for the postwar development of the coal, iron and steel industries in China,

and the possibility of enormous contracts going to British firms. Though the 1930s attempts to

enlist foreign participation in the nationalist development of a modern Chinese steel industry had

failed, it had been the weakness of the political nation, not foreign opposition and not any

inherent backwardness of the economic nation that had precluded its success.

Turkey

If China had been the true epicenter of global inter-imperialist competition before World

War I, the (partial) stabilization of which was indeed the great innovation of America’s turn-of-

the-century ascendancy, Turkey was more classically a zone of European great power politics. 43 [need to track down this reference] 44 Lund to Blunt, Mar. 18, 1938. FO 371/22156, F3717/2796/10.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

25

Yet the end of World War I and the recognition of the sovereignty of the Turkish Republic at

Lausanne in 1923 left Britain with a new preeminence in the region that significantly reduced the

possibility of Great Power conflict over the Middle East.45 At the same time historic ties between

Turkey and Germany remained strong, and German exporters continued to look on Turkey as

one of their most important export markets and one they were at serious risk of losing were they

not to mount a concerted offensive.

Since at least the early 19th century Ottoman officials had realized that the empire’s

economic backwardness relative to the European powers was issuing in a profound military

disadvantage, ultimately imperiling the sovereignty of the Empire. The dependency of

concessions and foreign debt supervision was a humiliation that Turkey’s postwar nationalist

leadership was determined to purge. When the postwar civil strife between Turks and Greeks led

to the exodus of much of Turkey’s capitalist class – and with them much of the country’s capital

– the Kemalist leadership could see no alternative to a large state involvement in economic life.

Although in the 1920s they focused their energies on agricultural modernization, the Depression

cleared the way for grander visions of industrial modernity. The makeshifts of the 1920s

morphed into the official ideology of the 1930s – “étatism” – and into a determination to

accelerate industrialization through all available means, encouraged not least by the collapse in

Turkey’s terms of trade and the concomitant evaporation of the country’s ability to import

manufactured goods.46 The Turks secured early support in 1932 with an $8 million gold dollar

45 John Darwin, “An Undeclared Empire: The British in the Middle East, 1918-39,” Journal of Imperial and Commonwealth History 27, no. 2 (May 1999): 159–76; Yücel Güçlü, “Turco-British Relations on the Eve of the Second World War,” Middle Eastern Studies 39, no. 4 (October 1, 2003): 159–205. 46 Erik Jan Zürcher and ebrary, Inc, Turkey a Modern History, 3rd ed (London  ; New York: I.B. Tauris, 2004), 197, http://site.ebrary.com/lib/yale/Doc?id=10133094; Caroline E. Arnold, “In the Service of Industrialization: Etatism, Social Services and the Construction of Industrial Labour Forces in Turkey (1930–50),” Middle Eastern Studies 48, no. 3 (May 2012): 363–85; Mustafa Türkeş, “A Patriotic Leftist Development-Strategy Proposal in Turkey in the 1930s: The Case of the Kadro (Cadre) Movement,” International Journal of Middle East Studies 33, no. 1 (February

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

26

loan from the Soviet Union to finance principally the purchase of textile machinery. But the first

Turkish Five Year Plan embraced also railroads, ports, coal mines, chemicals, and electrical

power, as well as iron and steel. The Turkish state founded development banks to finance and in

some cases manage new industrial enterprises, and it sought about winning foreign financial and

technical support for its nationalist ambitions. In later years the project would be ridiculed for its

poor siting (it was far from markets and from raw materials), for its gigantism, and for the poor

quality of its management. But in 1932 when the Turks began serious conversations with

German firms about contracting for the construction of an iron and steel mill at Karabük, they

viewed it as a significant step forward for the Turkish economy

The first national unit to bid for the project was a German consortium headed by Krupp.

For the entire 19th century and through World War I Krupp had been the major supplier of

munitions to the Ottoman military, not to mention a major exporter of steel for projects such as

the Baghdad Railway. Beginning in 1926, groups of German firms had begun to compete for

large contracts from the Turkish state, mostly in the arena of railway construction. The first

contract was awarded in 1927 to a consortium led by the construction firm Julius Berger Tiefbau,

followed by very large contracts to Krupp-led consortia in 1930 and again in 1934. The consortia

included many of the major firms of German heavy industry and engineering, and the contracts

received Reich guarantees through the Export-Garantie-Ausschuss and the DRT. Krupp in

particular was determined to win back this former sphere of influence for its firm in particular

and German industry in general. In 1932, already active in railway construction, Krupp began

discussions with officials in Turkey about the possibility of constructing a large, integrated iron

and steel works, in line with the Five Year Plan. Krupp sent its own experts to investigate and 2001): 91–114; Osman Okyar, “The Concept of Étatism,” The Economic Journal 75, no. 297 (March 1, 1965): 98–111, doi:10.2307/2229238.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

27

reported favorably on raw material supplies and the economic viability of the project. Krupp

officials told the RWM that an iron and steel industry for Turkey represented “a very interesting

project for German industry, since it can be expected that such an installation, which will first be

laid out on a small scale but later expanded and built out, entails orders for additional

installations and facilities, which will naturally fall to German firms.”47 The Export-Garantie-

