Time MattersPostindustrialization, New Social Risks, and Welfare State Adaptation in Advanced...

26
Time Matters Postindustrialization, New Social Risks, and Welfare State Adaptation in Advanced Industrial Democracies Giuliano Bonoli Swiss Graduate School of Public Administration Lausanne, Switzerland Western welfare states were built during the postwar years, with one key objective: to protect family (male) breadwinners against the consequences of losing their ability to extract an income from the labor market. Structures of social risk, however, have changed dramatically since then, so that current social risks include precarious employment, long-term unemployment, being a working poor, single parenthood, or inability to reconcile work and family life. Changes in structures of social risk have resulted in the adaptation of welfare states only in the Nordic countries but much less in continental and southern Europe. To account for this divergence in social policy trajectories, this article argues that the reorientation of the Nordic welfare state was pos- sible because new social risks emerged before the maturation of the postwar welfare states. The argument is demonstrated through comparative statistical analysis relating the timing of key socioeconomic developments to current levels of spending in relevant policies. Keywords: social policies; welfare reform; new social risks W estern welfare states were essentially conceived and built during the postwar years, with one key objective: to protect wage earners form the social risks associated with the then-dominant patterns of employment and family structures. Above all, postwar welfare states were about reduc- ing the dependency of wage earners and their families on the vagaries of markets. The process of commodification of labor that had been brought Comparative Political Studies Volume 40 Number 5 May 2007 495-520 © 2007 Sage Publications 10.1177/0010414005285755 http://cps.sagepub.com hosted at http://online.sagepub.com 495 Author’s Note: This article is based on work presented at several conferences and benefited enormously from comments made. In particular, I thank Klaus Armingeon, Jochen Clasen, Evelyne Huber, Lane Kenworthy, Jane Lewis, Bruno Palier, Lyle Scruggs, Nico Siegel, and John Stephens.

Transcript of Time MattersPostindustrialization, New Social Risks, and Welfare State Adaptation in Advanced...

Time MattersPostindustrialization, New SocialRisks, and Welfare State Adaptationin Advanced Industrial DemocraciesGiuliano BonoliSwiss Graduate School of Public AdministrationLausanne, Switzerland

Western welfare states were built during the postwar years, with one keyobjective: to protect family (male) breadwinners against the consequences oflosing their ability to extract an income from the labor market. Structures ofsocial risk, however, have changed dramatically since then, so that currentsocial risks include precarious employment, long-term unemployment, beinga working poor, single parenthood, or inability to reconcile work and familylife. Changes in structures of social risk have resulted in the adaptation ofwelfare states only in the Nordic countries but much less in continental andsouthern Europe. To account for this divergence in social policy trajectories,this article argues that the reorientation of the Nordic welfare state was pos-sible because new social risks emerged before the maturation of the postwarwelfare states. The argument is demonstrated through comparative statisticalanalysis relating the timing of key socioeconomic developments to currentlevels of spending in relevant policies.

Keywords: social policies; welfare reform; new social risks

Western welfare states were essentially conceived and built during thepostwar years, with one key objective: to protect wage earners form

the social risks associated with the then-dominant patterns of employmentand family structures. Above all, postwar welfare states were about reduc-ing the dependency of wage earners and their families on the vagaries ofmarkets. The process of commodification of labor that had been brought

Comparative Political StudiesVolume 40 Number 5

May 2007 495-520© 2007 Sage Publications

10.1177/0010414005285755http://cps.sagepub.com

hosted athttp://online.sagepub.com

495

Author’s Note: This article is based on work presented at several conferences and benefitedenormously from comments made. In particular, I thank Klaus Armingeon, Jochen Clasen,Evelyne Huber, Lane Kenworthy, Jane Lewis, Bruno Palier, Lyle Scruggs, Nico Siegel, andJohn Stephens.

about by the industrial revolution and the advent of capitalism was nowbeing turned back for the first time in two centuries (Esping-Andersen,1990; Polanyi, 1957). The postwar welfare state protected well against therisk of being unable to extract an income from the labor market, be itbecause of sickness, invalidity, old age, or lack of employment. Because ofthe dominant family arrangement of the time, its efforts were concentratedon the male breadwinner. Directly, women did not benefit much from thepostwar welfare state, except in the event of widowhood or, in other words,when the male breadwinner was no longer there. Postwar welfare stateswere arguably well adapted to the societies in which they were conceivedand developed: industrial societies with stable family structures and a cleardivision of labor between men and women in couples. They were success-ful in guaranteeing a poverty-free existence to almost all and in securingextremely high levels of social cohesion.

Since the 1970s, however, things have changed dramatically. A numberof socioeconomic trends have transformed the societies in which we live, sothat today the inability of the family father to extract an income from thelabor market is certainly not the only important risk to which wage earnersare exposed, nor is it probably the most serious one. Postindustrial labormarkets are characterized by higher wage inequality with the result that forthose at the bottom end of the wage distribution, access to employment is nota guarantee of a poverty-free existence. Family instability, resulting inincreases in divorce rates and in single parenthood, have reduced the rele-vance of the figure of the male breadwinner and created new social problemsfor which postwar welfare states are at best unprepared. Women’s entry intolabor markets, if it has reduced the dependence of households on the malebreadwinner, also creates new problems and dilemmas. Socioeconomictransformations have shifted the target of social policies away from the malebreadwinner and toward women and younger, often low-skill people.

But have welfare states adapted their shooting, and are they aiming inthe right direction? Studies of comparative social policy show that theanswer to this question is inevitably mixed. Some welfare states have beenrather successful in adapting to changed patterns of social risk. This is thecase above all of the Nordic countries, where policies for women andfamilies are highly developed, where unemployed people have access to awhole arsenal of active labor market policies, and where wage inequality hasincreased only moderately. In contrast, continental and southern Europeanwelfare states seem to have largely failed so far to take into account thechanging nature of social risk. Countries such as Italy or Germany continueto put the bulk of their welfare effort in income replacement programsdesigned for core (male) workers and have neglected the emergence of new

496 Comparative Political Studies

social risks associated with employment and family change. Liberal welfarestates, finally, have somewhat shifted their focus away from the male bread-winner and toward new risk groups, but in a way that puts more emphasison manipulating the incentive structure they are faced with than on providingprotection against the new risks.

The objective of this article is to account for such divergence in socialpolicy trajectories, focusing in particular on the bifurcation between Nordicand continental European countries. Why did some countries from the 1970sonward begin to reorient their welfare states in the direction of better pro-tection of new social risks while other ones stuck to the trajectory defined inthe early postwar years? Different national paths in social policy develop-ments are nothing new in comparative social policy, but what is intriguing inthe current phase of adaptation is the fact that the countries that have gonefurthest in developing protection against new social risks were not the mostgenerous postwar welfare states. As will be argued below, the traditionalsocial risks associated with an industrial society were covered most exten-sively in continental European countries. Contrary to the dominant viewfound in the literature, I claim that the most generous welfare states for(male) wage earners were not those found in the Nordic countries but thoselocated in continental and southern Europe. The impression is that a gener-ous postwar welfare state and a high level of coverage for new social risksare mutually exclusive, or at least inversely related. This observation contra-dicts prevailing theories of comparative social policy making, which con-sider welfare state expansion, whether today or in the old days, to be aconsequence of the power resources of the Left and of the labor movement.

