Managerial Moral Hazard and Bond Covenants

57
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=611801 Managerial Moral Hazard and Bond Covenants 1 by Sudheer Chava, Praveen Kumar, and Arthur Warga 2 May 26, 2007 1 We thank an anonymous referee for very helpful comments. We also thank Michael Bradley, Martin Dierker, Yaniv Grinstein, Jean Helwege, Kose John, Dmitry Livdan, Milton Harris, Roni Michaely, Amiy- atosh Purnanandam, Latha Ramchand, Michael Roberts, Steve Ross, Matt Spiegel, Sheridan Titman, Stuart Turnbull, and Toni Whited for helpful comments or discussions and Andrew Metrick for providing us the G-index data. We especially thank Annette Poulsen for detailed comments at the WFA (2005) Meetings in Portland. All remaining shortcomings are our responsibility. 2 Chava is from the Mays School of Business, Texas A&M University; email: [email protected]. Ku- mar and Warga are from the C.T. Bauer College of Business, University of Houston; emails: [email protected] and [email protected].

Transcript of Managerial Moral Hazard and Bond Covenants

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=611801

Managerial Moral Hazard and Bond Covenants1

by

Sudheer Chava, Praveen Kumar, and Arthur Warga2

May 26, 2007

1We thank an anonymous referee for very helpful comments. We also thank Michael Bradley, MartinDierker, Yaniv Grinstein, Jean Helwege, Kose John, Dmitry Livdan, Milton Harris, Roni Michaely, Amiy-atosh Purnanandam, Latha Ramchand, Michael Roberts, Steve Ross, Matt Spiegel, Sheridan Titman, StuartTurnbull, and Toni Whited for helpful comments or discussions and Andrew Metrick for providing us theG-index data. We especially thank Annette Poulsen for detailed comments at the WFA (2005) Meetings inPortland. All remaining shortcomings are our responsibility.

2Chava is from the Mays School of Business, Texas A&M University; email: [email protected]. Ku-mar and Warga are from the C.T. Bauer College of Business, University of Houston; emails: [email protected] [email protected].

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=611801

Abstract

Based on an analysis of the agency risk for bondholders from managerial entrenchment and fraud,

and using an e¢ cient contracting framework, we derive and test refutable hypotheses about the

in�uence of managerial moral hazard on the use of bond covenants. Entrenched managers can both

exacerbate and ameliorate bondholder agency risk, and the in�uence of fraud risk on bond covenants

is determined by the quality of information on the �rms�net assets and economic prospects. Our

empirical analysis indicates that managerial entrenchment and the risk of managerial fraud signif-

icantly in�uence the use of covenants, in the direction predicted by our agency-theoretic analysis.

Moreover, the use of covenants responds to cross-sectional variations in the �rms� informational

environment that in�uence the risk of managerial fraud. We also �nd that the Sarbanes-Oxley Act

(SOX) has not signi�cantly in�uenced the overall use of bond covenants; however, the passage of

SOX appears to have reduced the agency risk to bondholders from managerial moral hazard with

respect to investment.

Keywords : Managerial entrenchment, Fraud, Bond covenants, Contracting e¢ ciency

JEL classi�cation codes: G32, G34, D82

1 Introduction

One of the most important, and interesting, implications of the agency cost or �nexus of contracts�

view of the �rm [Jensen and Meckling (1976)] is that corporate bond covenants reduce the cost

of debt. By reducing the discretion of shareholders and managers ex post, and ameliorating the

agency risk faced by bondholders, covenants reduce the cost of debt ex ante. For example, Smith

and Warner (1979, page 121) note that while bond covenants restrict �exibility, they can increase

the value of the �rm at the time bonds are issued by, �. . . reducing the opportunity loss which

results when stockholders of a levered �rm follow a policy which does not maximize the value of

the �rm.�

However, the literature almost exclusively focuses on agency risks faced by bondholders due to

con�icts of interests between equity- and debt-holders. This focus assumes that managers pursue

stockholders�interests in maximizing shareholder value. But the �nance literature has long empha-

sized shareholder-manager con�icts because of the separation between ownership and control by

self-interested managers [Berle and Means (1932)]; the recent spate of corporate scandals, involving

prominent cases of top-management malfeasance, have only intensi�ed this concern.

A substantial body of corporate �nance research examines the mechanisms through which man-

agers entrench themselves [e.g., Stulz (1988) and Shleifer and Vishny (1989)] to pursue policies

� such as, the misuse of free cash �ows for �empire building�[Jensen (1986, 1993), Stulz (1990)

and Hart (1995)] � that do not maximize shareholder value. Moreover, the recent cases of top-

management malfeasance, ranging from seemingly excessive executive compensation awards [e.g.,

Computer Associates, NYSE, and Home Depot] to executive self-dealing and accounting frauds

[e.g., Enron, Tyco, Worldcom], have emphasized the risk to investors of managerial fraud abetted

by overly-optimistic representations of �nancial performance and economic prospects.

In this paper, we analyze the agency risk for bondholders from managerial entrenchment and

fraud. We then formulate and empirically test refutable hypotheses regarding the e¤ects of man-

agerial moral hazard on the inclusion (or exclusion) of the major types of bond covenants. Our

empirical analysis indicates that managerial moral hazard plays a signi�cant and multi-faceted role

on the use of bond covenants and, more generally, on the agency risk for bondholders.

We �rst extend the entrenchment literature to examine the e¤ects of managerial entrenchment

on the agency risk faced by bondholders � as opposed to equity-holders. Importantly, manager-

ial entrenchment does not always increase bondholder risk. This is because entrenched managers

1

sometimes bene�t the bondholders by opposing the interests of shareholders, especially in situa-

tions where bondholder and shareholder interests are in con�ict. For example, entrenchment may

aggravate bondholder risk from the �asset substitution�e¤ect [Jensen and Meckling (1976)], espe-

cially if the �rm has access to risky growth options. But the interests of entrenched managers may

be aligned with bondholders in resisting change of control through takeovers, in contravention of

shareholders�preferences. Our analysis serves to separate situations where entrenched managers

threaten versus support bondholder interests.

In a related vein, the actual risk of managerial fraud for bondholders depends on the quality

of information that is available on the �rm�s performance and prospects. This information quality

is determined partly by the transparency of the �nancial statements (which can be controlled by

insiders) and partly by the regulatory environment.

To derive testable hypotheses on the relationship between managerial moral hazard and the

use of various types of bond covenants, we appeal to the contractual e¢ ciency hypothesis (CEH),

which implies that bond covenants will be included to minimize the sum of agency and (reduced)

operational �exibility costs [see, Smith and Warner (1979)]. Thus, the likelihood of covenant inclu-

sion depends on the intensity of the agency risk to bondholders from shareholders and managerial

moral hazard. We carefully parse factors that determine the intensity of bondholder agency risk in

relation to the four major types of covenants, namely, restrictions on investments, dividend payouts,

subsequent �nancing, and �rm behavior during speci�c events such as when the �rm is a takeover

target.

Our empirical test design builds on the emerging empirical literature on entrenchment [e.g.,

Berger et al. (1997) and Hu and Kumar (2004)] that posits a number of empirical proxies � based

on executive compensation and the strength of internal governance mechanisms � for the extent

of managerial entrenchment. However, there is a signi�cant correlation amongst theses proxies,

and their latent interaction can be problematic for empirical test design. We therefore develop an

entrenchment measure based on principal components analysis. Moreover, to address the risk of

managerial fraud, we examine the impact of the �rms�information environment on the utilization

of bond covenants. We do so by analyzing the in�uence of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX) of 2002,

the transparency of the �rms��nancial statements, and the dispersion in analysts�forecasts. Our

analysis is based on all corporate bonds issued during 1993-2005,1 and contains information on

1We focus attention on this period because our analysis requires information on executive compensation and CEOcharacteristics through S&P�s Execucomp.

2

over 54 covenants.

The principal result of our empirical analysis is that managerial moral hazard has a signi�cant

in�uence on the use of bond covenants. We �nd that managerial entrenchment and the risk of

managerial fraud signi�cantly in�uence the use of covenants, in the direction predicted by the

CEH. That is, corporate bond contracts are contractually e¢ cient in the use of the various types of

covenants by taking into account factors that aggravate or ameliorate the agency risk to bondholders

from managerial moral hazard.

Managerial entrenchment signi�cantly increases the use of investment-related covenants, espe-

cially for high growth option �rms. Moreover, the use of investment restrictions responds to factors

that increase managers� incentives for adopting risky investments and aggressive debt �nancing

policy; for example, in high-growth option �rms, the use of investment restrictions is positively as-

sociated with the sensitivity of the CEO�s wealth with respect to stock price volatility (vega). On

the other hand, �rms with entrenched management are signi�cantly less likely to use restrictions

on dividend payouts and the behavior of the �rm when it is a takeover target. Both individual

entrenchment proxies and the composite entrenchment measure load signi�cantly on the likelihood

of using covenants.

Consistent with our predictions, the use of covenants responds to cross-sectional variations in

the �rms� informational environment that in�uence the risk of managerial fraud. We �nd that

higher �nancial transparency, by reducing the fog around the �rm�s assets in hand, reduces the use

of dividend payout covenants. In addition, the dispersion of analysts�earnings forecasts � being

forward-looking and being correlated with uncertainty of economic prospects � increases the use

of investment-related covenants. Interestingly, the passage of SOX has not signi�cantly in�uenced

the use of covenants; however, it appears to have reduced the agency risk to bondholders from

managerial moral hazard with respect to investment.

Our analysis makes several contributions. We are among the �rst to examine the e¤ect of

managerial entrenchment and fraud on the agency risk faced by bondholders; to emphasize that

entrenched managers can both exacerbate and ameliorate this risk; to empirically measure the risk

of managerial fraud through cross-sectional and time-series variations in the �rm�s information

environment; and, overall, to empirically test the e¤ect of managerial moral hazard on bondholder

agency risk through the observed usage patterns of corporate bond covenants.

Our results add to the literature that studies the design and use of bond covenants. Among other

3

factors, this literature emphasizes �rm size and capital structure [e.g., Malitz (1986) and Begley

(1994)] and growth options [e.g., Nash et al. (2003) and Bradley and Roberts (2003)] as in�uencing

the use of bond covenants. But we �nd that factors associated with managerial entrenchment �

such as, the length of the CEO�s tenure, the CEO�s compensation structure and share ownership,

and the presence of large shareholders � and the risk of managerial fraud � such as, the �rm�s

�nancial transparency and uncertainty about its investment prospects � play a signi�cant role in

the use of bond covenants, even when we control for the factors identi�ed in the literature. These

results substantially expand the rather limited literature on the in�uence of managerial moral

hazard on bond covenants [e.g., Begley and Feltham (1999)].2 Moreover, our results point to a

multi-faceted interaction between managerial moral hazard and bondholder agency risk; they also

highlight the heterogeneity that underlies the use of di¤erent types of bond covenants.

Our analysis therefore has interesting implications for the long-standing literature that examines

bondholder-shareholder con�icts [e.g., Jensen and Meckling (1976) and Myers (1977)], and ways

to mitigate such con�icts [e.g. Green (1984)]. This literature emphasizes problems with respect

to claim dilution, excessive dividend payouts (with liquidating dividends as an extreme case), and

asset substitution. However, the intervening role of entrenched management in ameliorating these

problems � for example, the dividend payout risk and the leveraged takeover risk � or exacerbating

them � for example, asset substitution risk � is rarely considered. The evidence presented in this

paper on the use of bond covenants suggests that bondholders take into account the in�uence

of entrenched management on their overall agency risk. Moreover, an important area for future

research is to examine the implications of the common interests of bondholders and shareholders

in reducing the risk of managerial fraud.

Our results also add to the emerging literature on the role of managerial entrenchment on cor-

porate investment and �nancial policies. For example, Berger et al (1997) �nd that entrenchment

in�uences the choice of �rms�capital structure, and Hu and Kumar (2004) show that entrench-

ment is a signi�cant factor in the determination of �rms�payout policy. Our results here indicate

that managerial entrenchment is also a signi�cant factor in the design and use of bond covenants.

However, and unlike the shareholder-manager con�ict, where entrenchment unambiguously hurts

shareholder interests, managerial entrenchment can support bondholder interests in certain situa-

2Begley and Feltham (1999) examine the e¤ect of managerial opportunism on the inclusion of restrictions ondividend payouts and subsequent �nancing on a sample of 91 non-convertible debentures issued between 1975 and1979. Their analysis indicates that managerial share-ownership has a signi�cant e¤ect on the inclusion of thesecovenants.

4

tions. Moreover, our construction of a composite managerial entrenchment measure is novel and

will be useful in further empirical research on this issue.

Finally, our analysis indicates that �nancial markets are quite sophisticated in adapting the

design of debt contracts to cross-sectional variations in the quality of information available to

assess �rms�net assets position and future prospects. For example, �nancial transparency reduces

the use of covenants restricting dividends and other payouts, but not investment or event speci�c

restrictions, while the dispersion in analysts�forecasts increases the use of investment restrictions,

but not subsequent �nancing or dividend payout restrictions. Similarly, the design of bond contracts

appears to have responded appropriately to structural changes in the quality of �nancial information

regarding �rms following the passage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act in 2002, by reducing the role of

managerial moral hazard in the use of investment restrictions. These results are supportive of the

view that �rms tend toward an e¢ ciently designed �nexus of contracts.�

We organize the remaining paper as follows. Section 2 analyzes the e¤ects of managerial moral

hazard on bondholder agency risk. Section 3 derives the refutable hypotheses and describes the

empirical test design. Section 4 describes the data and discusses the results of the empirical analysis,

and Section 5 concludes.

2 Managerial Moral Hazard and Bondholder Agency Risk

Corporations typically issue bonds with a variety of restrictive covenants � our database includes

over �fty � that restrict issuer behavior and protect bondholders. Following Smith and Warner

(1979), the literature usually classi�es these covenants in four major categories: those that restrict

the �rm�s (1) investments, (2) payouts to shareholders, (3) issuance of debt instruments (subsequent

to the current issue), and (4) response to major events such as when the �rms is a takeover target

and is in �nancial distress. However, and as we noted earlier, the literature almost exclusively

focuses on the agency risk faced by bondholders due to con�icts of interest with shareholders. In

this section, we start by summarizing the agency risk for bondholders when shareholders pursue

their own agenda. But our focus is to develop the agency risk to bondholders from managerial

moral hazard and to explicate the implications of this risk for e¢ cient design of bond covenants.

5

2.1 Bondholder-Shareholder Con�icts

Bondholders can be hurt by excessive payouts to shareholders; by claim dilution due to subsequent

issuance of debt of higher priority; by asset substitution involving a shift toward high risk projects

that bene�t shareholders [e.g., Jensen and Meckling (1976)]; by under-investment when �rms forego

positive NPV projects if they principally bene�t the bondholders [e.g., Myers (1977)]; and, by

acquisitions that increase leverage and a¤ect debt seniority [e.g., Warga and Welch (1993)]. To

address these agency risks, bondholders use covenants that restrict investment policy, subsequent

�nancing policy, payout policy, and management response to takeover bids and �nancial distress.