Ausschuss appears to have rejected Krupp’s initial proposal largely because the scale of

guarantees that the Reich had already extended to Krupp-led consortia in Turkey was running up

against an overall limit on Turkish guarantees that the Reich had imposed on itself. The steel

works project, initially valued at RM 18 million, would have come on top of over RM 95 million

(approx. $38 million) that had already been extended.48 In the event, Krupp did sign a contract in

1934 for T£ 20 million (approx. $16 million), T£ 11 million of which was for railway equipment,

and the remainder for the iron and steel works. But the Turkish government decided to open the

latter project to competition, seemingly keen to invite British proposals. Overall, however,

German industry viewed Turkish industrialization as a major domain of future orders for its

exporters.49 And although German political influence in the Middle East was simply too small in

comparison to Britain’s to bring Turkey into an alliance with Hitler’s regime, nevertheless the

scale of German exports – capital goods and arms – quite probably was responsible for Turkish

neutrality until the very end of the war. The enormous amounts of deliveries to Turkey

guaranteed by the German state strongly indicates both the importance of the Turkish market for

47 Fried. Krupp AG Abteilung Ost to the Reichswirtschaftsministerium, Dec. 21, 1934. BABL R2/17334. 48 N.B. I am waiting on documents from the Bundesarchiv that give exact amounts. This sum is calculated on the basis of a report from 1932 listing RM 55 million in deliveries already guaranteed, combined with RM 40 million that were guaranteed as part of a second Krupp railway construction contract negotiated in 1934. “Niderschrift der Sitzung des Export-Garantie-Ausschuss für Regierungsgeschäfte”, Dec. 5, 1932. BABL R3101/19299. 49 Reinhard Hüber, Deutschland und der Wirtschaftsaufbau des Vorderen Orients (Türkei, Ägypten, Iran, Irak, Syrien-Libanon, Palästina) (Stuttgart: F. Enke, 1938). Ter-Nedden (RWM), “Ausführungen über die Türkei”, Oct. 28, 1938. BABL R2/17226.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

28

German exports, and the creditworthiness of the Turkish state – which is to say, the likelihood

that Turkey would remain politically and economically sovereign, well into the future.50

Meanwhile, competition was intensifying for all contracts related to the Turkish

industrialization drive. Groups of British firms had begun looking for contracts as early as 1930,

and the British Foreign Office closely monitored the activities of German firms in Turkey. For a

time the Turkish government, anxious to husband scarce foreign exchange, was only awarding

Five Year Plan contracts to countries with which it had a clearing agreement. British exporters

encouraged their own government to conclude such a treaty, in order that they might compete for

the large orders that were steadily issuing from the Turkish state banks.51 British firms felt that

they were facing an uphill battle, since “whereas our continental competitors approached [the

Turkish government] as a compact engineering-cum-financial group, United Kingdom firms

merely wasted their time by going out to Turkey before constructive financial proposals have

been settled even in principle.”52 British engineering firms were eager to interest themselves in

Turkish proposals, but the question of financing was, as ever, paramount. British firms were not

in a position to extend long-term credits themselves (as their German competitors, with

guarantees from the German Reich, appeared prepared to do), but would instead require

financing from the City of London. City bankers, in turn, would require good security from the

Turkish government before they would consent to extend such long-term credits, especially

given Turkey’s severe shortage of foreign exchange, which would limit its ability to remit

50 British officials held a similar view: “whatever may be thought of the financial and economic measures of the present Turkish régime, that régime is most unlikely to collapse politically, and, unless it collapses politically, it is almost bound to succeed in building up a state which in a few years will be a much more valuable friend, and incidentally a much more valuable customer (though possibly a different kind of customer), than the Turkey of today.” Foreign Office position on the Turkish steel works, Mar. 17, 1936. FO 371/20070, E1457/23/44. 51 Board of Trade to Metropolitan-Vickers Electrical Export Co., Jan. 9, 1935. FO 371/19031, E244/25/44. 52 Record of Interview at the Board of Trade with Commander W. R. Gilbert, head of the Metropolitan-Vickers mission to Turkey. Jan. 9, 1935. FO 371/19031, E244/25/44.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

29

payment for British equipment in Sterling.53 On these grounds German industry was at a

considerable competitive advantage. As a British official explained,

the [German] manufacturers get paid in cash by discounting the Turkish bonds with the Consortium of German banks & it is the latter . . . which bear the risk . . . Since the 1931-1932 reorganization of German banking system, the German government has acquired a virtually controlling interest in the banks, & the banks, in turn have long had a controlling interest in the German iron and steel industry. The situation is therefore that the German government is acquiring a dominant interest in the industrialization of Turkey & it is willing to pay the price for it, in view of the political considerations involved & the immediate economic benefit of finding employment for her industrial workers.54 A combine of British government and industry began to organize itself to compete for the

Turkish iron and steel contract in early 1936. British officials had concluded that the

participation of the Export Credit Guarantee Department would be necessary – not just to

provide a guarantee but in fact to issue a loan to the Turkish government for the purchase of

equipment, since British banks had apparently no appetite for the risk. Given the congenital

conservatism of the British Treasury, and what they felt was the likelihood of a Turkish default

on the Ottoman debt, British officials considered it necessary to undertake a detailed survey of

Turkish finances before they could extend such an official credit.55 Although the Payments

Agreement concluded in 1935 was meant for “normal trade” between the two countries, British

officialdom saw in Turkey’s statist industrialization the end of “normal trade,” and pointed to “a

risk that if we do not manage to get hold of this key order for the Turkish iron and steel works,

and, so far as may be possible, for other capital goods which may be needed by Turkey, we may .