To try to untangle this puzzle, this article introduces the time dimensionin the analysis of social policy making. As argued by Paul Pierson (2004),policy analysts tend to forget the importance of time-based factors, such assequences or the relative timing of key events. This article shows that theinclusion of time-based independent variables in an explanatory model ofsocial policy making improves its ability to account for apparently puzzlingobservations. It considers several important developments such as socialchange, political mobilization of actors, and policy feedback effects and sit-uates them in time. The result is a picture in which countries display dif-ferent configurations of the relevant independent variables at key momentsin time in a way that helps to account for the observed divergence in tra-jectories of welfare state adaptation. Put simply, countries that experiencedpostindustrial social transformations in the 1970s (northern European,English-speaking countries) faced a more favorable situation for develop-ing new social risk policies because competing claims because of popula-tion aging and generous pension promises were negligible at the time. In

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 497

contrast, continental and southern European countries, where developmentssuch as the tertiarization of employment and increased family instabilityoccur with a time lag of 20 to 30 years, are facing emerging new demandsin a context where competing claims are highest, leaving little room tomaneuver to develop new social risk policies.1

Social Change and New Social Risks

In this article, new social risks are understood as situations in whichindividuals experience welfare losses and that have arisen as a result of thesocioeconomic transformations that have taken place during the past threeto four decades and that are generally subsumed under the heading ofpostindustrialization. The most important of these are deindustrializationand the tertiarization of employment, the massive entry of women into thelabor force, increased instability of family structures, and the destandard-ization of employment. These trends, both individually and in interactionwith one another, have altered structures of social risk in Western societies(on the concept of new social risks, see Bonoli, 2005, in press; Hemerijck,2002; Jenson, 2002; Taylor-Gooby, 2004). These trends are briefly sketchedin this section. Data giving some idea of the magnitude of social changeinvolved are provided below in the quantitative analysis.

Deindustrialization and the Tertiarization of Employment

In recent years, one of the most important sources of social risk has beendeindustrialization and its consequences, in terms of mass unemploymentamong industrial workers but especially in terms of a labor market where theservice sector is predominant. Even though the total volume of employmenthas not decreased during the past four to five decades, the replacement ofindustrial jobs by service sector employment has left large numbers of for-mer industrial workers jobless and unable to reintegrate the labor market inthe service sector. The key consequence of this development has been long-term unemployment, a social risk that was virtually unheard of during thetrente glorieuses. Industrial long-term unemployment, however, may not bethe most important social consequence of deindustrialization, especiallybecause it is a temporary phenomenon, related to the transition frompredominantly industrial to predominantly service-based economies. Ascohorts of dismissed industrial workers reach retirement age, this type ofunemployment will slowly fade away.

498 Comparative Political Studies

The decline of manufacturing and the expansion of service employment,however, have altered labor markets in a more fundamental way, especiallyat their lower end, consisting of low-skill, low-value-added jobs. Low-skillindividuals have always experienced disadvantage. However, during thepostwar years, low-skill workers were predominantly employed in the man-ufacturing industry. They were able to benefit from productivity increasesbecause of technological advances so that their wages rose in line with thoseof the rest of the population. The strong mobilizing capacity of the tradeunions among industrial workers further sustained their wages, which cameto constitute the guarantee of a poverty-free existence. Today, low-skill indi-viduals are mostly employed in the low-value-added service sector or areunemployed. Low-value-added services such as retail sale, cleaning, cater-ing, and so forth are known for providing very little scope for productivityincreases (Pierson, 1998). In countries where wage determination is essen-tially based on market mechanisms, this means that low-skill individuals areseriously exposed to the risk of being paid a poverty wage (United States,United Kingdom, Switzerland). The situation is different in countries wherewage determination, especially at the lower end of the distribution, is con-trolled by governments (through generous minimum wage legislation) or bythe social partners (through encompassing collective agreements). Underthese circumstances, the wages of low-skill workers are protected, but jobcreation in these sectors is limited, so that many low-skill individuals are infact unemployed (Iversen & Wren, 1998). Overall, the fact of possessing lowor obsolete skills today entails a major risk of welfare loss, considerablyhigher than in the postwar years. The resulting new social risks are long-term (low-skill) unemployment and working poverty.

Women’s Entry Into Labor Markets

Women’s increased labor force participation is obviously not a source ofsocial risk per se. If anything, couples with two incomes are better pro-tected against the risk of poverty. Rather, a new risk stems from the inabil-ity to combine motherhood and child rearing with paid employment. Sincethe 1970s, starting in northern Europe, we see the gradual entry of women,and particularly married women with young children, into labor markets.This has meant that the standard division of labor within couples that wastypical of the trente glorieuses has collapsed. The domestic and child carework that used to be performed on an unpaid basis by housewives nowneeds to be externalized, either to state-provided services or to markets. Inmany countries, parents (but most significantly women) experience severe

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 499

difficulties in finding adequate child care provision. This is a major sourceof frustration and can result in important losses of welfare, for example if aparent reduces working hours because of the unavailability of adequatechild care facilities. But the inability to reconcile work and family life canlead to more than just frustration. To the extent that dual-earner coupleswith children are considerably less likely to be in poverty than are familiesthat follow the male breadwinner model (Esping-Andersen, 2002, p. 58),inability to reconcile work and family life can, especially for low-incomeparents, be associated with a poverty risk. The inability to reconcile workand family life concerns above all parents of young children but also work-ers who have a frail (elderly) relative requiring care.

Increased Instability of Family Structures

Since the early postwar years, indicators of family instability havesoared in most countries. Divorce rates, out-of-wedlock births, and the pro-portions of single-parent households show that family bonds are todaymore uncertain than 50 years ago. Like women’s participation in the labormarket, family instability is not a social risk per se, but its consequencesare. Lone parenthood, for instance, is associated with a higher incidence ofpoverty in all Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development(OECD) countries. What is more, the incidence of poverty is particularlyhigh for lone parents who are not in work (Esping-Andersen, 2002, p. 37).For them, the ability to reconcile work and family life may be crucial ifpoverty is to be avoided. In addition, most social security systems assumedstable family marriages, and divorce often results in entitlement losses forone or both partners. Divorced women, for instance, are often among theleast covered in pension systems.