2.2 Managerial Entrenchment and Agency Risk for Bondholders

From a practical perspective, shareholders cannot easily separate corporate managers involuntarily

from control. Such separation typically requires a successful proxy motion by shareholders [e.g.,

Fluck (1999)], or a takeover [e.g., Shleifer and Vishny (1986)], or a bankruptcy [e.g., Zwiebel (1996)].

Managerial entrenchment is possible because there are transactions costs in shareholder activism

and the market for corporate control, and corporations can avoid bankruptcy through renegotiation

with debt-holders [e.g., Leland (1994)]. Managers may also e¤ectively entrench themselves by mak-

ing manager-speci�c investments [e.g., Shleifer and Vishny (1989)] and by strategically enhancing

their voting rights [e.g., Stulz (1988)].

Entrenchment allows self-interested managers signi�cant �exibility to pursue their own agenda

� for example, undertaking risky projects to expand the asset base under their control. Entrenched

management can clearly threaten bondholder interests in a variety of ways. Opportunistic invest-

ment choice by entrenched managers, who value increasing the size of assets under their control,

i.e., �empire-building� [e.g., Jensen (1986, 1993) and Stulz (1990)] can increase the default risk.

Moreover, indiscriminate �nancing of such investments can upset the seniority of claims of the

existing lenders.

We note that bondholders are substantially constrained in eliminating agency con�icts with

entrenched managers through monitoring and incentive contracts. The objective of most internal

governance mechanisms, such as monitoring by the board of directors, is to protect shareholder

� and not bondholder � interests. Similarly, the board writes long-term incentive contracts with

managers to advance shareholder interests. Thus, bondholders usually protect themselves from

opportunistic managerial behavior only through covenants that restrict such behavior

6

However, the incentives of entrenched managers can sometimes be aligned with bondholder

interests. An important illustration of this occurs when the �rm faces an unfriendly takeover

attempt. As is well known, heavily debt-�nanced takeovers are often inimical to the interests of the

current bondholders because they substantially increase leverage (and hence the default risk) and

can subvert the existing seniority of claims. But while a change of control may be in shareholders�

interests, it will (almost axiomatically) be resisted by an entrenched management. Therefore,

bondholder and entrenched management interests are aligned � against the shareholders � in the

face of unfriendly takeover attempts. In a related vein, entrenched managers resist exceptionally

large dividend payouts to shareholders, because they value liquid assets to �nance �empire building�

and manager-speci�c investments. Therefore, entrenched managers reduce the risk of large dividend

payouts for bondholders.

2.3 Managerial Fraud and Agency Risk for Bondholders

Another important managerial agency risk for bondholders is the possibility of managerial fraud.

To hide self-dealing, to misrepresent the economic prospects of the �rm in order to induce outside

investment, and to set up o¤-balance-sheet transactions and entities, management may strategically

make �nancial statements impenetrable. Therefore, the managerial fraud-related agency risk for

bondholders will be inversely related to the quality of information on the �rm�s net asset position

and its economic (or investment) prospects. Moreover, and unlike the case of entrenchment, the

prospect of managerial fraud is unambiguously inimical to bondholder interests. We thus expect

that the use of covenants will be positively related to the extent of informational asymmetry about

the �rm.

Building on Myers� (1977) categorization of �rm value into the value of assets-in-place and

growth options, we can distinguish between two major types of informational asymmetries between

insiders and outsiders. One type of informational asymmetry is with respect to the true quality

of the �rm�s investment prospects (or the value of its growth options), and is therefore forward-

looking. The other type of informational asymmetry is with respect to the �rm�s current balance

sheet (or the value of its assets in place), and is typically based on the �rm�s past performance

and �nancial policies (i.e., its past capital structure and payout decisions). Clearly, the accounting

or �nancial disclosure regulations focus on the latter, because they require public companies to

follow certain protocols (e.g., the Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP)) in disclosing

7

income and balance sheet entities. But these protocols do not ensure that insiders provide high-

quality information on the form�s economic or investment prospects. Outside analysts generally

provide this type of assessment. In sum, we expect that the use of covenants will be related to the

�rms��nancial transparency and the quality (or precision) of assessment of its economic prospects

by outside analysts.

2.4 Contractual E¢ ciency and Inclusion of Bond Covenants

While covenants are the principal instruments available to bondholders to address agency risk

from shareholders and entrenched managers, including an ever-greater variety of restrictions is

not always in bondholder interest. This is because covenants constrain management�s ability to

implement policies that improve the �rm�s operational position and reduce default risk. Of course,

management attempts to minimize the inclusion of covenants subject to maintaining a given cost

of debt. Therefore, in an e¢ cient contracting outcome, the likelihood of covenant inclusion will be

higher when, (1) there is intrinsic agency risk for bondholders from shareholders or from managerial

moral hazard and (2) there are no alternative mechanisms that will reduce this risk. Conversely,

the likelihood of covenant inclusion is low if either of these conditions is not satis�ed.

Some illustrations will clarify our terminology. Bondholders of �rms with high growth oppor-

tunities face low intrinsic risk of excess shareholder payouts, ceteris paribus, because any positive

cash �ows are largely re-invested by such �rms. Similarly, bondholders of large �rms face lower

intrinsic risk of a leveraged takeover of the �rm, because it is more di¢ cult to �nance and manage

the takeover of large �rms, other things being the same. On the other hand, bondholders face a

higher intrinsic risk of excess dividend payouts from �rms with high default risk, because sharehold-

ers know that they will be unable to extract any cash from the �rm once it declares bankruptcy.

Finally, the demand for payout covenants will be lower if the �rm is incorporated in a State that

imposes �nancial conditions on dividend payouts, such as the �total assets� constraint [see, e.g.,

Peterson and Hawker (1997)].

We conclude, therefore, that other things held �xed, the use of bond covenants will be positively

(negatively) related to the extent of managerial entrenchment whenever entrenchment threatens

(supports) bondholder interests. Similarly, the use of managerial fraud related covenants will

be negatively related to the quality of information regarding the �rms�net assets and economic

prospects.

8

3 Hypotheses and Empirical Test Design

In this section, we build on the foregoing analysis to derive testable hypotheses on the likelihood of

inclusion of the four principal types of bond covenants. We �rst derive hypotheses related to the

agency risk of �empire building�and misuse of free cash �ows because of managerial entrenchment.

We then derive hypotheses relating to the agency risk of managerial fraud. Finally, we specify the

empirical proxies and the data we use to test these hypotheses.

3.1 Entrenchment and Inclusion of Covenants

We start with factors that drive the inclusion (or exclusion) of investment (related) covenants. The

foregoing analysis then suggests that the likelihood of including such covenants will be positively

associated with the extent of managerial entrenchment, other things being the same.3

Hypothesis 1 The likelihood of including investment-related covenants will be positively (nega-

tively) related to factors that enhance (weaken) managerial entrenchment.

The CEH further re�nes the somewhat generic Hypothesis 1. Unlike shareholders, bondholders

are not concerned per se about entrenched managers adopting negative NPV projects. Rather, their

concern is when entrenchment aggravates the well known �asset substitution� e¤ect [Jensen and

Meckling (1976)], where shareholders or managers of levered �rms have an incentive to undertake

risky projects because debt-holders bear the consequences of investment failure. But it is well

known that the asset substitution problem is most acute for �rms with high default probability;

hence, for a given level of entrenchment, the likelihood of including investment restrictions will be

higher for �rms with greater default probability.

Meanwhile, there is an argument in the literature that the investment risk for bondholders is

greater for high-growth option �rms [e.g., Smith and Warner (1979)] when managers presumably

have access to a rich menu of high-growth and high-risk investment opportunities. This argument

implies that the positive in�uence of managerial entrenchment on the use of investment restrictions

will be greater for high-growth option �rms. Another important implication is that the asset

substitution problem for bondholders will be exacerbated in high-growth option �rms if managers

have incentives to take risky investments. Speci�cally, if managers hold stock options with a

3 In the usual fashion, our empirical hypotheses are stated under the �ceteris paribus�(i.e., other things held �xed)assumption. However, for expositional ease we do not make this assumption explicit in these statements.

9

high delta (i.e., their wealth is more sensitive to the stock price), then their incentives for risk-

shifting (toward bondholders) will be higher, ceteris paribus, because such activities bene�t equity

holders. Moreover, bondholder investment risk will also be positively related to the sensitivity of

the managers�wealth to stock volatility, or vega, because a higher vega increases the managers�

incentives for undertaking risky investments and an aggressive debt policy [e.g., Cohen et al. (2000)

and Coles et al. (2006)].

Hypothesis 2 The likelihood of including investment-related covenants will be positively related to

the default risk of the �rm. Moreover, the e¤ects of managerial entrenchment and the delta and

vega of the CEO�s stock option holdings on the use of investment restrictions will be greater for

high-growth option �rms.

Hypotheses 1 and 2 refer to the �rm�s investment policies, generally speaking. However, the

entrenchment hypothesis is especially relevant for investments in the form of mergers with or

acquisitions of other �rms by the issuing �rm. This is because a common instrument for �empire

building� by managers is the expansion of assets through mergers and acquisitions by the �rm.

Thus, we predict that,

Hypothesis 3 The likelihood of including restrictions on mergers and acquisitions by the issuing

�rm will be positively (negatively) related to factors that enhance (weaken) managerial entrench-

ment.

Next, we consider the determinants of including dividend payout covenants. Entrenched man-

agers prefer lower payouts because they use internal resources to expand the assets under their

control [Jensen (1983) and Hart (1995)]. Therefore, for bondholders, the risk of excessive dividend

payouts to shareholders is intrinsically lower with entrenched managers, because such managers

will resist shareholders in relinquishing their control over internal resources.

Hypothesis 4 The likelihood of including dividend payout covenants will be negatively (positively

related to factors that enhance (weaken) managerial entrenchment.

Apart from entrenchment, the use of dividend payout restrictions will also be in�uenced by other

factors that in�uence the intrinsic risk of excessive payout to shareholders. We have mentioned

some of these factors above.

10

Hypothesis 5 The likelihood of including dividend payout restrictions is more likely when the �rm

is small and has low growth-options and when the default risk is high.

Turning to the subsequent �nancing covenants, entrenchment has two opposing e¤ects. For

a given level of investment, managers that are more entrenched will be less likely to do debt

�nancing [see, e.g., Hart and Moore (1995)], and this reduces the subsequent �nancing risk for

bondholders. But, as we have pointed out before, more entrenched managers are also likely to

over-invest because of �empire-building,�which increases the demand for �nancial resources, and

therefore may push management toward debt �nancing. The net e¤ect of managerial entrenchment

on the subsequent �nancing restrictions therefore appears to be ambiguous. Meanwhile, �rms with

higher borrowing costs pose a lower intrinsic risk of subsequent debt �nancing for bondholders.

The e¢ cient contracting framework therefore implies that such �rms will be less likely to include

subsequent �nancing restrictions, ceteris paribus.

Hypothesis 6 Controlling for the investment opportunity set, the likelihood of including subse-

quent �nancing covenants will be negatively (positively) related to factors that enhance (weaken)

managerial entrenchment. Moreover, �rms with low (high) cost of debt will be more (less) likely to

use these restrictions.

We now examine the e¤ects of entrenchment on the use of event-speci�c covenants. For the

reasons mentioned above, bondholders often su¤er when the �rm is taken over, especially in highly

levered transactions. Therefore, the interests of entrenched management will be aligned with bond-

holders in thwarting change of control through takeovers; conversely, the interests of bondholders

and shareholders will con�ict if the shareholders bene�t from the tender o¤er for the �rm. Bond-

holders thus face a lower intrinsic risk of a leveraged takeover of the �rm if shareholder power

to facilitate the takeover is restricted by the corporate charter or if the likelihood of successful

takeovers is low because of large �rm size and presence of poison pills. Finally, we note that high

default risk will be positively associated with the use of �nancial-distress related covenants.

Hypothesis 7 The likelihood of including event-speci�c covenants is higher if, (i) shareholder

power is relatively unrestricted in takeover situations, (ii) there are no signi�cant anti-takeover

provisions in the corporate charter, (iii) the level of managerial entrenchment is low, (iv) the �rm

size is small, (v) the cost of borrowing to �nance takeovers is low, and (vi) the default risk is high.

11

3.2 Managerial Fraud and Inclusion of Covenants

Based on the observed pattern of managerial fraud, we posit that some of the principal types of

fraud are the misuse of investment funds, excessive payouts to managers, and aggressive senior debt

�nancing (of value-destroying activities) � often camou�aged through o¤-balance-sheet transac-

tions. Therefore, better (poor) quality of information regarding the economic performance and

net asset position of the �rm, along with the nature of the �rm�s economic prospects, reduces

(increases) the agency risk bondholders from managerial fraud.

Our framework implies that di¤erent types of informational asymmetries (between insiders and

bondholders) will be correlated with the use of di¤erent types of covenants. This is because particu-

lar types of informational asymmetries exacerbate speci�c types of agency risks for the bondholders.

To explicate, let us compare the implications (for bondholders) of insiders�private information on

the net assets of the �rm versus their private information on the investment or economic prospects

of the �rm. Greater uncertainty about the �rm�s net assets undermines bondholders�ability to mon-

itor payouts to shareholders and additional debt �nancing by the �rm, while greater uncertainty

about the investment prospects undermines bondholders�ability to assess investment-related man-

agerial moral hazard. Thus, we conclude that greater uncertainty regarding the �rms�investment

opportunities will lead to a greater use of investment restrictions, while lower �nancial transparency

or impenetrable �nancial statements will increase the use of restrictions on payouts and subsequent

�nancing.

Hypothesis 8 The likelihood of including payout and subsequent �nancing restrictions will be neg-

atively related to the quality of information regarding the �rms�net assets. And the likelihood of

including investment restrictions will be negatively related to the quality of information regarding

the �rms�investment prospects.

We now specify the proxies and test design we use to confront the foregoing hypotheses with

the data.

3.3 Empirical Proxies

3.3.1 Managerial Entrenchment and Incentives

While the theoretical literature on entrenchment is well developed, empirical tests of the entrench-

ment hypothesis have only recently emerged in the literature [e.g., Berger et al. (1997) and Hu and

12

Kumar (2004)]. As measures of entrenchment, these studies use proxies for CEO power, e¤ective-

ness of internal governance mechanisms, monitoring by large external shareholders, and the CEO�s

incentives for shareholder value-maximization. Building on this literature, we posit that managerial

entrenchment is positively correlated with long CEO tenure, lack of independence of the board of

directors, low share of CEO compensation derived from equity-based incentives, high CEO com-

pensation relative to other top executives, CEO share-ownership, and absence of monitoring by

large shareholders.