. . find ourselves, in a few years, faced with a loss of the market for consumption goods and

without any footing at all in the market for capital goods”.56 The British were leery of sending a

financial mission to Turkey for fear it might signal the possibility of raising a private loan in 53 “Visit to Turkey of representative of Metropolitan Vickers”, Feb. 1, 1935. FO 371/19031, E840/25/44. 54 “Contracts for Public Works in Turkey”, Mar. 29, 1935. FO 371/19031, E2200/25/44. 55 “Financial Situation in Turkey.” Jan. 13, 1936. FO 371/20070, E245/23/44. 56 Ibid.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

30

London. Meanwhile if they could not figure out a way to extend credits to the Turkish regime

they “shall be doing nothing to prevent a default on the Ottoman Public Debt, and . . . leaving the

commercial field open to our competitors with unfortunate political results”.57 Indeed, British

officials realized that,

if we miss the opportunity of getting the steel works contract, it will certainly go to Krupps. We know that the Germans are prepared to make almost any sacrifice in order to re-establish their economic – and probably now their ultimate political – influence in the Middle East. They have been making a great drive in Persia with considerable success. They are now within an ace of obtaining a large railway contract in northern Iraq. If they secure this steel works contract in Turkey too, it will materially help them to consolidate their position throughout the Middle East, and we may well have cause to regret, not only economically but politically, the passive attitude which will have made us lose this opportunity.58

While the question of British financing hung in the balance, as observers waited to see if

the Turks would make payments on the next coupon of the Ottoman debt due in late May, the

Turkish government had opened conversations with the U.K. branch of the H. A. Brassert & Co.

engineering firm for a contract totaling roughly £2.5 million (approx. $12 million). Not wishing

to overburden the existing Anglo-Turkish payments agreement with a raft of new imports into

Turkey unmatched by any corresponding increase in Turkish exports to the U.K., and finding the

Turks unwilling to pledge another revenue stream (e.g. oil royalties owed them by the

Government of Iraq from a 1926 agreement) as security, U.K authorities began looking for more

creative means of assuring that their exporters would get paid. Sensitive to the bureaucratic

57 “Financial situation in Turkey.” Jan. 16, 1936. FO 371/20070, E254/23/44. 58 Ibid. The U.K. government was divided on the steel works question between on the one hand the Treasury, interested to protect U.K. bondholders and the Board of Trade, looking to the market for “Manchester piecegoods”, and on the other side the FO, who were monitoring the German economic-cum-political advance in the Middle East, and the ECGD and the Department of Overseas Trade, which were convinced that the Turks – and many other countries – would soon render themselves self-sufficient in consumer goods, meaning that the future for British exports must lie with capital goods producers. The departments in favor of industrial credits to Turkey could also count on the support of Service Departments represented in the Committee of Imperial Defense’s Sub-Committee on Industrial Intelligence, who considered Turkish friendship essential to British goals in the eastern Mediterranean, and who also saw the iron and steel works as fundamental to any Turkish re-armament program, thus positioning Britain well to secure contracts for Turkish military as well as industrial investments. “Turkish financial situation: iron and steel works contract”, Mar. 19, 1936. FO 371/20070, E1583/23/44.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

31

obstacles to their goals, the Turkish Ministry of National Economy, likely in consultation with

Brassert & Co., crafted a proposal for a concerted effort to increase British imports of strategic

minerals from Turkey, through sale of which the Turkish government would receive sterling that

could in turn be transferred to British exporters.59 This would be done through creation of an

“Anglo-Turkish Comptoir” outside of the existing payments agreement. This comptoir would be

overseen directly by Brassert & Co. and would have the right to direct sales of certain Turkish

products – especially strategic minerals like copper, chrome, molybdenum, and manganese – to

the U.K. Brassert & Co. was essentially committing itself to find buyers for these minerals; the

British government, through the ECGD, was in turn assuming the risk that Brasserts would fail

to line up any customers.60 The ECGD was favorable towards this proposal, although it

stipulated that the mines whose output would be sold through the comptoir need be under the

supervision of British engineers. For its willingness to provide a credit against the sale of these

raw materials, it insisted that provision be made for sale of these raw materials to other markets,

in case there were no buyers in the U.K. It estimated that the order would provide direct

employment of British labor amounting to 10,000 man years, and double that in indirect

employment. It saw further advantages in that Britain was at the time considered behind its

German and American competitors in the technique of steel plant construction, and such an order

might help it catch up. Further it would provide the British with a captive supply of strategic

minerals, and the Turks with a reserve of sterling, which could in turn only further stimulate

British employment. Both the ECGD and the DOT feared that if they failed to secure this order,

59 “Financial position in Turkey; iron and steel works project.” Mar. 7, 1936. FO 371/20070, E254/23/44. 60 Ibid.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

32

Turkey would increasingly become a German sphere of influence – technically, economically,

and perhaps even politically.61

Even with favorable pronouncement from the Committee on Imperial Defense – the high

temple of British grand strategy – still the Chancellor of the Exchequer would not consent to a