The Destandardization of Employment

The shift to a postindustrial employment structure has resulted in thepresence in modern labor markets of career profiles that are very differentfrom that of the standard male worker of the trente glorieuses, characterizedby full-time, continuous employment from an early age and with a steadilyrising salary. Yet the social security schemes (most notably pensions) thatwe have inherited from the postwar years are still clearly based on these tra-ditional assumptions regarding labor market participation. Pension cover-age, in most western European countries, is optimal for workers who spendtheir entire working life in full-time employment. Part-time work usuallyresults in reduced pension entitlements, as do career interruptions. The

500 Comparative Political Studies

result of the presence of these new career profiles in the labor market maybe, if pension systems are not adapted, the translation of the labor marketand working poor problems of today into a poverty problem for olderpeople in 30 or 40 years. From an individual point if view, the fact of fol-lowing an atypical career pattern entails a risk of insufficient social securitycoverage and hence a loss of welfare.

Patterns of Welfare StateAdaptation to New Social Risks

The social risks that have emerged during the past two or three decadesare generally not well covered by the welfare states that we have inheritedfrom the postwar years. In some cases, however, the policy design chosenfor protecting industrial workers turned out to be quite suitable for the newrisk groups. One can think, for example, of the wage bargaining system inthe Nordic countries or in Germany, which has existed throughout the post-war years and continues to perform a protective function for disadvantagedworkers to the present day. Solidaristic and encompassing wage agreementshave prevented the emergence of a working poor problem in these coun-tries. In most cases, however, policies designed to protect male industrialworkers against the loss of work income are of little use to most new riskgroups. Welfare states need to be adapted if they are to continue to deliverthe levels of social stability typical of the postwar years and to respond tocitizens’ expectations.

In this section, I try to map the extent to which countries have respondedto the emergence of new social risks. For the sake of clarity, I distinguishbetween a first set of policies labeled “industrial social policies” or the“postwar social policies” and a second group labeled “new social risk poli-cies” or “postindustrial social policies.” The former consists of policieswhose objective is to replace the income of wage earners, especially thosefulfilling a breadwinning function, when these are unable to extract anincome from the labor market. Functional equivalents such as employmentprotection laws (protection against dismissal) should also be considered partof the “industrial welfare state.” New social risk policies, in contrast, provideprotection against the risks and the problems associated with the socioeco-nomic transformations described above, loosely described by the notion ofpostindustrialization. Note that this distinction does not cover all the policiesthat are traditionally considered part of the welfare state, most notably healthcare, which cannot be unequivocally assigned to one or the other set. Healthrisks have certainly changed over time but have not had an impact on the

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 501

ability of health policy to provide good coverage. Universal access to thebest available treatment was and remains the best possible coverage againstboth old and new health risks. There are also policies that, depending on thedesign, can be seen as belonging to one set or as combining features of both.Universal flat rate pensions, for instance, have provided effective protectionagainst old age poverty to industrial workers and turn out to be particularlysuitable for today’s atypical employees. As a result, the analysis that followsmust be considered a best approximation rather than a precise description ofreal cross-national differences.

But why distinguish between two sets of social policy along the linessuggested above? First, these policies constitute responses to differentsocioeconomic transformations. The postwar welfare state can be seen asthe long-awaited response to the tremendous disruption and social insta-bility brought about by industrialization. New social risk policies, instead,constitute attempts to deal with problems that have little to do with indus-trialization and result from more recent social transformations. Second, andperhaps more important, the target groups of these two sets of policies aredifferent. It is of course impossible to define clear borders between groupsthat benefit from one or the other set of policies, but quite clearly, today, thepostwar welfare state targets (mostly male) older workers and older peoplein general, whereas the main beneficiaries of new risk policies are womenand younger, often low-skill people. The distinction between these twogroups is necessarily blurred, but postwar and new risk social policies areclearly aiming in different directions. Third, as will become clear below, ananalysis of welfare states that distinguishes between these two sets of poli-cies suggests that some widely held beliefs in relation to the ranking of wel-fare states by the extent to which they provide coverage against social riskshould be reconsidered.

The strategy followed to map postwar and new social risks policies con-sists of two steps.2 First, I outline the main features of each set of policiesin different welfare regimes on the basis of secondary literature on com-parative social policy. Second, I perform a descriptive, quantitative analysisusing social expenditure data provided by the OECD.

Industrial Social Risks in Postwar Welfare States

The standard view in the comparative social policy literature is that themost developed and generous social protection systems are found in thesocial democratic welfare states of northern Europe (see Castles &Mitchell, 1992; Esping-Andersen, 1990; Huber, Ragin, & Stephens, 1993;

502 Comparative Political Studies

Korpi, 1983; Palme, 1990). This conclusion is the result of the conflationof policies belonging to the industrial welfare state and those providing cov-erage against new social risks. This is clear in Esping-Andersen’s (1990)seminal work on welfare regimes, whose rank ordering of welfare states interms of the level of decommodification they provide largely depends onthe degree of conditionality of benefits, which is lower in social democra-tic welfare states. Income replacement benefits in continental Europeanwelfare states tend to be equally generous but generally require longer peri-ods of labor market participation. This difference is obviously importantfor new social risk groups, who are considerably better protected in socialdemocratic welfare states. It mattered less, however, for the industrialworkers of the trente glorieuses. Full employment made it easy to fulfill thecontribution requirements of the continental European welfare states. Inaddition, the contributory character and the equivalence principle embodiedin continental social insurance–based welfare states constituted a safeguardagainst the possibility of free riding by other social groups (Baldwin, 1990;Clasen, 1997). This is consistent with the strong attachment to social insur-ance shown by trade unions throughout continental Europe and by theirinsistence that the state should not use social insurance as a general socialpolicy instrument (Palier, 2002).

If, following the perspective put forward in this article, we distinguishbetween industrial social policies and policies that provide coverage againstnew social risks, the standard view found in the literature must be qualified.Policies providing protection against the typical industrial social risks wereprobably more developed in the continental European welfare states (e.g.,Germany, Italy, or France) than is generally acknowledged. This is not onlybecause social insurance served this purpose particularly well, but alsobecause industrial workers in continental Europe benefited from additionaladvantages in comparison to their Nordic counterparts. The first advantagewas more generous pension coverage. This was not so much the result ofhigher replacement rates (these tend to be similar between continental andnorthern Europe) but is because of a lower age of retirement, both in law andin practice. In 1980, French or Italian men, on average, retired some 3 yearsearlier than did their Swedish or Danish counterparts, with a comparablebenefit level (Scherer, 2001). In general, both the legal and the effective ageof retirement have been a few years lower in continental European countriesthan in northern Europe. From the point of view of industrial workers, thecore target of the industrial welfare state, this is obviously not a negligibledifference, as shown by the strong reluctance to accept increases in the ageof retirement.

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 503

Second, employment protection laws were (and are) considerably stricterin continental and particularly southern Europe. In this part of the world, thepath followed to protect workers from the vagaries of markets did not onlyrely on income replacement programs but put considerable emphasis onsecuring people’s place in the labor market by making it hard for theiremployers to lay them off (Bonoli, 2003; Whiteside & Salais, 1998). Writingin the 1960s, British political economist Andrew Shonefield (1964) notedwith surprise that in France workers have “quasi property rights” to theirjobs. In fact, in countries such as Italy, France, and Germany, strict employ-ment protection laws were used as functional equivalents to income replace-ment programs to provide economic security to wage earners. This form ofprotection was not included in Esping-Andersen’s (1990) analysis but can beseen as a functional equivalent to decommodification. After all, it resultedfrom workers’ and unions’ demands.