However, Hu and Kumar (2004) �nd that some proxies have con�icting e¤ects on entrenchment.

Take, for example, the e¤ects of a signi�cant stock ownership in the �rm by the CEO. On the one

hand, a large personal equity stake by the CEO makes his or her interests intrinsically more aligned

with the shareholders�, and thereby reduces entrenchment. On the other hand, signi�cant stock-

ownership enhances the CEO�s power, improves his or her bargaining position with respect to

the board, and makes unfriendly takeovers more di¢ cult; all of these e¤ects increase managerial

entrenchment.

To address the issue of con�icting e¤ects of various entrenchment proxies, we develop uni�ed

measures of managerial entrenchment. These �rm-speci�c composite entrenchment measures use a

principal components analysis to derive a linear combination of the major entrenchment variables.

Our �rst measure (ENTRP) uses (a combination of) long CEO tenure (LNGCEOTNR), the ratio

of cash or non-performance compensation to total compensation (PCASHCOMP), the ratio of the

CEO�s total compensation to the sum of the compensation of the other four highest paid executives

(CEORELCOMP), the delta of the CEO�s stock-option holdings based on the Black-Scholes option

valuation model (CEODELTA), the CEO�s share-ownership in the �rm (CEOSHROWN ), and the

presence of blockholders (BLOCKHOLDERS ), i.e., shareholders that own greater than 5 percent

of outstanding equity.4 The weights in this linear representation are the elements of the eigenvector

that accounts for the highest percentage of the variation in the said variables. Our second composite

entrenchment measure (ENTRC ) disentangles the e¤ects of managerial compensation from other

proxies for entrenchment. We construct this measure using a smaller set of compensation-based

variable such as CEODELTA, PCASHCOMP, and CEOSHROWN.

4 Information on the percentage of independent directors on the board is available only for less than two-thirds ofthe sample. Therefore, we do not directly include board independence in the principal components analysis, but wecheck its signi�cance as a separate covariate. We also note that while the delta aligns CEO interests with shareholdersand makes the manager less entrenched, there is no theoretical argument for directly linking the vega to entrenchment.

13

3.3.2 Shareholder Power and State Restrictions

Apart from the presence of blockholders,5 shareholder power is also a¤ected by the enumeration of

shareholder rights in the corporate charter. Recently, Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (GIM) (2003)

use a governance index (G-Index ) that scores the extent of managerial power (relative to sharehold-

ers) by examining 24 corporate charter provisions that limit shareholders�ability to monitor and

remove or separate management from control. The index, computed for each �rm by adding one

point for every provision that restricts shareholder rights (or increases managerial power), takes a

value between 0 and 24, with higher values indicating relatively weak shareholder rights or power.

GIM also sub-divide the 24 charter provisions into �ve sub-indices: delay provisions (G-Delay);

protection provisions (G-Protection); voting provisions (G-Voting); miscellaneous provisions (G-

Other); and, state level provisions (G-State). We use these sub-indices in our analysis. Finally, we

also include shareholder power index (E-Index ) of Bebchuk et al. (2004) as a proxy for shareholder

power.

We use a dummy variable to identify if there is a poison pills in the issuing �rm�s charter

(PPILL). An a¢ rmative indicator on poison pills suggests higher managerial power in the face

of a takeover attempt on the �rm. Hence, such �rms would be less likely to use event-related

restrictions, ceteris paribus.

Finally, we also incorporate restrictions, based on the laws of the State of incorporation of the

�rms, that in�uence the intrinsic risk to bondholders of excessive dividend payouts to sharehold-

ers. From the e¢ cient contracting perspective, the intrinsic risk for bondholders of large dividend

payouts is lower (higher) if the �rm is incorporated in a State that restricts (eases) shareholder

�exibility in dividend payouts. We follow Peterson and Hawker (1997) and �ag a �rm if its State

of incorporation allows �nimble dividends,� i.e., if the board of directors can pay cash and prop-

erty dividends out of either earned surplus or the sum of the �preceding and current �scal year�s

earnings�. Because earnings � rather than earned surplus � de�ne the operative limit on the

legality of these �nimble dividends,� the �rm can conceivably declare cash dividends even when

total liabilities exceed total assets. On the other hand, corporate laws of some States impose a

�total asset�constraint on payouts, so that dividends can only be paid out if the net assets of the

�rm exceed its liabilities. We �ag such �rms as well.

5 Interestingly, large institutional ownership does not intrinsically raise agency risk for bondholders. This is because�nancial institutions are themselves monitored and, therefore, are less likely to pressurize managers to make excessivedividend payouts or to take very risky investment projects at the expense of bondholder interests.

14

3.3.3 Financial Transparency and Information Quality

We examine three proxies for the quality of information on the �rms��nancial situation and eco-

nomic prospects. Two of these measures are �rm-speci�c, namely, the dispersion of analysts�

forecasts for the �rm�s earnings and the quality of disclosure of the �rm�s �nancial statements. The

third measure is the e¤ect of the Sarbanes-Oxley (SOX) Act of 2002 that in�uences the information

asymmetry between insiders and bondholders for all public �rms.

We use a �rm-speci�c accounting transparency score from S&P (available for 2002). This score

measures the number of items disclosed by the �rm in its �nancial statements; hence, the greater

the transparency of the �rm�s �nancial statements, the higher is the score [see, e.g., Cheng et al.

(2006)]. We use the transparency score (FINTRNSP) as a measure of the quality of information

on the �rms�net assets position.

While �nancial statements provide outsiders with a picture of the �rms�net assets position, they

are usually not very informative with respect to the their investment prospects, for e.g., the quality

of the �rms�growth options. However, �nancial markets have developed measures, such as earnings

forecasts by analysts, to provide forward-looking assessments to outsiders. Consistent with this,

the literature interprets the dispersion in analysts�forecasts to indicate greater uncertainty in the

�rm�s economic prospects [e.g., Gebhardt et al. (2001) and Diether et al. (2002)]. We thus take the

dispersion in the analysts�earnings forecasts (ANYLDISP) to be negatively related to the quality

of information regarding the �rms�economic prospects. As is typically done in the literature, we

use the standard deviation of I/B/E/S earnings per share forecasts by analysts for the next �scal

year end, scaled by the previous �scal year end�s stock price.

The Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 (SOX) was motivated by a spate of corporate and accounting

scandals (including Enron, Tyco, and Worldcom), and has a wide ambit. Among other things, it

sets up performance benchmarks to enhance auditor independence, corporate governance, and the

quality of �nancial disclosures. If the SOX has been e¤ective, then it should increase the quality

of the information that �ows to the capital markets regarding the �rms��nancial situation. Based

on Hypothesis 8, we therefore expect that payout and subsequent �nancing restrictions will be

reduced, other things held �xed, after the passage of SOX. We use a

15

3.3.4 Other Characteristics

To isolate and highlight the e¤ects of managerial moral hazard on covenant design, we control

for �rm-speci�c and macro factors that are emphasized in the existing literature as signi�cant

determinants of covenant design. We have already incorporated above the role of growth options,

�rm size, and default risk. Other factors highlighted in the literature include �rms� leverage,

tangible assets, the stability of operating cash �ows, and the credit spread (at the time of issue).6

We use the log of the market-to-book ratio (MTB) as a proxy for growth options and the log of total

assets (SIZE ) as a measure of �rm size. We control for leverage (LEVER), the ratio of tangible

to total assets (TNGASSET ), the volatility of operating income (OPINCVOL). For assessing the

default risk, we control for the ratio of pro�ts to assets (PROFIT ), the ratio of the loan (or issue)

size to assets (LOANSIZE ), and identify if the bond is non-investment grade at the time of issuance

(JUNKRATED). For the credit spread (CREDITSPR) at the time of issue, we use the di¤erence

between the yields of BAA and AAA rated bonds in the month before the issue.

3.4 Test Design

We analyze the determinants of covenant inclusion using multinomial probit regressions. Specif-

ically, for any given covenant-type j (where, j ranges from investment-related to event-speci�c

covenants), our dependent variable is yj 2 f0; 1g. Here, yj = 1 if covenant-type j is included in the

bond issue, is set equal to 0 otherwise. The multinomial probit speci�cation thus implies that

Pr(yj = 1) = �(�+ �0X) (1)

Here, X is a vector of covariates representing proxies for managerial entrenchment, shareholder

power, �rm-speci�c characteristics, and control variables. And, �(�) is the normal cumulative

distribution function.

6Studies by Nash et al. (2003) and Bradley and Roberts (2003) �nd a role for growth options and the use ofcovenants in corporate bonds and private loans. Malitz (1986) �nds �rm size and leverage to be a signi�cant factors,while Begley (1994) emphasizes the role of default risk and operating cash �ows. Bradley and Roberts (2003) also�nd that the inclusion of covenants varies systematically with macroeconomic factors such as the credit spread.

16

4 Results

In this section, we discuss the results of our empirical analysis. We start by describing the data, the

sample construction, and some salient characteristics of the sample. We then describe the results

for the tests of Hypotheses 1-8 that we explicated in the previous section.

4.1 Data

Our primary data sources are FISD database for bond issuance and covenant usage data; ExecCom-

pustat for managerial incentives and tenure data, Compustat for �rm level balance sheet variables;

CRSP for market information; IRRC for data on G-Index and board composition, and Thomson

13-F data for institutional ownership. We restrict the sample period to 1993�2005 because of data

availability on ExecCompustat. FISD contains detailed information on the bonds at the time of

issuance, such as o¤ering yield, o¤ering amount, call and put features etc. But the unique feature

that sets this database apart from other bond databases is the comprehensive information on 54

bond covenants, which cover the gamut of restrictions that are observed on bonds.

We only consider bonds issued by U.S. domiciled non-�nancial �rms that are in the intersection

of CRSP, COMPUSTAT, FISD and Executive Compensation databases. Further, the bond must be

a corporate debenture with issuance, o¤ering date and covenant information available in FISD. We

exclude convertible bonds, secured lease obligations, perpetual bonds, unit deals, rule 144a bonds,

Medium Term Notes (MTNs), private placement bonds, Yankee, Canadian, and foreign currency

bonds. The sample only includes those bond that have been issued during 1993� 2005.

The �nal sample includes 3108 bonds issued by 764 unique �rms. We take the balance sheet

information from the annual COMPUSTAT �les. We allow a three-month lag after the �scal year-

end to ensure that the annual balance sheet information is available to the market. We intersect

the balance sheet information with the bond data from FISD to ensure that we include only the

latest available annual data (as of the month of the bond issue). We obtain secondary yields on

the AAA and BAA bonds � required to compute the credit spread � from the Federal Reserve.

Analyst forecast information required to construct the analyst dispersion variable (ANYLDISP)

is taken from I/B/E/S summary �les. We consider the analyst earnings forecasts one month prior to

the bond o¤ering date, and compute ANYLDISP as the standard deviation of the analyst earnings

forecasts scaled by the previous �scal year end�s stock price.

As we mentioned above, we use Standard and Poor�s Transparency and Disclosure study

17

as the source for the �nancial transparency score (FINTRNSP). The study involved measure-

ment/assessment of 98 disclosure attributes, 35 of which are related to �nancial transparency and

information disclosure [see, Cheng et al. (2006) for more details]. We consider only the �nancial

transparency and information disclosure score. The ranking re�ects the quantity of items dis-

closed and does not directly assess the quality of the disclosed information. However, past studies

have suggested that the disclosure quantity and quality are highly correlated [e.g., Durnev and

Kim (2005)]. In order to construct a meaningful sample, we assume that the transparency score

published during October 2002 is valid for the calendar years 2001, 2002 and 2003.

4.2 Sample Characteristics

Table 1 displays some salient characteristics of the bonds in our sample. The predominant majority

of bonds are senior with a median o¤ering amount of $250 million and a median maturity of 10

years. Just over three-quarters of the sample comprises of investment grade bonds (with a rating of

BAA and above), with only 1% receiving the highest rating (AAA) and 39% receiving the minimum

investment grade ranking (BAA). Of the quarter of the sample that is below investment-grade, 14%

are low-grade bonds (with a rating of BA) and about 10% are in the �very speculative�category

(with a rating of B).

In Table 2, we compare the use of the four major categories of bond covenants in investment

versus non-investment grade bonds. This comparison gives an indication of the role default risk

plays in the use of the various types of covenants. Clearly, indirect investment restrictions � for

example, restricting transaction with a¢ liates, requiring maintenance of net worth, and requiring

properties acquired after issue to be included in the current issue mortgage � are used much more

frequently in non-investment grade bonds compared to the investment grade bonds. However,

merger and asset disposition restrictions are used in the preponderant majority of bonds, whether

they be investment or non-investment grade.

Turning to dividend restrictions, the use of such restrictions is strikingly more frequent for

high default-risk bonds, which is consistent with predictions from the literature on bondholder-

shareholder con�icts. Not surprisingly, high default-risk bonds are substantially more likely to

restrict to issuers� ability to change debt priority, because �rms closer to bankruptcy have the

greatest incentive to raise funds by issuing senior debt. Note that such bonds also use restrictions

on stock issuance much more frequently. However, most bonds, whether they are investment or

18

non-investment grade, include some form of subsequent �nancing restrictions. On the other hand,

high default risk bonds use change of control related (event) restrictions much more frequently than

investment-grade bond do.

4.3 Tests of Entrenchment Related Hypotheses

Table 3 presents the �rst set of results for the inclusion of investment-related covenants, i.e., Hy-

potheses 1 and 2. Model 1 is a speci�cation that includes �rm and bond-speci�c covariates, but

does not include the managerial entrenchment related covariates. Consistent with Hypothesis 2, we

�nd that high default risk �rms (i.e., the ones that tend to issue non-investment grade bonds) are

signi�cantly more likely to include investment-related covenants. Moreover, bonds are more likely

to include investment related covenants if the credit spread is higher. At this level of analysis,

we do not �nd that high-growth option �rms are more likely to include investment restrictions.

However, we will examine the role of high-growth option �rms more closely in Table 5 below when

we test (the other parts of) Hypothesis 2.

Models 2 and 3 in Table 3 start the analysis of the in�uence of entrenchment on the use of

investment restrictions. The results for these models indicate that factors positively associated

with the extent of CEO entrenchment � such as, a long CEO tenure and extraordinarily high

CEO compensation relative to other senior executives � load signi�cantly on the likelihood of

including investment covenants. That is, even after controlling for the usual covariates (cf. Model

1), the likelihood of including investment-related covenants is signi�cantly and positively related to

the CEO�s long tenure and the ratio of the CEO�s compensation to the sum of the compensation

of other top executives.

The analysis in Table 4 further investigates the relationship between entrenchment and invest-

ment restrictions. We examine the e¤ects of the composite entrenchment variables (ENTRP and

ENTRC ) on the likelihood of including investment covenants. Both these composite entrenchment

measures have a sizeable and signi�cant positive in�uence on the likelihood of including investment

restrictions.