£2.5 million credit for Turkey, on the rather obtuse grounds (given the elaborate comptoir

arrangement surrounding the proposal, and the repeated assurances from knowledgeable British

sources that the Turkish government was entirely solvent, just lacking in foreign exchange) that

the Turks should not be redirecting export earnings away from meeting their obligations to

bondholders and commercial creditors.62 In fact the will to overrule pure creditor interests was

strong. According to the Foreign Office, “the transactions now under consideration have

considerable political importance, and should be considered from the point of view of British

interests as a whole rather than from the interests of the Ottoman Public Debt Council.”63 The

Treasury did consent to an ECGD proposal to send a team of experts to Turkey to make a study

of Turkish “exportabilities” so as to determine just to what extent Turkish exports to the U.K.

could be increased. Against economizing proposals by the Board of Trade, who thought that the

British Commercial Secretary in Turkey should conduct the investigation, the departments

advocating support for the steel works (FO, DOT, ECGD) insisted that Brasserts, as the agency

that had already had discussions with British firms about their capacity to absorb additional

Turkish exports of raw materials, be dispatched for the purpose, even if it meant incurring an up-

front expense and making a preliminary commitment to the Turkish government that a British

61 “Financial situation in Turkey: Iron and Steel Works Contract” (ECGD and BOT memos on the subject), Mar. 18, 1936. FO 371/20070, E1457/23/44. 62 “Financial situation in Turkey: Iron and Steel Works Contract” (Waley, Treasury to Nixon, ECGD), Mar. 23, 1936. FO 371/20071, E1589/23/44. 63 “Export credits for Turkish steel works order,” Jan. 6, 1936. FO 371/20081, E76/39/44.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

33

government credit would indeed issue from a favorable inquiry.64 In the event, Somerville Smith

of the ECGD and Mackenzie of Brassert & Co. traveled to Turkey in early June to meet with

officials of the Ministry of National Economy, the Sumer Bank, the Mining administration, and

the Ministry of Finance. Several engineers stayed on for longer to make detailed studies of the

mines that would be attached to the Comptoir. The Comptoir itself was no simple matter, as the

French had their own Turkish Comptoir for sales in France towards repayment of the Ottoman

Debt, and were jealous that the new British organization might infringe on their payments; the

Germans meanwhile through their barter arrangements with the Turks had taken control of

something like 50% of Turkish exports, the proceeds from which the Turks could only use to buy

German goods. Eager as the British were to secure their steel works contract, they maintained the

solidarity of creditors, assuring the French that any wrong done to French bondholders would be

viewed every bit as severely in London as if British nationals had been the victims of

mistreatment. In the event, the British mission examined every single exportable commodity in

Turkey, ranging from timber to figs to molybdenum, and concluded that there was in fact a

tremendous capacity to increase exports and generate sufficient foreign exchange earnings to be

able to pay off the steel works credit in a few years. Under these conditions the British

investigators considered it advantageous that the Turkish government either owned, or was likely

soon to own, all of the mines in question, since this enabled them to dispose of the metals mined

as they saw fit.65 In essence, the Turkish and British governments were joining together to

organize Turkey’s domestic economy and its foreign trade in such a way that would create a

64 “Proposed investigation of Turkish exportabilities to United Kingdom.” Apr. 27, 1936. FO 371/20071 E2340/23/44. 65 H. Somerville Smith, “Report on Turkish Finances” Aug. 8, 1936. FO 371/20072, E5065/23/44.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

34

lasting partnership between Turkish industrialization and British capital goods production. Any

scruples about state intervention in economic life were dispensed with summarily.

The security of the project having been settled through the comptoir arrangement, there

remained the question of the interest rate on the official loan. This was a matter of pride on both

sides of the negotiations. For their part the Turks demanded of the British terms no worse than

the 5.5 % that Krupp – backed by the German government – was offering. The British

meanwhile fretted that anything less than 6.5 % would lead other countries that had received

official credits from the ECGD to protest. It is an indication of the international power dynamics

of the moment that the Turks bargained the Brits down to a number – 5.5 % – below what British

officials had instructed their negotiators was the absolute lowest they could offer.66 It is also a

reflection of Turkish officials’ strong desire to use British participation in the steel works to

balance out the large German presence in Turkish industrialization that they ultimately accepted

a proposal with financial terms that were slightly less generous than Krupp had offered.

The comptoir agreement was finally signed in late September, making possible final

negotiations on the steel plant itself. At the 11th hour Brasserts shocked the ECGD by asking that

the size of the British orders be increased from £2 million to £3 million, and that instead of the

ECGD guaranteeing 60% of the risk, as had initially been proposed, they assume the entirety of

the risk of non-payment, since British manufacturers were so busy with home orders that they

were only willing to undertake large foreign sales if they bore no risk on the transactions at all.67

On Nov. 17th, a week before the Sumer Bank was scheduled to announce the awarding of the

66 See the exchange of telegrams between Somerville Smith in Ankara and Nixon (both ECGD) in London around June 19th, 1936. FO 371/20082, E3643/39/44 and E3676/39/44. See also Nixon to Rendel (FO), Oct. 8, 1936, describing just how generous a financial deal he felt the ECGD had extended to the Turkish government. FO 371/20082, E6395/39/44. 67 Record of conversation between Baggallay (FO) and Somerville Smith (ECGD), Oct. 28, 1936. FO 371/20082, E6772/39/44.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

35

contract, the Turkish Ministry of National Economy suddenly informed Brassert & Co. that if

they did not reduce their price by £400,000 and agree to an interest rate of 5.5 %, the contract

would be awarded to Krupp. British officials attributed the abrupt switch to a recent visit to