If all of the above is taken into account, it is then clear that with regard tothe degree of protection granted to industrial workers, continental Europeanwelfare states were at least as developed as those of northern Europe. Tosome extent, they used other tools for providing economic security, but theyalso targeted their efforts more precisely on industrial workers. This claim isconsistent with the view put forward by those who have studied the impactof Christian democracy on social policy, who have argued that the Christiandemocratic variety of the welfare state is characterized by generous earningsreplacement cash benefits and by an underdeveloped social service sector(Huber & Stephens, 2001; van Kersbergen, 1995).

New Social Risks in Postindustrial Welfare States

If we focus on the second set of policies we are interested in (i.e., thepolicies that provide coverage against the new social risks defined above),then it is clearly the Nordic countries that have gone furthest in providingprotection (Taylor-Gooby, 2004; Timonen, 2004). First, the initial setup ofsocial democratic welfare states, based less on social insurance and more onuniversal provision, turned out to be much more suitable to the emerging,new, postindustrial labor market and family structures. The alliance betweenworkers and farmers at the beginning of the 20th century had resulted in apreference for tax-financed, noncontributory social programs, for examplein the field of pensions (Baldwin, 1990; Ferrera, 1993), which serve partic-ularly well the new atypical career profiles that have become increasinglycommon during the past two or three decades. Second, the postwar arrange-ment, based on centralized wage bargaining and active labor market policies(the so-called Rehn-Meidner model) developed for the benefit of industrial

504 Comparative Political Studies

workers, turned out to be particularly useful in protecting postindustrialservice workers against the risk of being paid a poverty wage and in pre-venting long-term unemployment and social exclusion (Benner & Vad,2000; Rueda & Pontusson, 2000). Social democratic postwar welfare states,thus, even though they were built for industrial workers, already embodiedmany features that will make them more suitable to protect against the newsocial risks that have emerged in more recent years.

But the higher level of protection against new social risks found in socialdemocratic welfare states cannot be explained only by institutional predis-position. Countries such as Sweden or Denmark were able to take intoaccount changes in the socioeconomic sphere from the 1970s onward and toreorient their welfare states accordingly. This is clear in the case of policiesfor women. Indicators from the mid-1960s show little difference betweenNordic and continental European countries in relation, for instance, tofemale employment rates. In 1965 the female employment rate was 53% inSweden and 49% in Denmark, against 52% for Switzerland and 49% forGermany and the United Kingdom and 42% for the United States (OECD,2004c). Sweden did have a tradition in providing child care services, butthese were set up in the context of combating poverty rather than facilitatingthe conciliation of employment and family life (Morel, 2001). In fact, thedevelopment of extensive child care coverage and other policies supportingwomen’s (and mothers’) employment followed the expansion of femaleemployment; it did not precede it (Leira, 1992). Like in much of continen-tal Europe today, the late 1960s and early 1970s for working mothers in theNordic countries were dominated by juggling and by reliance on informalcare (Leira, Tobio, & Trifiletti, 2004; Naumann, 2001). The reorientation ofthe Nordic welfare state began in the 1970s. Sweden introduced individualtaxation in 1971, its first law on preschool education in 1973 and parentalleave in 1974. A law on child care was introduced in Norway in 1975.

Things followed a different course in continental European countriesand in the United Kingdom. Female employment remained stable aroundthe 50% mark until the late 1980s, when it started increasing. In fact,female employment in continental and southern European countries seemsto be following the Nordic pattern with a delay of some two to threedecades. Thus, female employment reached 60% in Sweden in 1972. Thesame level was reached in Switzerland in 1988, in the United Kingdom in1989, in the Netherlands in 1999 and in Austria in 2002. Other continentalEuropean countries have also seen dramatic increases in the femaleemployment rate during the past decade (by around 6 percentage points),but these remain below the 60% mark: In 2003 the female employment ratein Germany was 59%, in France 56%, and in Italy 43% (OECD, 2004a). In

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 505

the latter three countries, high unemployment and low employment ratesamong (male and female) older workers are responsible for somewhatlower female employment rates. The social transformations behind theemergence of new risks and new demands are clearly proceeding at a dif-ferent pace in different countries. Can the same be said for the developmentof the relevant policies? Is the reorientation of the Dutch, the Swiss, or theGerman welfare state just a matter of time?

The findings of the comparative social policy literature suggest that thisis not the case. The country studies included in Scharpf and Schmidt’s (2000)comprehensive analysis of trends in social and employment policies showlittle evidence that countries such as Italy, Germany, Switzerland, or Austriaare responding to increases in female labor market participation with thedevelopment of the relevant policies on a large scale. Some reforms havebeen adopted, often through political exchange or “vice-into-virtue” strate-gies (Levy, 1999), but the 2000s in Germany or Italy are clearly not like the1980s in Sweden or Denmark, even though the demand for child careservices can be considered similar. In 1980, Denmark and Sweden spent1.8% and 2.2%, respectively, of their GDP on family services, essentiallychild care, whereas in 2001 Germany and Italy spent 1.1% and 0.5%,respectively (OECD, 2004b). The same argument can be made in relationto other areas of social policy that are particularly relevant to those who arehit by new social risks, in particular active labor market policies.

The above discussion has focused essentially on Nordic and continentalEuropean welfare states. But how did liberal welfare states respond to theemergence of new social risks, generally speaking, in a way that has been con-sistent with their historical preference for market solutions and that sees stateintervention as appropriate only where market failures are evident? Changesin skill requirements by employers have resulted in a downward adjustment ofwages for low-skill occupations, with the well-known increases in inequalityin many English-speaking countries (Förster & Pearson, 2002). Similarly, withregard to demands stemming form women’s entry into employment, marketshave provided the services requested. This was more clearly the case in theUnited States, where low wages for child care workers facilitated the expan-sion of this sector.

Spending on Industrial and New Social Risk Policies

Social expenditure as a proportion of GDP is one of the most widelyavailable and used indicators in the cross-national comparison of socialpolicies. As noted by many, it is problematic in the sense that it is influencedby the denominator (GDP); it is sensitive to changes in the number of

506 Comparative Political Studies

beneficiaries and tells us little about how the money is spent (Esping-Andersen, 1990; Siegel, 2000). However, it can provide a first approxima-tion of the extent to which countries have developed polices in given fields.Its other advantage is that it makes it possible to synthesize in a simple indi-cator a substantial amount of information. An analysis based on socialexpenditure on industrial and new risk social policies can thus complementthe picture presented above by providing a more synthetic view.