Taken together, the results in Table 3 and 4 show that the positive in�uence of managerial

entrenchment on the inclusion of investment restrictions is robust � loading signi�cantly for both

individual proxies and composite measures of entrenchment � and thus provide strong overall

support for Hypothesis 1. It is also noteworthy that the credit spread at the time of issue is no

19

longer a signi�cant factor in the inclusion of investment restrictions once we control for managerial

entrenchment related moral hazard. However, high default risk (i.e., JUNKRATED) continues to

load signi�cantly, even when we control for the entrenchment related variables.

Table 5 displays the analysis for the role of high-growth options on the inclusion of investment

restrictions, as explicated in Hypothesis 2. Model 1 in this table examines the interaction between

entrenchment and the presence of growth options. We �nd that the likelihood of covenant inclusion

is higher when entrenched management controls high growth option �rms, which is consistent with

the prediction of Hypothesis 2. Next, Models 2 and 3 in this Table indicate that the in�uence of

the delta and vega of the CEO�s stock option holdings on the inclusion of investment restrictions

is greater for high growth-option �rms, again supporting Hypothesis 2. Interestingly, we �nd (but

do not show) that the delta and vega of the CEO�s stock option holds load signi�cantly in the

likelihood of investment restrictions. However, as we see in Models 2 and 3, the in�uence of delta

and vega occurs mostly for high-growth option �rms. We therefore conclude that bondholders face

greater agency risk from high-growth option �rms with respect to managerial moral hazard on the

�rm�s investment policy. Therefore, for bondholders, the agency risk of managerial entrenchment

and incentives for risky investment is especially acute for high-growth option �rms.

Table 6 tests Hypothesis 3 by examining the likelihood function for including restrictions on

investments by the �rm through mergers and acquisitions. Model 1 shows a benchmark speci�cation

that excludes the managerial entrenchment variables. Firms with higher default risk, as measured

by a high ratio of loan size to assets and non-investment grade bond ratings are more likely to

include merger restrictions. On the other hand, and consistent with the CEH, utility �rms that

are under regulatory supervision for expansion plans are less likely to include the said covenants,

ceteris paribus.

Models 2-4 of Table 6 show the e¤ects of managerial entrenchment related variables on the

use of mergers restrictions. Even controlling for the benchmark covariates, entrenchment variables

such as long CEO tenure and the two composite entrenchment measures (ENTRP and ENTRC )

have a signi�cant and positive in�uence on the likelihood of including merger restrictions. The

evidence therefore supports the notion that bondholders target risky �empire building�behavior by

entrenched managers through restrictions on the scope of the mergers and acquisitions activity by

the �rm.

Table 7 presents results for the inclusion of dividend payout restrictions, and therefore tests

20

Hypotheses 4 and 5. Again, we estimate a benchmark speci�cation ( Model 1) that does not include

entrenchment related covariates. Consistent with Hypothesis 5, �rms with low (high) intrinsic risk

of excessive dividend payouts also have a lower (higher) likelihood of including dividend restrictions,

other things being the same. Thus, larger �rms and �rms with high growth options (high market-

to-book �rms) are less likely to include dividend instructions. On the other hand, �rms with higher

default risk � i.e., �rms with higher leverage or issuing bonds with non-investment grade ratings

� and �rms in industries known for high dividend payout ratios (e.g., utilities) are more likely to

include such restrictions, ceteris paribus.

Models 2-5 of Table 7 exhibit the in�uence of managerial entrenchment on the inclusion of

dividend restrictions. Consistent with Hypothesis 4, entrenchment variables such as long CEO

tenure and the two composite entrenchment measures (ENTRP and ENTRC ) have a signi�cant

and negative in�uence on the likelihood of including dividend payout restrictions. These results

indicate that bondholders view managerial entrenchment as ameliorating the risk of shareholders

paying themselves large dividends. In a related vein, we �nd (but do not tabulate) that, for a given

level of managerial entrenchment, �rms with more independent boards are less likely to include

payout restrictions in their bond issues. Thus, our analysis suggests that independent boards

monitor not only management but also shareholder moral hazard in terms of excessive dividend

payouts.

Table 8 examines the in�uence of the State corporate laws on the likelihood of including dividend

payout restrictions [see, Section 3.3.2]. Consistent with the predictions from the CEH, we �nd that

�rms incorporated in States that allow �nimble dividends�are signi�cantly more likely to include

payout restrictions when issuing bonds, other things being the same. On the other hand, �rms

incorporated in States that impose a �total assets�type of constraint on payouts are signi�cantly

less likely to include such restrictions.

We turn, next, to examine the determinants of the use of subsequent �nancing restrictions.

Table 8 reports these results. From the benchmark speci�cation (Model 1), we �nd that larger and

high growth option �rms are less likely to include such restrictions. Such restrictions are also less

likely to be used when the overall cost of corporate debt is high � note that the coe¢ cient for the

credit spread is negative and signi�cant � and this result is consistent with Hypothesis 6.

Models 2-3 in Table 9 show the e¤ects of managerial entrenchment on the likelihood of includ-

ing subsequent �nancing covenants. For the reasons mentioned above, this e¤ect is theoretically

21

ambiguous. However, Hypothesis 6 asserts that entrenchment will have a negative e¤ect on the

need for subsequent debt �nancing, once we control for growth options. Indeed, we �nd that when

we control for growth options through the market-to-book ratio, factors positively correlated with

managerial entrenchment signi�cantly reduce the likelihood of including subsequent debt �nancing

restrictions. In fact, comparing Model 1 with the other models in Table 9, we notice that the e¤ect

of market-to-book is no longer signi�cant once we include the entrenchment related covariates.

This result reinforces our interpretation that the �entrenchment e¤ect�dominates the �investment

opportunity�e¤ect when bondholders consider the e¤ects of managerial moral hazard on the risk

of subsequent debt �nancing.

Table 10 examines the determinants of using event-speci�c covenants. Consistent with Hypoth-

esis 7, Model 1 indicates that the likelihood of including event related restrictions is negatively

related to �rm size and the credit spread (which in�uences the cost of borrowing), but positively

related to default risk. And, Models 2 and 3 indicate that these restrictions are less likely to be used

if shareholder power is restricted by the corporate charter, as measured by the G-Index of Gompers

et al. (2003) and the E-Index of Bebchuk et al. (2004). These results further support Hypothesis

7. However, the composite entrenchment variables (e.g., ENTRP) do not load signi�cantly on the

likelihood of using event-speci�c covenants.

Table 11 further explores the e¤ects of corporate charter restrictions on shareholder power

and takeovers on the likelihood of including event-speci�c covenants. Model 1 here shows that,

consistent with Hypothesis 7, such covenants are signi�cantly less likely to be included if there

are anti-takeover provisions in the corporate charter, such as poison pills. Model 2 examines the

in�uence of the sub-indices of the G-Index. We �nd that restrictions on shareholder power that

tend to protect management are most in�uential, i.e., �rms with charter provisions that protect

management against shareholder proxy motions are signi�cantly less likely to include takeover-

speci�c covenants. Because such restrictions essentially enhance managerial entrenchment, the

results of Model 2 reinforce the evidence that takeover-speci�c covenants are less likely to be

included if managerial power is enhanced in relation to shareholder power.

22

4.4 Tests of Fraud Related Hypotheses

4.4.1 The E¤ect of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act

While the objectives of SOX have received considerable prominence, its actual impact on the quality

of information �owing from corporations to outsiders, and on managerial behavior, is still unclear.

Indeed, the recent literature that assesses the e¤ects of SOX �nds mixed results [e.g., Cohen et al.

(2005), Jain et al. (2004), and Beneish et al. (2005)].7 Therefore, the e¤ect of SOX on the use of

corporate bond covenants is of substantial interest. For, if we observe a signi�cant reduction in the

use of certain types of covenants after the passage of SOX (when controlling for other exogenous

variations), then this would suggest that the legislation has reduced certain types of agency risks

for corporate bondholders. Conversely, an insigni�cant change in the pattern of covenant usage

after the passage of SOX would suggest that the legislation has not signi�cantly in�uenced the

agency risk faced by bondholders of public corporations. However, we can directly examine this

issue, because we examine a panel data with detailed information on the use of various types of

covenants.

In Table 12, we examine how the passage of SOX has in�uenced the use of corporate bond

covenants. We do so by analyzing the di¤erences in the patterns of covenant use for bonds issued

before and after the passage of SOX. We restrict attention to those �rms that have issued bonds

both before and after the passage of SOX. We �nd that SOX does not appear to have signi�cantly

in�uenced the use of any of the major types of bond covenants. The only e¤ect of SOX, which we

observe by comparing Table 12 with Table 3, is that the in�uence of managerial entrenchment on

the use of investment restrictions has fallen after its passage. That is, the role of managerial moral

hazard in the use of investment restrictions has been reduced in the new regulatory regime.

Our results reinforce the mixed picture that is emerging in the literature regarding the e¤ect

of SOX on agency costs. For bondholders, it appears that the SOX has not signi�cantly changed

their desired pattern of covenant use. To some extent, this is not surprising because SOX, by itself,

has not signi�cantly in�uenced the �ow of forward-looking information on the �rms� investment

prospects, or signi�cantly a¤ected shareholder power with respect to high dividend payouts, or

7While Jain et al. (2004) �nd that information uncertainty or adverse selection re�ected in liquidity measures,such as bid-ask spreads, has declined after the passage of SOX, Cohen et al. (2005) �nd no change in the informationcontent of earnings in the post-SOX era. Beneish et al. (2005) �nd that the e¤ects of implementing some of the SOXprovisions depends on the �rms�information environment; for example, �rms that hire high-quality auditors exhibitlower e¤ects of implementing such provisions.

23

restricted the �rms� behavior while being a takeover target. On the other hand, our analysis

suggests that the SOX requirements have reduced bondholder risk from managerial moral hazard

on investment, possibly by increasing the expected penalty costs for managers if they camou�age

ine¢ cient investments by misrepresenting the �rm�s �nancial statements.

4.4.2 The E¤ects of Firm-Speci�c Information Asymmetry Measures

Table 13 examines the relationship between the likelihood of covenant usage and the dispersion in

analysts�forecasts, for each of the four major covenant types. Consistent with Hypothesis 8, we

�nd that �rms with higher forecast dispersion are signi�cantly more likely to use investment-related

covenants. These results reinforce earlier evidence in Table 4 that � from the bondholders�per-

spective � managerial moral hazard with respect to risky investments increases signi�cantly with

a greater range (or uncertainty) in investment prospects. Interestingly, the dispersion of analysts�

forecasts does not signi�cantly in�uence the use of the other three major types of covenants. This

result further supports the CEH, because uncertainty about future earnings, implicit in higher

dispersion of analysts� forecasts, is not substantively relevant to the agency risk with respect to

excessive dividend payouts (to shareholders), subsequent debt �nancing, or the �rm�s behavior as

a takeover target or during �nancial distress.

Table 14 presents the results of an analysis of the e¤ect of the �rms�transparency score on its

covenant usage in 2001-2003. We �nd that the use of dividend payout restrictions is signi�cantly

and negatively related to the �rm�s transparency score, which is consistent with the prediction from

the contracting e¢ ciency framework. However, the transparency score is not signi�cantly related

to the use of the subsequent �nancing restrictions; and, consistent with the priors, it also does

not signi�cantly in�uence the use of investment-related and event-speci�c covenants. It appears

that the agency risk of excessive debt �nancing is not signi�cantly a¤ected by the number of items

disclosed in the �nancial statements, but the risk of large dividend payouts to shareholders is.

5 Summary and Conclusions

Bond covenants play a prominent role in the agency theory of the �rm. Their use exempli�es

the idea that �rms voluntarily proscribe their operational �exibility to lower agency risk for bond-

holders, and therefore also the cost of debt. However, the literature almost exclusively focuses on

bondholder-shareholder con�icts. We examine the e¤ects of managerial moral hazard on agency

24

risk for bondholders. Based on an analysis of the agency risk for bondholders from managerial

entrenchment and fraud, and using the contractual e¢ ciency hypothesis (CEH), we derive testable

hypotheses on in�uence of managerial moral hazard on the inclusion (or exclusion) of the major

types of bond covenants. Our analysis emphasizes that entrenched managers can both exacerbate

and ameliorate bondholder agency risk, because they sometimes bene�t the bondholders by op-

posing the interests of shareholders in situations where there are bondholder-shareholder con�icts.

Moreover, in calibrating agency risk due to managerial fraud, we emphasize the quality of the

information regarding the �rm�s net assets position and economic prospects.

Our empirical analysis, based on all corporate bonds issued during 1993-2005 and containing

information on over 54 covenants, indicates that managerial moral hazard has a signi�cant in�uence

on the use of bond covenants. The extent of managerial entrenchment and the risk of managerial

fraud signi�cantly in�uence the use of (the various types of) bond covenants, in the direction

predicted by the CEH. We �nd that individual entrenchment proxies and composite entrenchment

measures both load signi�cantly on the likelihood of including (or excluding) various covenants.

Moreover, the use of covenants responds to cross-sectional and time-series variations in the �rms�

informational environment in a manner consistent with addressing the risk of managerial fraud.

Overall, our analysis suggests that there is a multi-faceted interaction between managerial moral

hazard and bondholder agency risk, and supports the view that �rms tend toward an e¢ ciently

designed �nexus of contracts.�

25

References

Bebchuk, L.A., Cohen, A., and A. Ferrell, 2004, What matters in corporate governance?, Harvard

University Discussion paper No. 491.

Begley, J., 1994, Restrictive covenants included in pubic debt agreements: An empirical investigation,

Working paper, University of British Columbia.

Begley, J., and G. Feltham, 1999, An empirical examination of the relation between debt contracts and

management incentives, Journal of Accounting and Economics 39, 857-878.

Berger, P., E. Ofek, and D. Yermack, 1997, Managerial entrenchment and capital structure decisions,

Journal of Finance, 52, 1411-1438.

Billet, M., T. King, and D. Mauer, 2004, Bondholder wealth e¤ects in mergers and acquisitions: New

evidence from 1980s and 1990s, Journal of Finance 59, 107-135.

Beneish, M., M. Billings and L. Hodder, 2005, Internal control weaknesses and information asymmetry,

Working Paper, Indiana University.

Berle, A., and G. Means, 1932, The modern corporation and private property (Macmillan, New York).

Bradley, M., and M. Roberts, 2003, Are bond covenants priced?, Working paper, Duke University.

Cheng, A., D. Collins and H. Huang, 2006, The Market Response to the October 15, 2002 Standard &

Poors Transparency & Disclosure Rankings, Working Paper, University of Memphis.

Coles, J., N. Daniel, and L. Naveen, 2006, Executive compensation and managerial risk-taking, Forth-

coming, Journal of Financial Economics.