Turkey by Schacht, “and to the fact that under his influence Krupps are out to get the contract at

an un-commercial price.”68 The ECGD responded by slashing the insurance premium that

Brasserts was to pay to them, enabling a reduction in the overall price of £250,000. They would

not agree to an interest rate lower than 6%, although they did hold out the possibility that the rate

could be lowered in two years time. The power of the Turkish negotiating position was, however,

such that even after they had agreed to forfeit most of the premium for the 100% credit guarantee

they were offering to Brasserts, still the Brits had to plead with their counterparts that “if they

persist in demanding an additional reduction they must realize that in effect they are asking for a

cash gift from the [British] Treasury.”69 After making clear that at last they could lower their

price no further, the Turkish Ministry of National Economy accepted a proposal from Brassert &

Co. for a total price of £2,745,000 at 5.5 % interest.70 The contract was signed – after some last-

minute panic in London – on Dec. 2, 1936. Mackenzie, the Brasserts director who led the

negotiations with the Turkish government, declared proudly that the contract represented

“England’s first act of co-operation in Turkey’s industrial plan. In the near future you will see

the happy results of the great confidence which Atatürk’s Turkey has inspired in the world of

68 Record of FO conversation with Somerville Smith, Nov. 19, 1936. FO 371/20082, E7262/39/44. 69 Sir Percy Loraine, U.K. ambassador to Turkey, to FO, Nov. 21, 1936. FO 371/20082, E7290/39/44. 70 N.B. In fact the Turkish government accepted this offer over one identical in total cost, but with a different coupon rate (£2,690,000 at 6%). Clearly the Turkish government attached enormous amounts of prestige to the interest rate they were paying to foreign contractors for long-term credit – the Brits referred to Turkish “amour propre.” I do not yet have direct evidence to substantiate this claim, but I strongly suspect that this attitude is an expression of anti-imperialist politics. Imperialism for countries like Turkey was in part the experience of being charged high rates of interest for long-term borrowing, when countries higher up in the global credit hierarchy constructed in the financial capitals of Europe could borrow at much lower rates. See the truly brilliant exposition, based on the archives of the Credit Lyonnais, in Marc Flandreau and Frédéric Zumer, The Making of Global Finance 1880-1913, Development Centre Studies (Paris: OECD, 2004).

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

36

English capital and industry.” It was “the first time the British Government and the City had

guaranteed and financed an enterprise in Turkey. There was no need . . . to stress the financial

consequences for both countries.”71

Brazil

Since the mid-19th century, Brazil had been steadily incorporated into the international

economy. As the world’s largest producer of coffee, foreign capital, especially British, had

poured into Brazil to finance the construction of railways and other public utilities in order to

facilitate the outward flow of coffee and the inward flow of European manufactured goods.

Throughout the Republican period a coffee planting aristocracy (Brazil was unique among South

American countries in having spent most of the 19th century under monarchical rule; its planters

thus all carried titles of nobility) had dominated the country’s political life, and, in the eyes of

nationalists then and nationalist historiography since, maintained the country in a position of

dependence on foreign capital. In 1910, an international congress of geologists declared to the

world that Brazil possessed an unsurpassed quantity of the highest grade iron ore, and from that

moment schemes to link the exploitation of Brazil’s iron ore to a Brazilian steel industry

proliferated. Before the war these schemes involved concessions to Brazilian businessmen, but

none of them had the capital necessary to move more than a trifling quantity of ore, since the ore

was situated in the interior of Minas Gerais, with only a small, narrow-gauge railway to transport

it to the coast. Success would require massive amounts of capital to build a railway with much

higher capacity across difficult terrain. Brazil’s paltry supplies of coking coal, located in an

71 Sir P. Loraine to the FO, Dec. 4, 1936, quoting local paper “Ulus” of Dec. 3. FO 371/20082, E7695/39/44.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

37

entirely different part of the country from the ore and from the major markets of Rio de Janeiro

and São Paulo, constrained the prospects for a domestic steel industry.

Serious efforts to pursue the iron and steel project began in 1919, when a group of British

capitalists hired the American Percival Farquhar to negotiate a concession from the Federal and

Minas Gerais governments and to raise investment capital in New York. Before the war Farquhar

had been the largest capitalist in Brazil, constructing a massive paper empire of railways, ports,

and timber properties. Price declines in 1915 had ruined him, and his Brazil Railway Company

suffered a spectacular bankruptcy. To Brazilians he was the epitome of “Yankee imperialism”.

Large and influential constituencies opposed his efforts to develop the iron and steel industries

from the moment he began.