In Figure 1, different items of social expenditure are assigned either to thecategory of industrial social policies or to the one of new social risk policies,on the basis of the definitions used above. Policies that aim above all at

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 507

2.00 4.00 6.00 8.00

Spending on NSR policies

7.50

10.00

12.50

15.00

17.50

Sp

end

ing

on

ind

ust

rial

so

cial

po

licie

s

��

AUS

A

B

CAN

DK

FINF

D

I

NL

NZ

N

P

E

S

CH

UK

US

Figure 1Spending on Industrial and on New Social Risk (NSR) Policies in

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)Countries as a Proportion of GDP, 5-Year Averages (1997-2001)

Note: Recalculation of data from OECD (2004b).

replacing the income of the family father in a context of full employment areconsidered industrial social policies. These include old age and survivorcash benefits, incapacity cash benefits and services, and unemployment cashbenefits. In contrast, policies that aim at protecting individuals from theconsequences of postindustrial socioeconomic trends in the labor market orin the family field are counted as new social risk policies. These includespending for families (cash and services), active labor market policies, oldage services,3 and social assistance (cash and services). This is a rough dis-tinction, partly dictated by the breakdown of expenditure data chosen bythe OECD. But it does correspond to the definitions used in this article,whether in terms of risks or in terms of social groups that are mostlytargeted by the relevant policies.

The distribution of countries in relation to the effort made in protectingagainst industrial and new social risks reflects the comments made above inthe descriptive analysis of policies. Interestingly, countries cluster aroundregime type, but not in the way one would expect on the basis of Esping-Andersen’s (1990) decommodification analysis. In relation to industrial socialpolicies, it is continental European countries that make the biggest effort,especially Italy, Switzerland, Austria, and Belgium, four typically conserva-tive welfare states. In contrast, in relation to new social risk policies, theleaders are clearly the Nordic countries, especially Sweden, Denmark, andNorway. Liberal welfare states, instead, are found in the bottom left quad-rant, which means that these countries have made only modest efforts ineither policy direction. Of course there is also some variation within thethree clusters. France and Germany provide better new social risk coveragethan do other continental European countries. The United Kingdom, proba-bly the less liberal of the liberal welfare states, in this classification ends uptogether with continental European countries, though at the bottom of thegroup in relation to the effort made in covering industrial social risks.

The separate analysis of industrial and new risk social policies and theresulting country distribution presented in Figure 1 reveal a puzzle for thecomparative social policy literature. Analyses that do not consider the twoareas of social policy separately, by definition, do not allow for the possi-bility that the factors that lead to the developments of industrial and newsocial risk policies, respectively, be different. But, as the country distribu-tion presented in Figure 1 shows, this must be the case. The factors that areconducive to the development of generous industrial welfare states cannotat the same time be leading to extensive new social risk coverage. It wouldotherwise be impossible to account for the bifurcation between continentaland Nordic countries visible in the graph.

508 Comparative Political Studies

Accounting for Divergent National Trajectories

In this section I discuss three hypotheses that can help make sense of thepattern of cross-national variation emerging from Figure 1: the different roleplayed by social and Christian democratic parties in the development of post-war welfare states, the changing function and adaptability of postwar welfarestate structures, and the timing of relevant socioeconomic developments.

Christian Versus Social Democracy

As shown by several studies, social democracy was not the only politi-cal force behind the development of welfare states. Christian democraticparties played an important role as well (Huber & Stephens, 2001; vanKersbergen, 1995). The welfare states developed by Christian democrats,however, distinguished themselves for a preference for less redistributionneeded to comply with the cross-class character of these parties and for lessemphasis on services, particularly those services that replace family taskssuch as child care. The reference to the Catholic social doctrine, subsidiarity,and the preference for the traditional male breadwinner–housewife familyarrangement explain these features (Huber & Stephens, 2001).

This explanation is basically convincing, but there are a number of prob-lems with it. First, it neglects the fact that the postindustrial socioeconomictrends that resulted in the reorientation of the Nordic welfare states were muchmore advanced in these countries in the 1970s than they were in continentaland southern Europe. To some extent, this may be because of the predomi-nance of Catholicism in these countries, which contained and delayedwomen’s aspirations for access to work income. The ideology of social part-nership supported by Christian democrats may also have been responsible fora delay in the restructuring of industry and the resulting decline of industrialemployment in those countries. The apparent impact of Christian democracymay be less because of the ideological stance of Christian democrats and morebecause of the impact that Catholicism has had on the timing of key socio-economic developments. Second, the decline of Christian democracy duringthe past decade in almost all the western European countries in which theseparties were once dominant has not freed the way for the expansion of newsocial risk policies. During the past 10 years, Christian democrats have beenforced out of government or have seen their traditionally strong influence ingovernment reduced in Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Belgium, andSwitzerland. Yet new social risk policies have not mushroomed in these coun-tries. Third, it is true, as Huber and Stephens (2001, pp. 41-44) argue, that the

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 509

aversion of Christian democrats to services is particularly strong for family-replacing activities and not so relevant in education or health. But there areother areas of new social risk policies, such as active labor market policies, thatwould fit particularly well with the requirement to satisfy non-working-classvoters. Facilitating re-entry in the labor market is certainly a more appealingsolution than is the passive compensation of joblessness for the middle-classvoters who make up a substantial part of the electorate of Christian democrats.Yet active labor market policies, such as other new social risk policies, areunderdeveloped in continental European welfare states.

In sum, the ideological stance of Christian democrats may be inimical tosome new social risk policies, but this is unlikely to be the only explanationof the divergence of national trajectories highlighted above.

Institutional Predisposition

As seen above, during the postwar years all western European countriesdeveloped comprehensive systems of social protection and labor market regu-lation providing coverage against the main traditional social risks. The instru-ments chosen to that end, however, were very different. Some countries limitedstate intervention to redistribution (United Kingdom), whereas other onesintervened in the functioning of labor markets with clear social policy objec-tives, either through legislation (France, Italy) or collectively negotiated agree-ments (Germany, Nordic countries; Bonoli, 2003; Whiteside & Salais, 1998).

These different instruments turned out to be more or less suitable torespond to the new social demands and needs resulting from the transitionto a postindustrial society. This has been the case in particular in the Nordiccountries where some of the social transformations associated with the sur-facing of new social risks have not resulted in the emergence of widespreadsocial problems. In fact, the risks associated with service employment (lowwage, insecurity) and with family change (reconciling work and family life)were, in some circumstances, already well covered by programs developedin the context of the postwar welfare states, often for a different purpose.This is clearly the case of Sweden (and to some extent of the other Nordiccountries), which in the 1950s developed an employment regime based onegalitarian collective wage bargaining and on active labor market policies,the already mentioned Rehn-Meidner model.

Old institutions matter also because they can be more or less amenable toadaptation. Clasen and Clegg (in press) show that the inclusion of activationelements in unemployment compensation schemes has been politically morefeasible in countries where the government has more or less direct controlover these policies, such as Denmark and the United Kingdom. In contrast,

510 Comparative Political Studies

in Germany and in France, where unemployment insurance is managed bythe social partners, the inclusion of activation elements has been considerablymore difficult. The French preschool system (école maternelle) constitutes asecond, often-quoted example of a long-standing institution that can beadapted to new demands. Preschools were first introduced at the end of the19th century in the context of an ongoing struggle between Republicans andthe Catholics for the control of the education system. Today, thanks also tovarious adjustments, for example in opening times, the école maternelle rep-resents a highly valued and used form of child care for children aged 3 to 6(Morgan, 2001).