Cohen, R., B. Hall, and L. Viceira, 2000, Do executive stock options encourage risk-taking?, Working

Paper, Harvard University.

Cohen D., A. Dey and T. Lys, 2005, Trends in earnings management and informativeness of earnings

announcements in the pre- and post- Sarbanes-Oxley periods, Working Paper, Northwestern University.

Core, J., and W. Guay, 1999, The use of equity grants to manage optimal equity incentive levels, Journal

of Accounting and Economics 28, 151-184.

Cremers, K., V. Nair, and C. Wei, 2003, The impact of shareholder control on bondholders, forthcoming,

Review of Financial Studies.

Diether, K., C. Malloy, and A. Scherbina, 2002, Di¤erences of Opinion and the Cross-Section of Stock

Returns, Journal of Finance 57, 2113-2141.

Durnev, A., and E. H. Kim, 2005, To steal or not to steal: Firm attributes, legal environment and

valuation, The Journal of Finance 60, 1461-1493.

26

Fluck, Z, 1999, The Dynamics of the management-shareholder con�ict, Review of Financial Studies 12,

379-404.

Gebhardt, W., C. Lee, and B. Swaminathan, 2001, Toward an implied cost of capital, Journal of Ac-

counting Research 39, 135-142.

Gompers, P., J. Ishii, and A. Metrick, 2003, Corporate governance and equity prices, Quarterly Journal

of Economics, 118, 107-155.

Hart, O., 1995, Financial contracting (Oxford University Press, Oxford, U.K.)

Hart, O., and J. Moore, 1995, Debt and seniority: An analysis of the role of hard claims in constraining

management, American Economic Review 85, 567-585.

Hu, A., and P. Kumar, 2004, Managerial entrenchment and payout policy, Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis 39, 759-790.

Jensen, M., 1986, Agency costs of free cash �ow, corporate �nance, and the market for takeovers,

American Economic Review 76, 323-329.

Jensen, M., 1993, The modern industrial revolution, exit, and failure of internal control systems, Journal

of Finance 48, 35-44.

Jensen, M., and W. Meckling, 1976, Theory of the �rm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership

structure, Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360.

Jain P., J. Kim and Z. Rezaee, 2004, The e¤ect of Sarbanes-Oxley act of 2002 on market liquidity,

Working Paper, University of Memphis.

Leland, H., 1994, Corporate debt value, bond covenants, and optimal capital structure, Journal of

Finance, 49, 1213-1252.

Malitz, I., 1986, On �nancial contracting: The determinants of bond covenants, Financial Management

15, 18-25

Myers, S., 1977, Determinants of corporate borrowing, Journal of Financial economics 5, 147-175.

Nash, R., J. Netter, and A. Poulsen, 2003, Determinants of contractual relations between shareholders

and bondholders: Investment opportunities and restrictive covenants, Journal of Corporate Finance 9, 201-

232.

Peterson C., and N. Hawker, 1997 , Does corporate law matter? Legal capital restrictions on stock

distributions, Akron Law Review, 31, 175-228.

Shleifer, A., and R., Vishny, 1986, Large shareholders and corporate control, Journal of Political Economy

94, 461-488.

27

Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny, 1989, Management entrenchment: The case of manager-speci�c investments,

Journal of Financial Economics 25, 123-139.

Smith, C., and J. Warner, 1979, On �nancial contracting: An analysis of bond covenants, Journal of

Financial Economics 7, 117-161.

Stulz, R, 1988, Managerial control of voting rights: Financing policies and the market for corporate

control, Journal of Financial Economics 20, 25-54.

Stulz, R., 1990, Managerial discretion and optimal �nancing policies, Journal of Financial Economics

26, 3-27.

Warga, A., and I. Welch, 1993, Bondholder losses in leveraged buyouts, Review of Financial Studies 6,

959-982.

Zwiebel, J., 1996, Dynamic capital structure under managerial entrenchment, American Economic Re-

view 86, 1197-1215.

28

Table1:BondCharacteristics

Thefollowingtabledocumentsthevariouscharacteristicsofbondsinoursample.The2006editionoftheFixedIncomeSecurities

Database(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.ThesampleisrestrictedtobondsissuedbyU.S.domicilednon-

�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutiveCompensationdatabases.Weconsideronlycorporate

debentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailableinFISD.Weexcludeconvertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetual

bonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MediumTermNotes(MTNs),privateplacementbonds,Yankee,Canadianandforeigncurrency

bonds.PanelApresentsthesummarystatisticsforspread,amountandmaturity.PanelBtabulatestheseniorityfeaturesofthebonds

inthesampleandPanelCtabulatestheMoody�sratingofthebondsatissuance.Alltheissuecharacteristicsaretheaveragesforall

thebondsissuedduringthesampleperiod,1993-2005.O¤eringyieldistheactualyield-to-maturityonbondissued.Thespreadofthe

bondisthedi¤erencebetweenitsyieldandtheyieldofatreasurybondofsimilarmaturity.O¤eringamountisthetotalfacevalue

oftheissueinmillionsofUSdollars.Maturityisthedi¤erenceoftheissuedateandthematuritydateandismeasuredinmonths.

Seniorityreferstotheseniorityofthebond.InPanelC,wepresentthenumberofbondswithagivenratingasapercentageofthe

totalnumberofbondsthatareissuedduringthesampleperiod.

PanelA:BondCharacteristics

variable

mean

25thpcntl

50thpcntl

75thpcntl

o¤eringspread

6.83

6.13

6.89

7.56

treasuryspread

124.57

67.00

98.00

157.00

o¤eringamount($mil)

332.50

150.00

250.00

400.00

maturity(inmonths)

162.64

83.00

120.00

145.00

PanelB:SecurityFeatures

Seniority

Frequency

Percentage

seniorsecured

154

5.0%

senior

2719

87.5%

seniorsubordinate

230

7.4%

junior

10.0%

subordinate

10.0%

PanelC:Moody�sBondRatings

Moody�sRating

Frequency

Percentage

AAA

341.1%

AA

173

5.6%

A923

29.7%

BAA

1215

39.0%

BA

436

14.1%

B302

9.7%

CAAandbelow

230.7%

29

Table2:Classi�cation

ofCovenantsbytheNatureofRestrictions

The2006editionoftheFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.Thesample

isrestrictedtobondsissuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutive

Compensationdatabases.WeconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailableinFISD.W

eexclude

convertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,privateplacementbonds,Yankee,

Canadian,andforeigncurrencybonds.The�fty-fourcovenantsinthebondindenturearegroupedintovariouscategoriesbasedon

thenatureoftherestrictions.WeuseSmithandWarner(1979)frameworktogroupthecovenantsandcodethebondashavinga

particularcovenantifthebondcontainsoneormoreofthecovenantsfallingunderthatcategory.Restrictionsonthesubsidiaryand

parentcompanyarebothconsidered.Mergerrestrictionsarecovenantsthatrestrictsaconsolidationormergerbytheissuing�rm.

Assetsaledispositioncovenantsincluderestrictionsonsaleofassets,assetsaleclauseandsaleandtransferofassetstounrestricted

subsidiaries.Abondiscodedashavinganindirectinvestmentrestrictioncovenantifthebond�sindentureincludesatleastoneofthe

followingcovenants:restrictionsontransactionswitha¢liates,�xedchargecoverage,maintenanceofminimum

networth,restrictions

onredesignatingsubsidiaries,subsidiary�xedchargecoverageratioandafteracquiredpropertyclause(thatmandatesthattheproperty

acquiredafterthecurrentdebtissueissoldwouldbeincludedinthecurrentissuersmortgage).Abondiscodedashavinginvestment

restrictionsifthebond�sindenturecontainsatleastoneofthefollowingrestrictions:restrictionsonconsolidationormergers,asset

dispositionrestriction,indirectinvestmentrestrictions,bondissecured,stocksalerestrictionsor,directinvestmentrestrictions.A

bondiscodedashavingdividendandpaymentrestrictionsifthebond�sindenturerestrictseitherdividendsorotherpayments.Debt

priorityrestrictionsincluderestrictionsonfundeddebt,indebtedness,liensand,seniordebtissuanceofparentandsubsidiary�rms.

Stockissuancerestrictioncategoryincluderestrictionsonissuanceofstockand,preferencestockofparentandsubsidiary�rms.Abond

iscodedashavingasubordinatedebtcovenantifthebondindentureincludesoneormoreofthefollowingrestrictions:subordinate

debtissuance,netearningstest,leveragetest,subsidiaryborrowings,subsidiaryguarantees,subsidiaryleveragetestandnegative

pledgecovenant(theissuercannotissuesecureddebtunlessitsecuresthecurrentissueonapari-passubasis).SubsequentFinancing

Restrictionsequalsoneifthebond�sindenturecontainsoneofdebtpriorityrestrictions,stockissuancerestrictions,subordinatedebt

restrictions,restrictionsonsaleandleaseobligations.Defaultrelatedeventcovenantsinclude:crossdefault,crossacceleration,rating

declinetriggerputanddecliningnetworthcovenant.Eventrestrictionsiscodedasoneifthebond�sindenturecontainsatleastone

covenantfallingunderdefaultrelatedeventcovenantsoriftheindenturecontainsachangeincontrolpoisonput.Eachrowlists

thenumberofbondswithoneormorecovenantsbelongingtothatcategoryasapercentageofinvestmentgradebonds(column1),

non-investmentgradebonds(column2)andallthebonds(column3)issuedduringthesampleperiodof1993-2005.

30

Covenant

Investment

Non-Inv.

Total

Grade

Grade

(N=2347)

(N=761)

(N=3108)

PanelA:InvestmentRestrictions

MergerRestrictions

91.0%

98.6%

92.9%

AssetDispositionRestriction

90.4%

98.8%

92.4%

IndirectInvestmentRestrictions

5.5%

71.7%

21.7%

Secured

4.6%

5.9%

5.0%

StockSaleRestrictions

0.7%

9.2%

2.8%

DirectInvestmentRestrictions

0.2%

5.0%

1.4%

InvestmentRestriction

94.5%

99.7%

95.8%

PanelB:DividendRestrictions

DividendPaymentRestrictions

2.7%

65.5%

18.1%

RestrictionsonOtherPayments

0.8%

70.3%

17.8%

DividendorOtherPaymentRestriction

3.2%

72.4%

20.1%

PanelC:SubsequentFinancingRestrictions

RestrictionsonSubordinateDebtIssuance

88.0%

90.1%

88.5%

RestrictionsonSaleandLeaseObligations

69.0%

49.9%

64.3%

RestrictionsonDebtPriority

14.0%

77.1%

29.4%

StockIssuanceRestriction

1.8%

48.4%

13.2%

SubsequentFinancingRestrictions

92.0%

97.9%

93.5%

PanelD:EventRelated

Restrictions

DefaultRelatedEventCovenants

46.7%

87.8%

56.7%

ChangeinControlPoisonPut

2.7%

73.3%

20.0%

EventRestrictions

47.6%

92.6%

58.6%

31

Table3:DeterminantsofInvestmentRestrictions

Thefollowingtableanalyzesthedeterminantsoftheuseofinvestmentrestrictions,usingaprobitregression.The2006editionof

theFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.Thesampleisrestrictedtobonds

issuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutiveCompensationdatabases

during,1993�2005.WeconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailableinFISD.Weexclude

convertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,privateplacementbonds,Yankee,

Canadian,andforeigncurrencybonds.Thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceofinvestmentrestrictions.A

bondiscodedashavinginvestmentrestrictionsifthebond�sindenturecontainsatleastoneofthefollowingrestrictions:restrictions

onconsolidationormergers,assetdispositionrestriction,indirectinvestmentrestrictions,bondissecured,stocksalerestrictionsor,

directinvestmentrestrictions.Table2givesmoredetailsonthecovenantsthatfallintotheinvestmentrestrictionscategoryandis

basedontheclassi�cationofSmithandWarner(1979).LNGCEOTNRisthesquareoflengthofCEOtenuremeasuredinyears(from

thedateshebecameCEO).CEORELCOMPistheratiooftheCEO�stotalcompensationtothesumofthetotalcompensationof

theotherfourtopexecutivesreportedinexecutivecompensationdatabase.PROFIT

istheratioof�rm�spro�tabilitytothetotal

assetsofthe�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof�rm�stotaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassetsof

the�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,propertyandequipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBisthelogarithm

ofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhestandarddeviationofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast�veyears.

CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAandAAAratedbonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturitymeasured

inmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueof

oneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe�rmbelongs

utilityindustry.TheregressionsalsocontrolforCEOtenure(Model2),andindicatorsforcallableandputablefeaturesofthebond

inallthemodels.Thereare3019bondsinthebasemodel(Model1),and2732,2628,2811bondsinModels2-4respectively.Robust

standarderrorsadjustedfor�rmlevelclusteringarepresentedinparenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

32

Model1

Model2

Model3

Model4

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

LNGCEOTNR

0.0048

(2.69)

CEOdelta

0.2808

(2.97)

CEORELCOMP

0.4143

(2.46)

PROFIT

-0.2623

(-0.11)

-0.8851

(-0.41)

-1.4262

(-0.81)

-0.3629

(-0.15)

LEVER

0.4124

(0.56)

0.2622

(0.39)

-0.0714

(-0.13)

0.4913

(0.64)

SIZE

-0.1461

(-1.30)

-0.0992

(-0.91)

-0.2922

(-2.33)

-0.1514

(-1.30)

TNGASSET

-0.5811

(-1.31)

-0.4575

(-1.03)

-0.3954

(-0.73)

-0.7597

(-1.73)

MTB

-0.2240

(-0.81)

-0.1006

(-0.39)

-0.4392

(-1.27)

-0.1728

(-0.64)

OPINCVOL

-0.3428

(-0.09)

0.1127

(0.03)

-1.0686

(-0.35)

-0.1678

(-0.04)

CREDITSPR

1.1930

(2.06)

1.0750

(1.81)

0.9320

(1.80)

1.0681

(1.74)

MATURITY

-0.0024

(-0.03)

-0.0049

(-0.06)

-0.0703

(-0.90)

-0.0096

(-0.10)

LOANSIZE

0.0942

(0.57)

0.1141

(0.70)

-0.0714

(-0.49)

0.0682

(0.40)

JUNKRATED

0.8248

(2.89)

0.8312

(2.81)

0.7341

(2.49)

0.7853

(2.74)

UTIL

0.0610

(0.20)

0.0555

(0.17)

-0.1913

(-0.64)

0.0175

(0.06)

intercept

2.6479

(1.97)

2.8497

(2.39)

4.1969

(3.71)

2.5461

(1.79)

R2

0.114

0.129

0.128

0.116

33

Table4:DeterminantsofInvestmentRestrictions-Com

positeIndices

Thefollowingtableanalyzestheimpactofcompositeentrenchmentmeasuresontheuseofinvestmentrestrictions,usingaprobit

regression.The2006editionoftheFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.

ThesampleisrestrictedtobondsissuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDand

ExecutiveCompensationdatabasesduring1993�2005.Weconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformation

availableinFISD.Weexcludeconvertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,private

placementbonds,Yankee,Canadian,andforeigncurrencybonds.Thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceof

investmentrestrictions.Abondiscodedashavinginvestmentrestrictionsifthebond�sindenturecontainsatleastoneofthefollowing

restrictions:restrictionsonconsolidationormergers,assetdispositionrestriction,indirectinvestmentrestrictions,bondissecured,stock

salerestrictionsor,directinvestmentrestrictions.Table2givesmoredetailsonthecovenantsthatfallintotheinvestmentrestrictions

categoryandisbasedontheclassi�cationofSmithandWarner(1979).ENTRCisconstructedusingaprinicipalcomponentanalysis

asalinearcombinationofentrenchmentvariables(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,andCEOSHROWN)withtheweightsbeingthe

elementsoftheeigenvectorthataccountsforthehighestpercentageofthevariationinalloftheaboveentrenchmentvariables.ENTRP

issimilarlyconstructedexceptthistimethesetofentrenchmentvariablesusedinclude(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,CEOSHROWN,

LNGCEOTNR,PCASHCOMP,BLOCKHOLDERS).CEODELTAdenotesthedeltaoftheCEO�sstockandoptioncompensation

computedbytheBlack-Scholes-MertonmodelusingthemethodologyoutlinedinCoreandGuay(1999).CEORELCOMPistheratioof

theCEO�stotalcompensationtothesumofthetotalcompensationoftheotherfourtopexecutivesreportedinexecutivecompensation

database.PCASHCOMPistheratioofCEO�scashsalarytothetotalcompensation.CEOSHROWNisthepercentageofthe�rm�s

outstandingsharesthatareheldbytheCEO.LNGCEOTNRisthesquareoflengthofCEOtenuremeasuredinyears(fromthedate

shebecameCEO).PROFITistheratioof�rm�spro�tabilitytothetotalassetsofthe�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof�rm�s

totaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassetsofthe�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,propertyand

equipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBisthelogarithmofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhestandard

deviationofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast�veyears.CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAandAAArated

bonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturitymeasuredinmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe

�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisa

dummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe�rmbelongsutilityindustry.Theregressionsalsocontrolforindicatorsforcallable

andputablefeaturesofthebondinallthemodels.Model1and2areestimatedon2611and2531bondsrespectively.Robuststandard

errorsadjustedfor�rmlevelclusteringarepresentedinparenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

34

Model1

Model2

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

ENTRC

0.6919

(2.61)

ENTRP

0.3028

(2.73)

PROFIT

-1.2753

(-0.68)

-1.6670

(-0.91)

LEVER

-0.1120

(-0.20)

-0.1331

(-0.24)

SIZE

-0.2942

(-2.25)

-0.2389

(-1.87)

TNGASSET

-0.6786

(-1.30)

-0.6902

(-1.34)

MTB

-0.4727

(-1.32)

-0.3380

(-0.98)

OPINCVOL

-1.0391

(-0.32)

-0.4666

(-0.14)

CREDITSPR

0.8200

(1.54)

0.8479

(1.59)

MATURITY

-0.1187

(-1.58)

-0.1211

(-1.61)

LOANSIZE

-0.1019

(-0.67)

-0.0503

(-0.33)

JUNKRATED

0.6724

(2.24)

0.6492

(2.13)

UTIL

-0.1767

(-0.59)

-0.1705

(-0.55)

intercept

4.9401

(4.24)

4.4486

(3.99)

R2

0.142

0.133

35

Table5:ImpactofGrowthOptionson

InvestmentRestrictions

Thefollowingtableanalyzestheimpactofgrowthopportunitiesontheinclusionofinvestmentrestrictions,usingaprobitregression.

The2006editionoftheFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.Thesample

isrestrictedtobondsissuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutive

Compensationdatabasesduring1993�2005.Weconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailable

inFISD.Weexcludeconvertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,privateplacement

bonds,Yankee,Canadian,andforeigncurrencybonds.Thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceofinvestment

restrictions.Abondiscodedashavinginvestmentrestrictionsifthebond�sindenturecontainsatleastoneofthefollowingrestrictions:

restrictionson

consolidationormergers,assetdispositionrestriction,indirectinvestmentrestrictions,bondissecured,stocksale

restrictionsor,directinvestmentrestrictions.Table2givesmoredetailsonthecovenantsthatfallintotheinvestmentrestrictions

categoryandisbasedontheclassi�cationofSmithandWarner(1979).ENTRCisconstructedusingaprinicipalcomponentanalysis

asalinearcombinationofentrenchmentvariables(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,andCEOSHROWN)withtheweightsbeingthe

elementsoftheeigenvectorthataccountsforthehighestpercentageofthevariationinalloftheaboveentrenchmentvariables.

CEODELTAandCEOVEGAdenotesthedeltaandvegarespectivelyoftheCEO�sstockandoptioncompensationcomputedbythe

Black-Scholes-MertonmodelusingthemethodologyoutlinedinCoreandGuay(1999).PROFITistheratioof�rm�spro�tabilityto

thetotalassetsofthe�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof�rm�stotaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmof

totalassetsofthe�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,propertyandequipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBis

thelogarithmofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhestandarddeviationofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast

�veyears.CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAandAAAratedbonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturity

measuredinmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakes

thevalueofoneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe

�rmbelongsutilityindustry.Theregressionsalsocontrolforindicatorsforcallableandputablefeaturesofthebondinallthemodels.

Model1,2and3areestimatedon2611,2628and2674bondsrespectively.Robuststandarderrorsadjustedfor�rmlevelclustering

arepresentedinparenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

36

Model1

Model2

Model3

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

MTB�ENTRC

0.6967

(2.23)

MTB�CEODELTA

0.2911

(2.40)

MTB�CEOVEGA

1.5454

(2.68)

ENTRC

0.2373

(0.88)

CEODELTA

0.0747

(0.68)

CEOVEGA

-1.0449

(-1.74)

PROFIT

-1.0934

(-0.58)

-1.2311

(-0.71)

-0.6089

(-0.28)

LEVER

-0.0755

(-0.14)

-0.0266

(-0.05)

0.3967

(0.62)

SIZE

-0.2949

(-2.26)

-0.2887

(-2.30)

-0.1451

(-0.98)

TNGASSET

-0.6945

(-1.34)

-0.4116

(-0.76)

-0.5794

(-1.21)

MTB

-0.2920

(-0.87)

-0.6554

(-1.79)

-0.6459

(-2.00)

OPINCVOL

-1.0430

(-0.33)

-1.0949

(-0.36)

0.2055

(0.06)

CREDITSPR

0.8123

(1.53)

0.9263

(1.80)

1.1186

(1.81)

MATURITY

-0.1190

(-1.58)

-0.0705

(-0.90)

0.0081

(0.09)

LOANSIZE

-0.0943

(-0.62)

-0.0624

(-0.43)

0.1024

(0.60)

JUNKRATED

0.6626

(2.20)

0.7214

(2.45)

0.7368

(2.51)

UTIL

-0.2205

(-0.74)

-0.2432

(-0.82)

-0.1539

(-0.51)

intercept

4.8089

(4.22)

4.2890

(3.78)

2.9677

(1.90)

R2

0.144

0.130

0.126

37

Table6:DeterminantsofConsolidationandMergerRestrictions

Thefollowingtableanalyzesthedeterminantsoftheuseofrestrictionsonconsolidationsandmergersbythe�rm,usingaprobit

regression.The2006editionoftheFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.

ThesampleisrestrictedtobondsissuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDand

ExecutiveCompensationdatabasesduring1993�2005.Weconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformation

availableinFISD.Weexcludeconvertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,private

placementbonds,Yankee,Canadian,andforeigncurrencybonds.Thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceof

consolidationandmergerrestrictions.Table2givesmoredetailsonthecovenantsthatfallintotheinvestmentrestrictionscategory

andisbasedontheclassi�cationofSmithandWarner(1979).ENTRCisconstructedusingaprinicipalcomponentanalysisasalinear

combinationofentrenchmentvariables(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,andCEOSHROWN)withtheweightsbeingtheelementsof

theeigenvectorthataccountsforthehighestpercentageofthevariationinalloftheaboveentrenchmentvariables.

ENTRPis

similarlyconstructedexceptthistimethesetofentrenchmentvariablesusedinclude(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,CEOSHROWN,

LNGCEOTNR,PCASHCOMP,BLOCKHOLDERS).CEODELTAdenotesthedeltaoftheCEO�sstockandoptioncompensation

computedbytheBlack-Scholes-MertonmodelusingthemethodologyoutlinedinCoreandGuay(1999).CEORELCOMPistheratioof

theCEO�stotalcompensationtothesumofthetotalcompensationoftheotherfourtopexecutivesreportedinexecutivecompensation

database.PCASHCOMPistheratioofCEO�scashsalarytothetotalcompensation.CEOSHROWNisthepercentageofthe�rm�s

outstandingsharesthatareheldbytheCEO.LNGCEOTNRisthesquareoflengthofCEOtenuremeasuredinyears(fromthedate

shebecameCEO).PROFITistheratioof�rm�spro�tabilitytothetotalassetsofthe�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof�rm�s

totaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassetsofthe�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,propertyand

equipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBisthelogarithmofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhestandard

deviationofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast�veyears.CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAandAAArated

bonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturitymeasuredinmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe

�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisa

dummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe�rmbelongsutilityindustry.TheregressionsalsocontrolforCEOtenure(Model2),

andindicatorsforcallableandputablefeaturesofthebondinallthemodels.Model1-4areestimatedon3019,2732,2611and2531

bondsrespectively.Robuststandarderrorsadjustedfor�rmlevelclusteringarepresentedinparenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

38

Model1

Model2

Model3

Model4

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

LNGCEOTNR

0.0055

(3.02)

ENTRC

0.9129

(2.69)

ENTRP

0.3816

(2.91)

PROFIT

-1.0009

(-0.46)

-0.7053

(-0.33)

-0.9507

(-0.50)

-1.3730

(-0.74)

LEVER

0.0355

(0.05)

0.2608

(0.38)

-0.0959

(-0.17)

-0.2077

(-0.36)

SIZE

0.0989

(1.00)

0.0494

(0.48)

-0.0734

(-0.62)

-0.0417

(-0.35)

TNGASSET

-0.8530

(-2.06)

-0.6204

(-1.50)

-0.8221

(-1.72)

-0.8528

(-1.77)

MTB

-0.0971

(-0.33)

-0.1166

(-0.45)

-0.5749

(-1.60)

-0.4085

(-1.17)

OPINCVOL

3.2746

(0.78)

0.6122

(0.17)

-0.7787

(-0.25)

-0.5088

(-0.16)

CREDITSPR

0.9379

(1.98)

0.9896

(1.88)

0.6377

(1.42)

0.7995

(1.70)

MATURITY

-0.0725

(-0.91)

-0.0798

(-1.02)

-0.2020

(-3.12)

-0.1912

(-2.95)

LOANSIZE

0.3361

(2.75)

0.2891

(2.15)

0.1815

(1.44)

0.1949

(1.52)

JUNKRATED

0.5219

(2.13)

0.6694

(2.88)

0.3348

(1.23)

0.5975

(2.43)

UTIL

-0.7069

(-2.72)

-0.6816

(-2.78)

-0.9907

(-4.17)

-0.9334

(-3.76)

intercept

1.8651

(1.62)

2.5214

(2.28)

4.5405

(4.25)

3.9475

(3.79)

R2

0.196

0.192

0.241

0.227

39

Table7:DeterminantsofDividendRestrictions

Thefollowingtableanalyzesthedeterminantsoftheuseofrestrictionsondividendsandotherpayments,usingaprobitregression.

The2006editionoftheFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.Thesample

isrestrictedtobondsissuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutive

Compensationdatabasesduring1993�2005.Weconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailable

inFISD.Weexcludeconvertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,privateplacement

bonds,Yankee,Canadian,andforeigncurrencybonds.Thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceofdividend

andotherpaymentrestrictions.Table2givesmoredetailsonthecovenantsthatfallintotheinvestmentrestrictionscategoryand

isbasedontheclassi�cationofSmithandWarner(1979).ENTRCisconstructedusingaprinicipalcomponentanalysisasalinear

combinationofentrenchmentvariables(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,andCEOSHROWN)withtheweightsbeingtheelementsof

theeigenvectorthataccountsforthehighestpercentageofthevariationinalloftheaboveentrenchmentvariables.

ENTRPis

similarlyconstructedexceptthistimethesetofentrenchmentvariablesusedinclude(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,CEOSHROWN,

LNGCEOTNR,PCASHCOMP,BLOCKHOLDERS).CEODELTAdenotesthedeltaoftheCEO�sstockandoptioncompensation

computedbytheBlack-Scholes-MertonmodelusingthemethodologyoutlinedinCoreandGuay(1999).CEORELCOMPistheratioof

theCEO�stotalcompensationtothesumofthetotalcompensationoftheotherfourtopexecutivesreportedinexecutivecompensation

database.PCASHCOMPistheratioofCEO�scashsalarytothetotalcompensation.CEOSHROWNisthepercentageofthe�rm�s

outstandingsharesthatareheldbytheCEO.LNGCEOTNRisthesquareoflengthofCEOtenuremeasuredinyears(fromthedate

shebecameCEO).PROFITistheratioof�rm�spro�tabilitytothetotalassetsofthe�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof�rm�s

totaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassetsofthe�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,propertyand

equipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBisthelogarithmofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhestandard

deviationofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast�veyears.CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAandAAArated

bonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturitymeasuredinmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe

�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisa

dummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe�rmbelongsutilityindustry.TheregressionsalsocontrolforCEOtenure(Model2),

andindicatorsforcallableandputablefeaturesofthebondinallthemodels.Model1-4areestimatedon3019,2732,2611and2531

bondsrespectively.Robuststandarderrorsadjustedfor�rmlevelclusteringarepresentedinparenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

40

Model1

Model2

Model3

Model4

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

LNGCEOTNR

-0.0031

(-2.44)

ENTRC

-0.1085

(-2.11)

ENTRP

-0.1179

(-2.27)

PROFIT

0.9885

(0.92)

0.2602

(0.22)

0.0931

(0.09)

0.5986

(0.52)

LEVER

1.0959

(2.69)

0.7039

(1.77)

1.0019

(2.52)

0.8066

(2.03)

SIZE

-0.5295

(-5.67)

-0.5275

(-5.23)

-0.5311

(-5.26)

-0.5386

(-5.16)

TNGASSET

-0.1020

(-0.33)

-0.1431

(-0.45)

-0.1905

(-0.66)

-0.1487

(-0.49)

MTB

-1.3477

(-4.54)

-1.3682

(-4.17)

-1.1759

(-3.66)

-1.2483

(-3.83)

OPINCVOL

1.5285

(0.67)

3.2724

(1.40)

2.1178

(0.94)

2.4941

(1.08)

CREDITSPR

0.0194

(0.08)

0.1142

(0.40)

0.1929

(0.67)

0.2004

(0.68)

MATURITY

-0.0641

(-0.83)

0.0271

(0.36)

-0.0082

(-0.10)

0.0063

(0.08)

LOANSIZE

-0.0250

(-0.27)

-0.0218

(-0.20)

-0.0479

(-0.46)

-0.0519

(-0.48)

JUNKRATED

2.0934

(14.47)

2.2544

(14.67)

2.2961

(15.11)

2.3204

(14.69)

UTIL

0.6797

(3.01)

0.5318

(2.32)

0.6580

(2.89)

0.6201

(2.66)

intercept

2.5534

(3.44)

1.9883

(2.72)

2.0144

(2.68)

2.0194

(2.64)

R2

0.608

0.637

0.634

0.634

41

Table8:ImpactofStateLawson

theUseofDividendRestrictions

ThefollowingtableanalyzestheimpactofStatepayoutrestrictionsontheinclusionofdividendandpaymentcovenants,usingaprobit

regression.The2006editionoftheFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.

ThesampleisrestrictedtobondsissuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDand

ExecutiveCompensationdatabasesduring1993�2005.Weconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformation

availableinFISD.Weexcludeconvertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,private

placementbonds,Yankee,Canadianandforeigncurrencybonds.Thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceof

dividendandotherpaymentrestrictions.Table2givesmoredetailsonthecovenantsthatfallintothedividend

andotherpayment

restrictionscategoryandisbasedontheclassi�cationofSmithandWarner(1979).Thehistoricalstateofincorporationisobtained

from

EDGAR10-K

�lingsofthe�rm.NimbleDividends:WefollowPetersonandHawker(1997)andassignNIMBLE=1ifthe

corporatelawofthestateinwhichthebondissuerisincorporatedallowsboardsofdirectorstopaycashandpropertydividendsoutof

eitherearnedsurplusorthesumofthe"precedingandcurrent�scalyear�searnings".Earningsratherthanearnedsurplusde�nethe

operativelimitonthelegalityofthese"nimbledividends."Consequently,boardsofdirectorscouldconceivablydeclarecashdividends

evenwhentotalliabilitiesexceedtotalassets.TotalAssetConstraint:TACONSTR=1ifthecorporatelawofthestateinwhichthe

bondissuerisincorporatedrequiresthatthe�rmcanpaydividendsorotherdistributionsonlyifitmeetstheassettest,i.e.,thatthenet

assetsofthe�rmshouldbegreaterthanitsliabilities.PROFITistheratioof�rm�spro�tabilitytothetotalassetsofthe�rm.LEVER

iscomputedastheratioof�rm�stotaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassetsofthe�rm.TNGASSETis

theratioofnetplant,propertyandequipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBisthelogarithmofmarket-to-bookratioof

the�rm.OPINCVOListhestandarddeviationofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast�veyears.CREDITSPRisthedi¤erence

intheyieldsofBAAandAAAratedbonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturitymeasuredinmonths.LOANSIZEis

theratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthebondisrated

non-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe�rmbelongsutilityindustry.The

regressionsalsoincludeindicatorsforcallableandputablefeaturesofthebondinboththemodels.Models1and2areestimatedon

2173bonds.Robuststandarderrorsadjustedfor�rmlevelclusteringarepresentedinparenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

42

Model1

Model2

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

TACONSTR

-0.4084

(-2.28)

NIMBLE

0.3876

(2.23)

PROFIT

0.6908

(0.48)

0.3204

(0.22)

LEVER

1.4293

(2.88)

1.4912

(2.90)

SIZE

-0.4077

(-2.87)

-0.4672

(-3.40)

TNGASSET

-0.4275

(-0.96)

-0.3200

(-0.72)

MTB

-1.5462

(-3.82)

-1.5910

(-3.83)

OPINCVOL

2.3255

(0.67)

2.1448

(0.60)

CREDITSPR

0.2332

(0.69)

0.3163

(0.92)

MATURITY

-0.1561

(-0.96)

-0.0866

(-0.55)

LOANSIZE

0.1889

(1.40)

0.1348

(1.03)

JUNKRATED

2.1693

(11.03)

2.1985

(11.14)

UTIL

0.3579

(0.98)

0.3600

(0.97)

intercept

2.3579

(1.78)

1.8842

(1.43)

R2

0.706

0.713

43

Table9:DeterminantsofSubsequentFinancingRestrictions

Thefollowingtableanalyzesthedeterminantsoftheuseofsubsequent�nancingrestrictions,usingaprobitregression.The2006edition

oftheFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.Thesampleisrestrictedtobonds

issuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutiveCompensationdatabases

during1993�2005.WeconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailableinFISD.Weexclude

convertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,privateplacementbonds,Yankee,

Canadian,andforeigncurrencybonds.Thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceofsubsequent�nancingrestric-

tions.Table2givesmoredetailsonthecovenantsthatfallintothesubsequent�nancingrestrictionsrestrictionscategoryandisbased

ontheclassi�cationofSmithandWarner(1979).SubsequentFinancingRestrictionsequalsoneifthebond�sindenturecontainsoneof

debtpriorityrestrictions,stockissuancerestrictions,subordinatedebtrestrictions,restrictionsonsaleandleaseobligations.ENTRCis

constructedusingaprinicipalcomponentanalysisasalinearcombinationofentrenchmentvariables(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,

andCEOSHROWN)withtheweightsbeingtheelementsoftheeigenvectorthataccountsforthehighestpercentageofthevariation

inalloftheaboveentrenchmentvariables.ENTRPissimilarlyconstructedexceptthistimethesetofentrenchmentvariablesused

include(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,CEOSHROWN,LNGCEOTNR,PCASHCOMP,BLOCKHOLDERS).CEODELTAdenotes

thedeltaoftheCEO�sstockandoptioncompensationcomputedbytheBlack-Scholes-Mertonmodelusingthemethodologyoutlined

inCoreandGuay(1999).CEORELCOMPistheratiooftheCEO�stotalcompensationtothesumofthetotalcompensationofthe

otherfourtopexecutivesreportedinexecutivecompensationdatabase.PCASHCOMPistheratioofCEO�scashsalarytothetotal

compensation.CEOSHROWNisthepercentageofthe�rm�soutstandingsharesthatareheldbytheCEO.LNGCEOTNRisthesquare

oflengthofCEOtenuremeasuredinyears(fromthedateshebecameCEO).PROFITistheratioof�rm�spro�tabilitytothetotal

assetsofthe�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof�rm�stotaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassetsof

the�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,propertyandequipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBisthelogarithm

ofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhestandarddeviationofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast�veyears.

CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAandAAAratedbonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturitymeasured

inmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueof

oneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe�rmbelongs

utilityindustry.Theregressionsalsocontrolforindicatorsforcallableandputablefeaturesofthebondinallthemodels.Model1-3

areestimatedon3019,2611and2531bondsrespectively.Robuststandarderrorsadjustedfor�rmlevelclusteringarepresentedin

parenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

44

Model1

Model2

Model3

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

ENTRC

-0.1737

(-3.65)

ENTRP

-0.1553

(-3.64)

PROFIT

0.8738

(0.58)

0.0884

(0.05)

0.0535

(0.03)

LEVER

1.3804

(1.82)

1.3222

(1.53)

1.2713

(1.41)

SIZE

-0.2295

(-2.33)

-0.2083

(-2.03)

-0.2132

(-2.00)

TNGASSET

-0.5741

(-1.46)

-0.7053

(-1.64)

-0.7378

(-1.64)

MTB

-0.4678

(-2.10)

-0.1052

(-0.35)

-0.1556

(-0.52)

OPINCVOL

0.0778

(0.02)

-0.3857

(-0.12)

-1.1573

(-0.36)

CREDITSPR

-0.7068

(-2.57)

-0.6158

(-1.97)

-0.6533

(-2.06)

MATURITY

0.1671

(3.02)

0.1665

(2.56)

0.1716

(2.58)

LOANSIZE

0.0455

(0.46)

0.0237

(0.23)

0.0229

(0.21)

JUNKRATED

0.1523

(0.71)

0.3542

(1.53)

0.4174

(1.68)

UTIL

-1.2210

(-5.63)

-1.2714

(-5.70)

-1.2811

(-5.54)

intercept

3.6103

(4.47)

3.3728

(4.01)

3.5144

(4.07)

R2

0.211

0.227

0.227

45

Table10:DeterminantsofEventRestrictions

Thefollowingtableanalyzesthedeterminantsoftheuseofeventspeci�crestrictions,usingaprobitregression.The2006editionof

theFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.Thesampleisrestrictedtobonds

issuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutiveCompensationdatabases

during1993�2005.WeconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailableinFISD.Weexclude

convertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,privateplacementbonds,Yankee,

Canadian,andforeigncurrencybonds.Thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceofeventrelatedrestrictions.

Table2givesmoredetailsonthecovenantsthatfallintotheeventrelatedrestrictionscategoryandisbasedontheclassi�cationof

SmithandWarner(1979).Eventrestrictionsiscodedasoneifthebond�sindenturecontainsatleastonecovenantfallingunderdefault

relatedeventcovenantsoriftheindenturecontainsachangeincontrolpoisonput.Defaultrelatedeventcovenantsinclude:cross

default,crossacceleration,ratingdeclinetriggerputanddecliningnetworthcovenant.G-IndexandE-INDEXareconstructedusing

the�rmlevelcharterprovisionsasinGompers,IshiiandMetrick(2003)andBebchuk,Cohen,andFerrell(2004)respectively.ENTRP

isconstructedusingaprinicipalcomponentanalysisasalinearcombinationofentrenchmentvariables(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,

CEOSHROWN,LNGCEOTNR,PCASHCOMP,BLOCKHOLDERS)withtheweightsbeing

theelementsoftheeigenvectorthat

accountsforthehighestpercentageofthevariationinalloftheaboveentrenchmentvariables.CEODELTAdenotesthedeltaofthe

CEO�sstockandoptioncompensationcomputedbytheBlack-Scholes-MertonmodelusingthemethodologyoutlinedinCoreandGuay

(1999).CEORELCOMPistheratiooftheCEO�stotalcompensationtothesumofthetotalcompensationoftheotherfourtop

executivesreportedinexecutivecompensationdatabase.PCASHCOMPistheratioofCEO�scashsalarytothetotalcompensation.

CEOSHROWNisthepercentageofthe�rm�soutstandingsharesthatareheldbytheCEO.LNGCEOTNRisthesquareoflength

ofCEOtenuremeasuredinyears(fromthedateshebecameCEO).PROFITistheratioof�rm�spro�tabilitytothetotalassetsof

the�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof�rm�stotaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassetsofthe

�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,propertyandequipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBisthelogarithm

ofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhestandarddeviationofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast�veyears.

CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAandAAAratedbonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturitymeasured

inmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueof

oneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe�rmbelongs

utilityindustry.Theregressionsalsocontrolforindicatorsforcallableandputablefeaturesofthebondinallthemodels.Model1-4

areestimatedon3019,2839,2839and2531bondsrespectively.Robuststandarderrorsadjustedfor�rmlevelclusteringarepresented

inparenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

46

Model1

Model2

Model3

Model4

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

G�INDEX

-0.0749

(-3.25)

E�INDEX

-0.1113

(-2.17)

ENTRP

0.0147

(0.29)

PROFIT

-1.0131

(-0.92)

-0.7210

(-0.66)

-0.8589

(-0.78)

-0.5878

(-0.55)

LEVER

0.7044

(1.73)

0.7573

(1.81)

0.6441

(1.58)

0.5687

(1.33)

SIZE

-0.3904

(-5.76)

-0.4035

(-6.00)

-0.4066

(-6.03)

-0.3651

(-5.01)

TNGASSET

0.3841

(1.26)

0.4348

(1.36)

0.4557

(1.43)

0.3097

(0.96)

MTB

-0.1827

(-0.88)

-0.3500

(-1.77)

-0.2328

(-1.12)

-0.2728

(-1.45)

OPINCVOL

-0.1090

(-0.05)

-0.5745

(-0.25)

-0.0649

(-0.03)

-0.8305

(-0.37)

CREDITSPR

-0.5043

(-2.72)

-0.5192

(-2.67)

-0.5381

(-2.82)

-0.5026

(-2.60)

MATURITY

-0.0321

(-0.78)

-0.0364

(-0.89)

-0.0355

(-0.86)

-0.0179

(-0.41)

LOANSIZE

0.0084

(0.11)

0.0452

(0.59)

0.0367

(0.49)

0.0156

(0.20)

JUNKRATED

1.0857

(6.01)

1.0172

(5.47)

1.0714

(5.65)

1.1181

(5.75)

UTIL

-0.3038

(-1.54)

-0.4597

(-2.24)

-0.3355

(-1.65)

-0.3192

(-1.48)

intercept

3.8566

(7.05)

4.9282

(7.72)

4.2970

(7.38)

3.6110

(6.04)

R2

0.224

0.222

0.215

0.199

47

Table11:ImpactofCorporateCharterProvisionson

EventRestrictions

Thefollowingtableanalyzestheimpactofcertaincorporatecharterpovisionsontheuseofeventrestrictions,usingaprobitregression.

The2006editionoftheFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.Thesample

isrestrictedtobondsissuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutive

Compensationdatabasesduring1993�2005.Weconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailable

inFISD.Weexcludeconvertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,privateplacement

bonds,Yankee,Canadian,andforeigncurrencybonds.Thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceofeventrelated

restrictions.Table2givesmoredetailsonthecovenantsthatfallintotheeventrelatedrestrictionscategoryandisbasedonthe

classi�cationofSmithandWarner(1979).Eventrestrictionsiscodedasoneifthebond�sindenturecontainsatleastonecovenant

fallingunderdefaultrelatedeventcovenantsoriftheindenturecontainsachangeincontrolpoisonput.Defaultrelatedeventcovenants

include:crossdefault,crossacceleration,ratingdeclinetriggerputanddecliningnetworthcovenant.PPILLisadummyvariablethat

takesthevalueofoneifthe�rm�scharterhasapoisionpillprovisionandzerootherwise.G-INDEXandthesub-indicesG-DELAY,

G-PROTECTION,G-STATE,G-VOTING,G-OTHERareconstructedusingthe�rmlevelcharterprovisionsasinGompersetal.

(2003).PROFITistheratioof�rm�spro�tabilitytothetotalassetsofthe�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof�rm�stotaldebt

tototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassetsofthe�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,propertyandequipment

ofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBisthelogarithmofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhestandarddeviation

ofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast�veyears.CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAandAAAratedbonds.

MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturitymeasuredinmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe�rm.

JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisadummy

variablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe�rmbelongsutilityindustry.Theregressionsalsocontrolforindicatorsforcallableand

putablefeaturesofthebondinallthemodels.Models1-2areestimatedon2839bonds.Robuststandarderrorsadjustedfor�rmlevel

clusteringarepresentedinparenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

48

Model1

Model2

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

PPILL

-0.2396

(-1.92)

G�DELAY

-0.0867

(-1.60)

G�STATE

0.0742

(1.50)

G�PROTECTION

-0.1094

(-2.13)

G�VOTING

0.0432

(0.62)

G�OTHER

-0.1186

(-1.79)

PROFIT

-0.9450

(-0.85)

-0.9306

(-0.81)

LEVER

0.7722

(1.81)

0.7264

(1.79)

SIZE

-0.4018

(-6.00)

-0.3870

(-5.83)

TNGASSET

0.3853

(1.22)

0.5187

(1.68)

MTB

-0.2436

(-1.16)

-0.2904

(-1.45)

OPINCVOL

0.0729

(0.03)

0.1224

(0.05)

CREDITSPR

-0.5379

(-2.81)

-0.5387

(-2.71)

MATURITY

-0.0280

(-0.69)

-0.0403

(-0.98)

LOANSIZE

0.0340

(0.45)

0.0476

(0.67)

JUNKRATED

1.0415

(5.44)

1.0276

(5.36)

UTIL

-0.3789

(-1.85)

-0.5194

(-2.55)

intercept

4.2100

(7.24)

4.5556

(7.37)

R2

0.211

0.234

49

Table12:TheImpactoftheSarbanes-OxleyActon

BondCovenants

Inthefollowingtable,weanalyzetheimpactoftheSarbanes-OxleyActof2002onthedeterminantsofthevariouscovenants.The

2006editionoftheFixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.

Thesample

isrestrictedtobondsissuedbyU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutive

Compensationdatabasesduring1993�2005.Weconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailablein

FISD.Weexcludeconvertiblebonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,privateplacement

bonds,Yankee,Canadian,andforeigncurrencybonds.Further,only�rmsthatissuedbondsbothbeforeandafterthepassageof

Sarbanes-Oxleyactareincludedintheanalysis.InModel1,thedependentvariableisan

indicatorvariableforthepresenceof

investmentrestrictions.InModels2-4,thedependentvariablesareindicatorvariablesforthepresenceofdividendandotherpayment

restrictions,subsequent�nancingrestrictionsandeventrelatedrestrictionsrespectively.Table2givesmoredetailsontheclassi�cation

ofthecovenantsthatisbasedonSmithandWarner(1979).POSTSOXisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneforbonds

thatareissuedafterthepassageofSarbanes-OxleyAct(Oct,2002).ENTRPisconstructedusingaprinicipalcomponentanalysis

asalinearcombinationofentrenchmentvariables(CEODELTA,CEORELCOMP,CEOSHROWN,LNGCEOTNR,PCASHCOMP,

BLOCKHOLDERS)withtheweightsbeingtheelementsoftheeigenvectorthataccountsforthehighestpercentageofthevariation

inalloftheaboveentrenchmentvariables.CEODELTAdenotesthedeltaoftheCEO�sstockandoptioncompensationcomputed

bytheBlack-Scholes-MertonmodelusingthemethodologyoutlinedinCoreandGuay(1999).CEORELCOMPistheratioofthe

CEO�stotalcompensationtothesumofthetotalcompensationoftheotherfourtopexecutivesreportedinexecutivecompensation

database.PCASHCOMPistheratioofCEO�scashsalarytothetotalcompensation.CEOSHROWNisthepercentageofthe�rm�s

outstandingsharesthatareheldbytheCEO.LNGCEOTNRisthesquareoflengthofCEOtenuremeasuredinyears(fromthedate

shebecameCEO).PROFITistheratioof�rm�spro�tabilitytothetotalassetsofthe�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof�rm�s

totaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassetsofthe�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,propertyand

equipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBisthelogarithmofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhestandard

deviationofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast�veyears.CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAandAAArated

bonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturitymeasuredinmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe

�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisa

dummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe�rmbelongsutilityindustry.Theregressionscontrolforindicatorsforcallableand

putablefeaturesofthebondinallthemodels.Models1-4areestimatedon1555bonds.Robuststandarderrorsadjustedfor�rmlevel

clusteringarepresentedinparenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

50

Model1:Investment

Model2:Dividend

Model3:Subsequent

Model4:Event

Restrictions

Restrictions

FinancingRestrictions

Restrictions

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

POSTSOX

0.3382

(1.40)

-0.2475

(-1.48)

-0.2251

(-1.22)

-0.0527

(-0.49)

ENTRP

0.3278

(1.68)

-0.1577

(-2.49)

-0.1385

(-2.58)

-0.0407

(-0.67)

PROFIT

-3.8864

(-1.84)

1.0999

(0.69)

0.9870

(0.45)

-1.6577

(-1.03)

LEVER

0.3266

(0.42)

1.5511

(2.02)

1.6212

(1.37)

0.9736

(1.52)

SIZE

-0.2818

(-1.52)

-0.3539

(-2.50)

-0.2617

(-1.81)

-0.3641

(-3.62)

TNGASSET

-0.0050

(-0.01)

-0.6664

(-1.42)

-1.0889

(-2.08)

0.4664

(1.04)

MTB

-0.0413

(-0.09)

-1.1215

(-2.93)

-0.0798

(-0.18)

-0.1555

(-0.62)

OPINCVOL

-6.7890

(-1.87)

3.8740

(1.04)

-3.1638

(-0.87)

-1.6682

(-0.56)

CREDITSPR

0.1957

(0.29)

-0.1519

(-0.41)

-0.4969

(-1.31)

-0.4926

(-2.02)

MATURITY

0.0038

(0.03)

-0.0544

(-0.45)

0.1391

(1.83)

-0.0104

(-0.18)

LOANSIZE

0.2587

(1.90)

0.3586

(2.71)

-0.0340

(-0.24)

0.1297

(1.29)

JUNKRATED

-0.1207

(-0.34)

2.5869

(12.82)

0.3829

(1.28)

1.0444

(4.11)

UTIL

0.4326

(0.95)

0.6053

(1.77)

-1.3228

(-4.45)

-0.3078

(-1.05)

intercept

5.8621

(3.45)

2.1830

(1.92)

3.7609

(3.11)

3.8355

(4.53)

R2

0.238

0.687

0.249

0.208

51

Table13:TheE¤ectofAnalysts�ForecastDispersion

onBondCovenants

Theimpactofanalystforecastdispersiononthedeterminantsofthevariouscovenantsisanalyzedinthistable.The2006editionofthe

FixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.Thesampleisrestrictedtobondsissued

byU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutiveCompensationdatabasesduring

1993�2005.WeconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailableinFISD.Weexcludeconvertible

bonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,privateplacementbonds,Yankee,Canadian,and

foreigncurrencybonds.Further,only�rmsthathaveanalystforecastdataavailableinI/B/E/Sareincludedintheanalysis.InModel

1,thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceofinvestmentrestrictions.InModels2-4,thedependentvariables

areindicatorvariablesforthepresenceofdividendandotherpaymentrestrictions,subsequent�nancingrestrictionsandeventrelated

restrictionsrespectively.Table2givesmoredetailsontheclassi�cationofthecovenantsthatisbasedonSmithandWarner(1979).

ThekeyexplanatoryvariableisANYLDISPthatisconstructedasthestandarddeviationofearningsforecastdividedbystockprice

attheendof�scalyear.PROFITistheratioof�rm�spro�tabilitytothetotalassetsofthe�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof

�rm�stotaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenaturallogarithmoftotalassetsofthe�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,property

andequipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe�rm.MTBisthelogarithmofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhe

standarddeviationofthe�rm�soperatingincomeoverthepast�veyears.CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAand

AAAratedbonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmofbondmaturitymeasuredinmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototal

assetsofthe�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.

UTILisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofoneifthe�rmbelongsutilityindustry.Theregressionsalsocontrolforindicatorsfor

callableandputablefeaturesofthebondinallthemodels.Models1-4areestimatedon2450bonds.Robuststandarderrorsadjusted

for�rmlevelclusteringarepresentedinparenthesisnexttothemodelestimates.

52

Model1:Investment

Model2:Dividend

Model3:Subsequent

Model4:Event

Restrictions

Restrictions

FinancingRestrictions

Restrictions

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

ANYLDISP

70.1839

(2.53)

2.1358

(0.95)

0.8685

(0.20)

1.5279

(0.75)

PROFIT

-1.4693

(-0.60)

0.6351

(0.51)

1.4794

(0.90)

-1.4841

(-1.18)

LEVER

0.0762

(0.10)

1.5284

(3.01)

1.0609

(1.29)

0.6720

(1.44)

SIZE

-0.1583

(-1.20)

-0.5062

(-4.28)

-0.2825

(-2.58)

-0.3596

(-4.77)

TNGASSET

-0.4981

(-1.02)

-0.1185

(-0.32)

-0.5757

(-1.28)

0.4556

(1.34)

MTB

0.0379

(0.13)

-1.3459

(-3.89)

-0.5114

(-2.12)

-0.1550

(-0.67)

OPINCVOL

-3.8160

(-0.92)

1.2436

(0.48)

-2.1914

(-0.69)

-0.9997

(-0.40)

CREDITSPR

1.2974

(2.05)

0.2460

(0.84)

-0.7355

(-2.46)

-0.6052

(-2.99)

MATURITY

0.0165

(0.16)

-0.0961

(-0.87)

0.2000

(2.87)

-0.0489

(-1.04)

LOANSIZE

0.2750

(1.65)

0.0944

(0.79)

-0.0222

(-0.22)

0.1041

(1.26)

JUNKRATED

0.6220

(2.13)

2.0933

(12.91)

0.2256

(0.99)

1.0914

(5.49)

UTIL

0.1757

(0.56)

0.0963

(0.34)

-1.1829

(-4.53)

-0.5846

(-2.64)

intercept

3.2749

(2.02)

2.4692

(2.52)

3.7281

(4.03)

4.0840

(6.69)

R2

0.168

0.654

0.213

0.240

53

Table14:TheE¤ectofFinancialTransparency

onBondCovenants

Thefollowingtableanalyzestheimpactof�nancialtransparencyonthedeterminantsofthevariouscovenants.The2006editionofthe

FixedIncomeSecuritiesDatabase(FISD)isthesourceforallthedatapresentedinthistable.Thesampleisrestrictedtobondsissued

byU.S.domicilednon-�nancial�rmsintheintersectionofCRSP/COMPUSTAT,FISDandExecutiveCompensationdatabasesduring

1993�2005.WeconsideronlycorporatedebentureswithissuanceandcovenantinformationavailableinFISD.Weexcludeconvertible

bonds,securedleaseobligations,perpetualbonds,unitdeals,rule144abonds,MTN,privateplacementbonds,Yankee,Canadian,and

foreigncurrencybonds.InModel1,thedependentvariableisanindicatorvariableforthepresenceofinvestmentrestrictions.In

Models2-4,thedependentvariablesareindicatorvariablesforthepresenceofdividend

andotherpaymentrestrictions,subsequent

�nancingrestrictionsandeventrelatedrestrictionsrespectively.Table2givesmoredetailsontheclassi�cationofthecovenantsthatis

basedonSmithandWarner(1979).FINTRNSPisameasureof�nancialtransparencyandmeasuresthenumberofitemsdisclosedin

theannualreport.ThisinformationiscompiledbyS&Paspartoftheirtransparencyanddisclosurerankings[see,Chengetal.(2006)

formoreinformationonStandard&PoorsTransparency&DisclosureRankings].Theindexisavailablefor2002andweassumethat

�rmshavethesamelevelofdisclosurefor2001and2003alsoandusethisdatafor2001-2003period.PROFITistheratioof�rm�s

pro�tabilitytothetotalassetsofthe�rm.LEVERiscomputedastheratioof�rm�stotaldebttototalassets.SIZEisthenatural

logarithmoftotalassetsofthe�rm.TNGASSETistheratioofnetplant,propertyandequipmentofthe�rmtototalassetsofthe

�rm.MTBisthelogarithmofmarket-to-bookratioofthe�rm.OPINCVOListhestandarddeviationofthe�rm�soperatingincome

overthepast�veyears.CREDITSPRisthedi¤erenceintheyieldsofBAAandAAAratedbonds.MATURITYisthelogarithmof

bondmaturitymeasuredinmonths.LOANSIZEistheratioofloansizetototalassetsofthe�rm.JUNKRATEDisadummyvariable

thattakesthevalueofoneifthebondisratednon-investmentgradeatissuance.UTILisadummyvariablethattakesthevalueofone

ifthe�rmbelongsutilityindustry.Theregressionsalsocontrolforindicatorsforcallableandputablefeaturesofthebondinallthe

models.InModel1,JUNKRATED=1predictssuccessperfectlyandhenceitisdroppedandthemodelisestimatedon456bonds.

Models2-4areestimatedon511bonds.Robuststandarderrorsadjustedfor�rmlevelclusteringarepresentedinparenthesisnextto

themodelestimates.

54

Model1:Investment

Model2:Dividend

Model3:Subsequent

Model4:Event

Restrictions

Restrictions

FinancingRestrictions

Restrictions

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

Estimate

t-val

FINTRNSP

0.2906

(1.62)

-0.3617

(-2.22)

0.1305

(1.22)

0.0310

(0.23)

PROFIT

2.2303

(0.65)

0.3947

(0.11)

1.3141

(0.41)

-3.9001

(-1.78)

LEVER

0.5167

(0.35)

1.0136

(1.01)

0.0464

(0.04)

0.7963

(0.93)

SIZE

-0.1362

(-0.52)

-0.8617

(-2.08)

-0.4359

(-2.36)

-0.5497

(-3.24)

TNGASSET

-1.3012

(-1.21)

-3.3027

(-2.41)

-1.5542

(-2.42)

0.2498

(0.44)

MTB

0.0666

(0.17)

-1.7499

(-1.51)

-0.6184

(-1.49)

0.1607

(0.51)

OPINCVOL

-12.1061

(-2.32)

5.8221

(1.12)

-0.4813

(-0.09)

-0.6474

(-0.17)

CREDITSPR

-1.1117

(-1.22)

-0.1094

(-0.15)

-0.6191

(-1.36)

-0.8055

(-2.47)

MATURITY

-0.1992

(-0.87)

1.0702

(4.58)

0.2443

(1.81)

-0.1710

(-1.64)

LOANSIZE

0.0236

(0.07)

0.3574

(0.88)

-0.1629

(-0.89)

-0.0413

(-0.26)

JUNKRATED

2.9773

(5.05)

0.8043

(1.81)

0.7648

(2.00)

intercept

3.8199

(1.95)

2.6204

(0.87)

4.1911

(2.59)

5.8700

(3.70)

R2

0.213

0.672

0.190

0.150

55