Farquhar’s woefully unsuccessful attempts to make his scheme come off have been

detailed many times over. Their only significance here is that because of Farquhar, for Brazilians

the question of a national steel industry was even more charged with nationalist sentiment than

the Turkish or Chinese cases. At the same time, perhaps because it faced less existential threats

to its status as a sovereign nation, and because of a relatively thriving capitalism and capitalist

class especially in São Paulo, Brazil under Getulio Vargas moved more cautiously toward an

embrace of statist industrialization in the 1930s. But the crisis of primary producers in the 1930s

hit Brazil as hard as any country in the world. Coffee prices collapsed and Brazil went into

default on nearly all of its considerable sovereign debt. Throughout the 1930s relations between

Brazil and both the U.S. and the U.K. – the country’s two largest international creditors – were

seriously strained. Meanwhile Brazil produced commodities, especially cotton, that were

attractive to Nazi Germany, and thanks to clearing agreements Germany catapulted ahead of both

countries to become Brazil’s largest trading partner by 1935. The rise of German influence in

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

38

this large South American country, with a significant German population, an organized fascist

movement and a president who professed admiration for Mussolini and Salazar troubled

American policymakers. Increasingly the U.S. government demonstrated a willingness to woo

Brazil away from Germany. It found that favorable settlement of Brazil’s sovereign debt and

official credits for developmental projects were the principal domains within which the

Brazilians wished to negotiate. More than anything else, Vargas’s government wanted its steel

mill, and he did everything he could to persuade the U.S. government that the political

allegiances of his country would go to whichever country was willing to supply it with one on

competitive terms.

Until the Estado Novo coup in 1937, when Vargas, with the aid of senior military leaders,

officially established himself as dictator and introduced a constitution modeled off of Salazar’s

Portugal, progress on the steel project was limited to several rounds of investigation. In 1937,

three different German firms – Krupp, DEMAG (backed by the Vereinigte Stahlwerke, which

had a controlling interest in the firm) and the GHH – all became interested in the Brazilian

proposal, a project whose value they estimated to be the enormous sum of RM 200 million

(approx. $80 million).72 Krupp was a major supplier of arms to the Brazilian military and

maintained an active presence in the Brazilian capital. The military in turn was the strongest

72 In fact the Vereinigte Stahlwerke and its predecessor firms had been interested in developing Brazilian iron ore and in building a steel works in Brazil since 1924, when they established a joint venture they called “Brasiliana”, with possession of important sources of iron ore. After World War II these holdings became the basis for a major iron ore mining firm, Ferteco, but the evidence I have so far found does not suggest that before the war the Vestag was especially energetic in attempting to develop this business. [cite to Vestag files] Farquhar maintained active contacts especially with Fritz Thyssen of the Vereinigte Stahlwerke throughout the 1930s, continually hoping that the German desire for Brazilian ore would be great enough to move German firms to finance his development scheme. Although he was able to secure forward contracts for delivery, he was not able to pry investment capital loose from the German concern.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

39

advocate of closer ties with Germany.73 Between 1936 and 1938 one of Krupp’s most senior

officers, Friedrich von Bülow, was stationed full time in Brazil to negotiate with the Brazilian

military and government.74 Von Bülow maintained an especially active relationship with Olava

Egídio de Sousa Aranha, co-founder of the major domestic concern Monteiro-Aranha, and

cousin of Oswaldo Aranha, Vargas’s pro-American foreign minister. Unlike his cousin, Olavo

favored closer ties with Germany, and actively worked official and unofficial channels to win

support for the Krupp proposal.75 Although Krupp’s German competitors anticipated financing

the Brazilian project through the Dresdner Bank with guarantees from the Reich, Krupp

proposed a more direct means of payment. They would extend no loan, but would instead barter

the German machinery and equipment for additional deliveries of Brazilian ore, coffee, and

cotton, German demand for which was essentially unlimited.76

It is certainly possible to view Krupp as an instrument of German foreign policy, or even

an author of it (many contemporaries, including the U.S. and German governments, essentially

did). However, not only do documents confirm that Krupp was entirely able to make up its own

mind about which international opportunities it pursued, they also confirm that even in the period

of Nazism greatest ascendancy, political considerations did not necessarily trump economic

ones. In 1937 I.G. Farbenindustrie, the largest corporation in Germany, sent a senior

representative on a year-long tour of Latin America, during which time he met with nearly one

73 Frank D McCann, The Brazilian-American Alliance, 1937-1945 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974). 74 From 1932 to 1936 von Bülow was Krupp’s Berlin representative and personal assistant to Gustav Krupp von Bohlen und Halbach. After 1938 he ran the Gruson works armaments factory in Magdeburg. Later he was the senior Krupp officer in charge of military procurement. He was one of the 12 Krupp directors tried at Nuremberg, and served 12 years in prison. 75 Some of the scope of Monteiro-Aranha’s business relationships can be seen in the Schroders Archive, as both the British and U.S. branches of the J. Henry Schröder & Co. worked closely with Monteiro-Aranha. See especially Box SH-000082, Doc 30. “Correspondence, 1930 to 1940, JHSBC, Dr. Olavo Egydio de S. Aranha Jr, Brazil, Argentina, Coffee, 1930s.” 76 [citation from the von Bülow files in the Krupp archive]

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

40

thousand different individuals, ranging from local businessmen and elected officials to

international bankers, close to 200 of whom were Brazilian. In his nearly 200 page report back to

his board, he could barely contain his enthusiasm for the will to industrialization on the part of

all sectors of Latin American life. It is worth quoting at length:

One can speak of a new and modern epoch of the colonial – or better colonization – problem in a time of a tendency towards nationalization and industrialization. It is evident that in the long run all countries and colonies strive for independence. The presently existing relationship between mother country to colony will develop more and more in the direction of the relationship England has developed to its Dominions. That is, the mother country must be an ally and not an exploiter. Carrying the analogy to the young independent countries, which today display a powerful momentum in every way, it would mean that – viewed in the long term – the country that most secures its political and economic influence will be the one that has been most active as an ally in the development of existing opportunities.77

It seems likely, then, that even in the late 1930s Krupp’s – and German industry’s in general –

pursuit of foreign opportunities was linked to a long-term view of growth sectors in the world

economy, and the importance of securing a foothold in those sectors early.