The choices made by the architects of the postwar welfare state clearly haveconsequences in relation to the extent to which new social risks are covered.In some contexts, for example in the Nordic countries, employment-relatednew social risks may not even be perceived as such because their emergenceis de facto pre-empted by existing policies. Such instances, however, are rare.In most cases, effective coverage against new social risks requires the adop-tion of new policies or the radical reorientation of existing ones.

Timing

As pointed out above, the trends that are responsible for the emergenceof new social risks have progressed at a different pace in different countriesand regions. Broadly speaking, the Nordic and some English-speakingcountries (United States, United Kingdom, and Canada) have been the firstset of countries to enter the postindustrial age in the 1970s. They were fol-lowed by continental European countries about a decade later and by south-ern Europe even later. The claim made in this article is that differences inthe timing of key postindustrial socioeconomic developments will not onlygenerate catching up phenomena but may result in permanent differences inthe degree of development of new social risk policies.

The claim is based on the following argument. In countries that haveentered the postindustrial age relatively early, new demands generated bythe ongoing social transformations found comparatively little competition.Those hit by new social risks had to fight in the political arena to obtainbetter coverage, but they could count on the broad support of those actorsthat are generally in favor of welfare expansion, such as the Left and thetrade unions. In contrast, in countries that have developed into postindustrialsocieties more recently, demands for protection against new social risks arein strong competition with demands for the preservation, in spite of popu-lation aging, of the current level of protection provided by industrial wel-fare states. This requires enormous resources and can count on a substantial

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 511

level of popular support, whereas new social risk groups are notoriouslypolitically weak, both in terms of presence in key democratic political insti-tutions and in terms of participation in elections (Bonoli, 2005; Norris,2002). One consequence of the unbalanced power relationship between oldand new social risk groups is that incentives for vote-maximizing politicalactors are clearly geared toward the defense of the industrial welfare staterather than toward the development of new social policies. Demographictrends and differentials in turnout between age groups make it rational forvote-seeking politicians to present themselves as the defenders of the pen-sion system rather than the champions of child care, negative income taxes,or active labor market policies.

The presence of competing claims for different sets of social policiesaffects incentives across the whole political spectrum but can have a par-ticularly strong divisive effect on traditional prowelfare constituencies,such as left-wing voters and parties and labor movements. This is visible inthe increasingly strong cleavage between modernizers and traditionaliststhat characterizes the Left in many continental European countries.4 Suchdivisions reduce the chances of seeing the expansion of new social riskpolicies, particularly, because left-wing politicians are exposed to the sameincentive structure as everybody else and are thus likely, if forced to choose,to prefer the defense of the industrial welfare state.

Time is crucial in this argument. Whether countries manage or fail toreorient their welfare states in a way that reflects changed socioeconomiccircumstances depends on the relative timing of key socioeconomic trendsin interaction with existing welfare state structures. The key developmentsare postindustrialization and the increase in the cost of the industrialwelfare state resulting from the combination of demographic aging andgenerous pension promises. These two developments must not happensimultaneously if a welfare state is to be successfully reoriented.

How to test this hypothesis is far from being a straightforward task andrequires some ad hoc methods that may not conform to current orthodoxy incomparative policy research but that produce some intriguing results. Thefirst problem is how to characterize countries in relation to how advancedthey are at a given point in time in relation to the various relevant postin-dustrial socioeconomic trends. Table 1 offers a pragmatic answer to thisquestion. It takes as a benchmark the level of some relevant socioeconomicindicators in Sweden in 1970. As argued above, 1970 marks the beginningof the reorientation for the Swedish welfare state. The choice of this bench-mark is to a large extent arbitrary, but it provides us with a yardstick that canbe used to compare all countries (yardsticks are often arbitrary; what mattersis relativities). Then, for all the OECD countries for which sufficiently long

512 Comparative Political Studies

data time series are available, it reports the year in which the benchmark(i.e., the Swedish level in 1970) was reached. To summarize the informationprovided in relation to three socioeconomic trends, deindustrialization,expansion of female employment, and family instability, it reports for eachcountry the rounded average of the year in which the benchmark wasreached in the three trends (average benchmark year). The average benchmark

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 513

Table 1The Timing of Key Postindustrial Developments in 18 Organisation

for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Countries

Service Female Employment as Employment Rate, Divorce a Percentage of as a Proportion Rate (Divorce AverageTotal Civilian of the 15-64 as per 100 Benchmark

Employment (%) Population (%) Marriages) Year

Benchmark 54 58 30(Swedish levelin 1970)

Year in Which the Swedish 1970Level Was Reached (Benchmark Year)

Sweden 1970 1970 1970 1970Denmark — 1971 1972 1972Norway 1972 — 1981 1977Finland 1983 1982 1976 1980UK 1975 1988 1975 1979United States <1970 1984 <1970 1975Canada <1970 1987 1978 1978Australia <1970 1995 — 1982New Zealand 1978 1988 — 1979Germany 1986 2001 1981 1989France 1978 >2003 1982 1988Netherlands — 1998 1981 1990Switzerland 1980 1987 1980 1982Belgium — >2003 1984 1993Austria 1988 1994 1982 1988Italy 1985 >2003 >2003 1994Spain 1989 >2003 >2003 1996Portugal 1992 1990 >2003 1995

Note: Calculations are based on the OCED Statistical Compendium. In case of data missing inthe relevant years, the benchmark year has been estimated through linear interpolation. For thecalculation of averages, when the Swedish level was reached before 1970 or was not reacheduntil 2003 (end of data series), 1970 and 2003, respectively, were used.

year should not be interpreted as an attempt to precisely identify the momentin which countries become postindustrial societies. It simply provides anindication of the relative degree of advancement in the various countriesof the social trends identified above as responsible for the emergenceof new social risks. In some cases, the Swedish 1970 level was reachedbefore 1970.

Broadly speaking, the timing of the relevant socioeconomic develop-ments reflects the degree of development of new social risk policies, as pre-sented above. The early postindustrializers, the Nordic countries, have themost comprehensive systems of new social risk coverage. They are followedby the continental European countries, which reached Swedish levels ofpostindustrialization in the late 1980s, and, finally, by southern Europe.English-speaking countries, however, do not seem to fit the hypothesis. Thekey postindustrial socioeconomic trends progressed fast but were notaccompanied by the development of new social risk policies. This, however,reflects what happened during the postwar years, which did not see in thesecountries the construction of welfare states comparable to those of conti-nental and northern Europe. There are also differences within groups ofcountries. For instance, Finland is a latecomer among the Nordic group, asAustralia and New Zealand are among English-speaking countries.