Brazil used the Krupp offer as a bargaining chip with the United States from 1937 on.

Although Marcelo de Paiva Abreu is almost certainly right to argue that the United States would

never have permitted a loss of its commercial and political ascendancy in Brazil to Nazi

Germany78, nevertheless American policymakers responded as though such a threat was real.

American determination to keep Brazil close in what policymakers increasingly felt was a likely

international conflict with Germany corresponded, as discussed above, with a pronounced shift

in the nature of American thinking about foreign economic policy. Even as Brazil entered a

second round of default in 1937, reneging on agreements signed just two years prior, the

77 Dr. Max Ilgner (IG Farbenindustrie) "Die Exportförderung im Rahmen des Vierjahresplanes, angefertigt auf Grund von Erfahrungen aus der Exportförderungs-Praxis und von Beobachtungen auf den ausländischen Märkten." BABL R3101/33441. 78 Marcelo de Paiva Abreu, “Anglo-Brazilian Economic Relations and the Consolidation of American Pre-Eminence in Brazil, 1930-1945,” in Latin America, Economic Imperialism, and the State: The Political Economy of the External Connection from Independence to the Present, ed. Christopher Abel and Colin M. Lewis (London  ; Dover, NH: Athlone, 1985), 379–93.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

41

Treasury and increasingly even the State Department concerned themselves more with trade,

investment, and developmental aid, and less with making bondholders whole.79 The Export-

Import Bank was their vehicle. In 1938 ExIm financed a large purchase of railway equipment for

one of Brazil’s state-owned railways. And in 1939, with encouragement from the State

Department, the United States Steel Corporation sent a top-level mission to Brazil to study the

possibility of constructing an integrated iron and steel works.

The Greenwood commission reported extremely favorably on conditions in Brazil,

including even the quality of Brazilian coal, so long assumed to be insufficient for the economic

smelting of pig iron.80 In early 1940, however, going against the urgings of its own experts and

consultants, U.S. Steel’s finance committee decided not to pursue the opportunity presented to it

– to build and have a majority stake in the new steel works – even with probable support from

ExIm. It seems that the American firm both respected and feared the nationalist spirit that was

driving the Brazilian project forward. U.S. Steel’s directors felt there was no assurance that once

completed the mill would not be nationalized. They were unimpressed by Brazil’s record as a

debtor. And they were unpersuaded that building a steel mill in Brazil would not cost the firm an

important export market.81 A link between U.S. corporate capital and Brazilian industrialization

proved too difficult to forge at this juncture.

79 Adamson, “The Failure of the Foreign Bondholders Protective Council Experiment, 1934-1940”. On the growing influence of the Harry White/Adolf Berle view of the world in U.S. policymaking circles in the late 1930s, see Eric Helleiner, Forgotten Foundations of Bretton Woods: International Development and the Making of the Postwar Order (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2014). 80 William C. Burdett to Secretary of State, “Project for Steel Mill near Rio de Janeiro, Brazil.” Oct. 20, 1939. SDCDF 832.6511/32, NACP. 81 U.S. Steel’s internal debate over whether or not to participate in the Brazilian steel works is revealed in extraordinary detail in a special report that several company experts prepared in late December, 1939. “Proposed Participation by the Corporation in the Brazilian Steel Industry,” Dec. 29, 1939. 227-12: “United States Steel Corporation, 1939”, Thomas W. Lamont Collection, Harvard Baker Library Historical Collections. Some of Lamont’s views are laid out in Lamont to Voorhees (U.S. Steel Finance Committee), Jan. 4th, 1940. 227-13, “United States Steel Corporation, 1940”. TWLC.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

42

The U.S. government stepped rapidly into the breach. By mid-1940 the U.S. was making

clear to Brazilian authorities that it was prepared to extend an official loan to the Brazilian

government of $20 million for the purchase of steelmaking equipment; that it would select top

quality American engineers to design the works, oversee construction, and train Brazilian

engineers (in the U.S. and on site); and that it would do so on incredibly favorable terms.

American consulting engineers eagerly solicited the State Department and ExIm for the

business.82 Each time the negotiations hit a stumbling block, the American ambassador would

frantically wire that Krupp’s officers were beating down Vargas’s door to sweeten their offer.83

He stressed that at that moment the steel mill was the single most important matter in diplomatic

relations between the two countries.

After a debate in Congress over whether to increase the authority of the Export-Import

Bank to enable it to make this sort of loan, in September 1940 the deal was signed, providing for

a loan on five years’ term at only 4%. Construction began the next year, and the President

Vargas Works were inaugurated in 1943, a rapid timeline made possible by U.S. official

decisions to raise the export priority level of the necessary equipment to a par with requirements

for the war effort. For the Vargas government, solving “our national steel problem” was an

enormous public relations success. For the Americans it was a “practical demonstration of the