Simple statistical analysis shows that the average benchmark year cal-culated above is related to the level of spending on new social risk policies,as shown in Figure 2. The two variables are clearly associated, with aPearson correlation coefficient of –.57, significant at the .01 level (one-tailed). The relationship becomes even stronger if the new social risk bias,or the proportion of social spending that is attributed to new social riskpolicies, is taken as a dependent variable (Pearson = –.64, graph not repro-duced). This suggests that in countries that are less inclined to turn to thestate for dealing with social problems (English-speaking countries essen-tially), there is also a relationship between the timing of relevant socioeco-nomic trends and the development of new social risk policies, but this takesplace in the context of lower social expenditure.

The hypothesis presented in this article assumes a trade-off betweenspending on industrial and new social risk policies. However, there is noclear negative relationship between spending on these two functions (seeFigure 1). Why is it so? The answer is that the trade-off is asymmetric. Highlevels of industrial social policy spending prevent the development of newsocial risk policies, whereas high levels of spending on new social riskpolicies do not prevent the continuing expansion of spending on industrialsocial policies. The latter, in fact, does not depend so much on politicaldecisions but more on inevitable processes such as population aging and

514 Comparative Political Studies

program maturation. As a result, countries that have developed extensivenew social risk coverage in the past will continue to see social expenditureon industrial social policy increase. The average benchmark year is posi-tively but not significantly correlated with spending on industrial socialpolicies (Pearson’s r = .46).

These findings are all compatible with the timing hypothesis presentedabove, but can we rule out a simpler explanation, making reference to prob-lem pressure and to a time lag that policy needs to adapt to new needs anddemands? Countries in which problem pressure developed earlier have hadmore available time to respond to these new problems and, as a result, havetoday more comprehensive systems of protection against them. This simplerhypothesis implies that the apparent divergence among Western welfare

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 515

1970.00 1980.00 1990.00

Average benchmark year

2.00

4.00

6.00

8.00

�� ��

��

��

AUSA BCAN

DK

FIN

FD

I

NL

NZ

N

PE

S

CH

UK

US

Sp

end

ing

on

new

so

cial

ris

k p

olic

ies

Figure 2Relationship Between the Average Benchmark Year and Spending

on New Social Risk Policies, 1997 to 2001 Average

Note: See Table 1 and Figure 1 for details.

states is just a matter of time and that if given sufficient time, countries suchas Italy, Germany, and Switzerland will develop policy responses comparableto those that are currently in force in the Nordic countries. Considering thecurrent and expected budgetary pressures in southern and continental Europeancountries, this scenario looks most unlikely. In addition, like all explana-tions based simply on problem pressure, this hypothesis is not theoreticallyvery convincing, and it contradicts three decades of comparative social pol-icy research showing the absence of a direct link between problem pressureand policy solutions. Finally, empirically, this simpler explanation implies

516 Comparative Political Studies

0.00 2.00 4.00 6.00 8.00

Spending on NSR policies, 1987-1991

0.00

1.00

2.00

Incr

ease

in N

SR

sp

end

ing

in t

he

1990

s

��

AUS

B

CAN

DK

FIN

F

D

I

NL

NZ

N

PE

S

CH

UK

US

Figure 3Increase in Spending on New Social Risk (NSR) Policies

in the 1990s and Spending in 1987 to 1991

Note: See Figure 2 for details. Increase in NSR spending in the 1990s: difference betweenaverage NSR spending 1987-1991 and 1997-2001.

that late postindustrializers should now be catching up with the Nordiccountries and should be investing more in new social risk policies.Comparing spending on new social risk policies in two periods (1987-1991and 1997-2001), however, suggests that this is not the case. If a catching-up process were going on, one would expect the increase in spending onnew social risk policies between the two periods to be inversely related withthe amount spent in the earlier period. There is indeed a negative relation-ship between these two variables, but it is very weak (Pearson’s r = –.25)and nonsignificant (see Figure 3).

Conclusion

The main contribution of this article is the introduction of timing as an inde-pendent variable of social policy making in the past three decades. Althoughthe empirical evidence provided shows that the timing of different relevantsocioeconomic development has an impact on the shape of current welfarestates, some qualifications are needed. First, the timing explanation must notbe seen as an alternative to the prevailing interpretations of welfare state devel-opment but as a complement. The relevance of independent variables such asthe power resources of the working class, the strength of left-wing parties, orconstitutional structures is not disproved by this study. In fact, the scatter plotabove (Figure 2) shows a fair degree of unexplained variance in the dependentvariable. In particular, both industrial and new social risk policies are underde-veloped in English-speaking countries (especially the United States), a resultthat can be more easily explained with reference to the weakness of the Left inthose countries. Cross-national differences in the political mobilization ofwomen may also account for variation in the degree of development of newsocial risk policies (Huber & Stephens, in press). Second, more sophisticatedtesting of the timing explanation would be required. This could be done byusing pooled time-series analysis and lagged variables. Ideally, the hypothesisshould be tested in multivariate models, together with the other variables iden-tified in the literature as relevant for explaining the development of welfarestates, something that is clearly beyond the scope of this article.

The article has also attempted to develop a technique that can be used tointegrate the time dimension in policy analysis. Following Pierson’s (2004)call to pay attention to the “when” of social and political phenomena,it shows a relatively simple way in which time-based factors such assequences, the relative timing of given events, or differences in the speedof some trends can be integrated in policy analysis in a measurable way.

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 517

Time-based variables can arguably be developed further and integrated instatistical models of policy making, providing thus an opportunity to testthe time matters hypothesis.

Finally, on a more substantive level, the findings presented in the articleare not good news for those who are hit by new social risks in continentaland southern Europe. These countries have missed a window of opportunityto reorient their welfare states. During the next two to three decades, becauseof population aging, it will become increasingly difficult to introduce newsocial policies. Of course political struggles may be fought with the aim toimprove the living conditions of new social risk groups, but for a long while,the balance of power will be tilted in favor of the preservation of industrialsocial policies rather than toward the development of a new welfare state.

Notes

1. Similar arguments are made in Huber and Stephens (in press) and Fargion (2000). Thesestudies, however, do not attempt to empirically test the timing hypothesis.

2. For reasons of space, the mapping presented in this article must be synthetic, but a morecomprehensive analysis is provided in Bonoli (in press).

3. The inclusion of services for older people among the new social risk policies reflects thefact that in many cases, the main beneficiary of such policies is not frail elderly people them-selves but their children, especially their daughters. In the absence of services provided by thestate (or market), it is in fact generally family members who provide the informal care needed,of course where possible. This is in contrast with the decision to assign services for incapac-ity to industrial social risk policies. These include rehabilitation services that aim at reinsert-ing incapacitated workers into labor markets.

4. See, for example, in Germany the fight within the SPD on social and economic policies(Hering, 2004) or in Italy the strong division between the center Left and the refundedCommunist Party (Ferrera & Gualmini, 2000).

References

Baldwin, P. (1990). The politics of social solidarity. Class bases of the European welfare state1875-1975. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Benner, M., & Vad, T. (2000). Sweden and Denmark: Defending the welfare state. InF. W. Scharpf & V. Schmid (Eds.), Welfare and work in the open economy (pp. 399-467).Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

Bonoli, G. (2003). Social policy through labour markets. Understanding national differencesin the provision of economic security to wage earners. Comparative Political Studies, 36,983-1006.

Bonoli, G. (2005). The politics of the new social policies. Providing coverage against newsocial risks in mature welfare states. Policy and Politics, 33, 431-450.

518 Comparative Political Studies

Bonoli, G. (in press). New social risks and the politics of postindustrial social policies. InK. Armingeon & G. Bonoli (Eds.), The politics of postindustrial welfare states. London:Routledge.

Castles, F. G., & Mitchell, D. (1992). Identifying welfare state regimes: The links betweenpolitics, instruments and outcomes. Governance: An International Journal of Policy andAdministration, 5(1), 1-26.

Clasen, J. (1997). Social insurance in Europe. Bristol, UK: Policy Press.Clasen, J., & Clegg, D. (in press). New labour market risks and the revision of unemployment

protection systems in Europe. In K. Armingeon & G. Bonoli (Eds.), The politics of postin-dustrial welfare states. London: Routledge.

Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge, UK: Polity.Esping-Andersen, G. (2002). Why we need a new welfare state. Oxford, UK: Oxford

University Press.Fargion, V. (2000). Timing and the development of social care services in Europe. West

European Politics, 23(2), 59-88.Ferrera, M. (1993). Modelli di solidarietà. Politica e riforme sociali nelle democrazie [Models

of solidarity. Social policy and reform in democratic countries]. Bologna, Italy: Il Mulino.Ferrera, M., & Gualmini, E. (2000). Italy: Rescue from without? In F. W. Scharpf & V. A. Schmidt

(Eds.), Welfare and work in the open economy (pp. 351-398). Oxford, UK: Oxford UniversityPress.

Förster, M., & Pearson, M. (2002). Income distribution and poverty in the OECD area: Trendsand driving forces. OECD Econoimic Studies, 34, 7-38.

Hemerijck, A. (2002). The self-transformation of the European social model(s). In G. Esping-Andersen (Ed.), Why we need a new welfare state (pp. 173-214). Oxford, UK: OxfordUniversity Press.

Hering, M. (2004). Turning ideas into policies: Implementing modern Social Democraticthinking in Germany’s pension policy. In G. Bonoli & M. Powell (Eds.), Social Democraticparty policies in contemporary Europe (pp. 102-122). London: Routledge.

Huber, E., Ragin, C., & Stephens, J. D. (1993). Social democracy, Christian democracy, con-stitutional structure, and the welfare state. American Journal of Sociology, 99, 711-749.

Huber, E., & Stephens, J. (2001). Development and crisis of the welfare state. Parties andpolicies in the global markets. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Huber, E., & Stephens, J. (in press). Combatting old and new social risks. In K. Armingeon &G. Bonoli (Eds.), The politics of postindustrial welfare states. London: Routledge.

Iversen, T., & Wren, A. (1998). Equality, employment, and budgetary restraint. The trilemmaof the service economy. World Politics, 50, 507-546.

Jenson, J. (2002, August). From Ford to Lego: Redesigning welfare regimes. Presented at theAnnual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston.

Korpi, W. (1983). The democratic class struggle. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Leira, A. (1992). Welfare states and working mothers. The Scandinavian experience.

Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Leira, A., Tobio, C., & Trifiletti, R. (2004). Kinship and informal support as resources for the

first generation of working mothers in Norway, Italy and Spain. Unpublished manuscript.Levy, J. (1999). Vice into virtue? Progressive politics and welfare reform in continental

Europe. Politics and Society, 27, 239-273.Morel, N. (2001). Politique sociale et égalité entre les sexes en Suède [Social policy and

gender equality in Sweden]. Recherches et Prévisions, 64, 65-79.

Bonoli / Welfare State Adaptation 519

Morgan, K. (2001, August). Conservative parties and working women in France. Presented atthe Annual Meeting of the APSA, San Francisco.

Naumann, I. (2001, July). The politics of child care: Swedish women’s mobilisation for publicchild care in the 1960s and 1970s. Presented at the ECSR Summer School on Family,Gender and Social Stratification, Stockholm.

Norris, P. (2002). Democratic phoenix. Reinventing political activism. Cambridge, UK:Cambridge University Press.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. (2004a). Employment outlook.Paris: Author.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. (2004b). Social expenditure data-base (SOCX). Paris: Author.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. (2004c). Statistical compendium[CD-ROM]. Paris: Author.

Palier, B. (2002). Gouverner la sécurité sociale. Les réformes du système français de protec-tion sociale depuis 1945 [Governing social security. The reforms of the French social pro-tection system since 1945]. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.

Palme, J. (1990). Pension rights in welfare capitalism. The development of old-age pensionsin 18 OECD countries 1930 to 1985. Stockholm: University of Stockholm, SwedishInstitute for Social Research.

Pierson, P. (1998). Irresistible forces, immovable objects: Post-industrial welfare states con-front permanent austerity. Journal of European Public Policy, 5, 539-560.

Pierson, P. (2004). Politics in time. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Polanyi, K. (1957). The great transformation. Boston: Beacon.Rueda, D., & Pontusson, J. (2000). Wage inequality and varieties of capitalism. World Politics,

52, 350-383.Scharpf, F. W., & Schmidt, V. A. (Eds.). (2000). Welfare and work in the open economy.

Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Scherer, P. (2001). Age of withdrawal from the labour force in OECD countries. Paris:

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.Shonfield, A. (1964). Modern capitalism. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Siegel, N. A. (2000). Jenseits der Expansion? Sozialpolitik in westlichen Demokratien 1975-95

[Beyond expansion? Social policy in western democracies, 1975-1995]. In M. G. Schmidt(Ed.), Wohlfahrtsstaatliche politik. Institutionen, politischer Prozesse und Leistungsprofil(pp. 54-89). Opladen, Germany: Leske und Budrich.

Taylor-Gooby, P. (2004). New risks and social change. In P. Taylor-Gooby (Ed.), New risks,new welfare? (pp. 1-27). Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

Timonen, V. (2004). New risks—Are they still new for the Nordic welfare states? In P. Taylor-Gooby (Ed.), New risks, new welfare (pp. 83-110). Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

van Kersbergen, K. (1995). Social capitalism. A study of Christian democracy and the welfarestate. London: Routledge.

Whiteside, N., & Salais, R. (1998). Comparing welfare states: Social protection and industrialpolitics in Britain and France. Journal of European Social Policy, 8(2), 139-154.

Giuliano Bonoli is a professor of social policy at the Swiss School of Public Administration(IDHEAP), Lausanne, Switzerland. He has researched and published extensively on welfarestate issues, particularly pensions, labor market, and family policies. He is currently working ona project on the adaptation of Western welfare states to emerging new structures of social risk.

520 Comparative Political Studies