Good Neighbor policy.” And while it is easy to attribute the whole matter to power political

concerns, in fact without the conviction on the part of the business actors that industrialization in

countries like Brazil was a certainty, and that large orders would go in the future to whichever 82 Hermann Brassert himself called on the State Department, as did representatives of McKee & Co and Ford, Bacon & Davis, the firm U.S. Steel had hired in the 1930s to oversee a sweeping reorganization of its business, and whose advice to pursue business in Brazil and other developing countries it had ignored. U.S. officials ultimately chose McKee, finding Brassert’s political loyalties to be dubious. 83 John D Wirth, The Politics of Brazilian Development 1930-1954 (Stanford, Ca: Stanford Univ. Press, 1970), chap. 3; Oliver J. Dinius, Brazil’s Steel City: Developmentalism, Strategic Power, and Industrial Relations in Volta Redonda, 1941-1964 (Stanford, Calif: Stanford University Press, 2010), chap. 1.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

43

country supplied the necessary inputs for that process, it is difficult to see how any of these deals

would have been struck. As with the British in Turkey, but even more so, since Brazil was in fact

one of the world’s most egregious defaulters on its sovereign debt in the 1930s84, the U.S.

government and capital goods exporters had to overcome the opposition of creditor interests and

their representatives in government in order to finance a project like the Brazilian steel works.

Like in Britain, but more so, American officials had to defeat an entrenched protectionist lobby

in Congress in order to enter into cooperative projects with Latin American governments that

stood a real chance of hurting the foreign sales of American producers, even if they were likely

to increase the sales of other products.85

Of the four projects considered here, two were actually built. Britain successfully won a

steel works contract for its exporters with Turkey; the U.S. warded off German advances with a

winning offer for Brazil. Neither the Chinese Central Government nor the Cantonese regional

government could persuade potential partners in the U.S., Britain, or China that there was any

real likelihood of being repaid. Because of strong competition between national units, the

Brazilian and Turkish governments were both able to secure deals on incredibly favorable terms.

In both cases the newly founded industries belonged to the government, with foreigners having

84 Marcelo De Paiva Abreu, “Brazil as a Debtor, 1824–1931,” The Economic History Review 59, no. 4 (Nov., 2006): 765–87, doi:10.1111/j.1468-0289.2006.00359.x; Eichengreen, Barry and Richard Portes, “Debt and Default in the 1930s: Causes and Consequences,” European Economic Review 30 (1986): 599–640; Barry Eichengreen, “Historical Research on International Lending and Debt,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 2 (Spring 1991): 149–69. 85 That the U.S. planned to aid the industrialization of Latin America was major bone of contention for Republican protectionists. Said one member of Congress, “Jesse Jones . . . states . . . that the primary purpose of this bill is to industrialize South America. South America at the present time imports many of its manufactured products from the United States[.] . . . I deplore the fact that this Congress might by the enactment of this bill destroy one of the largest markets for manufactured goods, by taking our taxpayers’ money to industrialize practically the only market we may have left after the wars in Europe and Asia are a matter of history.” Congressional Record–House, Aug. 20, 1940, p. 10615.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

44

no claim on profits. In both cases the interest rates were low and the credit terms were long. The

Turkish government had to set up an elaborate payments arrangement to deal with a shortage of

sterling, but in no way did this appear as a threat to Turkish sovereignty. Turkey had to commit

to buying all of its equipment from Britain, and Brazil had to do the same with the U.S.

Important positions for foreign technicians were insisted upon – but only for the first few years

of operations, where in any event there were no qualified domestic technicians to begin with.

Both deals were unmitigated successes in international economic relations for both regimes.

Throughout much of the 20th century it has been assumed that competition for markets in

peripheral countries is a formula for subordinating those countries to the imperialist core. It can

be this, but this paper is meant to show that it can be the exact opposite as well. The factors

determining which type of relationship prevails are myriad86, but what appears to have been most

important in the interwar period is whether the sovereignty of the peripheral country was firmly

enough established that the possibility for overt political subordination was off the table, and

whether that country’s regime had enough directive power over its domestic economy to be a

credible partner in capital accumulation. The Chinese viewed the interest of Japan, which openly

sought the destruction of Chinese sovereignty, in Chinese economic development as an

imperialist threat. They saw British, German, and American interest – all countries that were

committed to Chinese sovereignty – as a bulwark in the cause of an integral China. Brazilians

feared Yankee imperialism, but the combination of a German counterweight to American

economic penetration and what Brazilians saw as the good faith of Roosevelt’s Good Neighbor

policy meant that cooperative relations were possible with the U.S. as well. In Turkey as well the

86 For a discussion of how what from one angle looks like economic imperialism can from another look like international support for national sovereignty, see Adam Tooze and Martin Ivanov, “Disciplining the ‘Black Sheep of the Balkans’: Financial Supervision and Sovereignty in Bulgaria, 1902-38,” Economic History Review 64, no. 1 (2011): 30–51.

Fertik, “Packaging Industrialization”,

45

German economic presence served as a balance to British imperial designs in the region, and this

was enough to enable cooperative relations between Britain and Turkey in Turkey’s industrial

development. And although Germany failed to win any of the contracts studied in this paper, its

state apparatus for encouraging the export of capital goods secured contracts with developing

countries totaling several hundred million Reichsmarks. In an earlier historical moment,

nationalistic self-assertion on the part of peripheral countries might have simply meant being cut

off from the world economy, for better or for worse. In the interwar period, when the world had

already been so effectively globalized, and when actors across the world became convinced that

the major incipient development in international economic life was the industrialization of

agrarian countries, the nationalistic self-assertion of newly developing countries was greeted

with proposals for the forging of even tighter international economic relations.