Optimal Network for BPD Regional Champion (BRC ... - USAID

65
Optimal Network for BPD Regional Champion (BRC) to Support Financial Inclusion SEADI DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Transcript of Optimal Network for BPD Regional Champion (BRC ... - USAID

Optimal Network for BPD Regional Champion (BRC) to Support Financial Inclusion

SEADI DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Optimal Network for BPD Regional Champion (BRC) to Support Financial Inclusion

July 2013

This publication was produced by DAI/Nathan Group for review by the United States Agency for International Development (USAID). It is made possible by the support of the American people. Its contents are the sole responsibility of the author or authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of USAID or the United States government.

SEADI Discussion Paper No. 5 This paper was written by Research and Training in Economics and Business (P2EB), Faculty of Economics and Business (FEB), Universitas Gadjah Mada (UGM) pursuant to a grant funded by the USAID Support for Economic Analysis Development in Indonesia Project.

Acknowledgements The authors listed below gratefully acknowledge the financial grant provided by SEADI-USAID. We express our gratitude to ASBANDA, who provided tremendous support for us in contacting all BPDs sampled. Constructive feedback and comments from James R. Hambric, Anwar Nasution, and Hery Kameswara are gratefully acknowledged. We thank Risky Raisa Putra, Haryo Saktioko and Pratiwi for excellent assistance during the project. All remaining errors are our responsibility.

Authors

Research and Training in Economics and Business (P2EB) Faculty of Economics and Business (FEB), Universitas Gadjah Mada (UGM) Rimawan Pradiptyo Catur Sugiyanto Sumiyana Inayati Nuraini Dwiputri Yudistira Hendra Permana Stephanus Eri Kusuma Wihana Kirana Jaya Fuad Rahman Andreas Kurniawan

Contents Glossary v

Abstract vii

Executive Summary ix

1. Background 1

2. Methodology 5

3. Banking Policies and Financial Inclusion 7

4. Network Formations of Sampled BPDs 9 Network Formation among BPDs 9

Network Formation in BPDs 11

Pattern of Networks and Transaction Costs 17

5. Interest Rates and Prudential Measures 21

6. Consumptive versus Productive Credits 23

7. Culture and Financial Inclusion 25

8. Local Government Policies 31

9. Other Support for Financial Inclusion 33

10. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations 35

References 37

Appendix A. Literature Review

Appendix B. Interprovince Network of Sampled BPDs

Figures Figure 1. Challenges in Financial Inclusion 2 Figure 2. Financial Network Formation of Bank Kalteng 13 Figure 3. Financial Networking of Bank DKI 15 Figure 4. Financial Network in BPD DIY 16 Figure 5. Financial Network of Bank Sulselbar 17 Figure 6. Relationship between Regional Economic and Financial Inclusion Process 18

Glossary Anakaraeng The past custom of patron-client relationship for Bugis and Makassar people AoRD Agent of Regional Development APEX Bank A bank supervised by another bank ASBANDA Asosiasi Bank Pembangunan Daerah (Association of Regional Bank

Development) Awigawig Custom rules in Bali Bappepam-LK Badan Pengawas Pasar Modal dan Lembaga Keuangan (Capital Market and

Financial Institutions Supervisory Agency); it is under supervisory of the Ministry of Finance

BI Bank Indonesia BKD Badan Kredit Desa (Village-owned Credit Agency) BMT Baitul Maal wat Tamwil; a sharia-based MFI BPD Bank Pembangunan Daerah (Regional Development Bank); classified into

general bank according to Act No. 7/1992 Bank Aceh BPD of Aceh Province Bank Nagari BPD of West Sumatera Province BPD DKI BPD of Jakarta Province BJB BPD of West Java and Banten Province Bank Jateng BPD of Central Java Province BPD DIY BPD of Yogyakarta Province Bank Jatim BPD of East Java Province BPD Bali BPD of Bali Province Bank Kalteng BPD of Central Kalimantan Province Bank Kalsel BPD of South Kalimantan Province Bank Kaltim BPD of East Kalimantan Province Bank Sulselbar BPD of South Sulawesi and West Sulawesi Province Bank Sultra BPD of South-East Sulawesi Province Bank Papua BPD of Papua and West Papua Province Bank plecit Informal moneylender in the traditional market Bendesa adat The head of a customary village in Bali BPR Bank Perkreditan Rakyat (People’s Credit Bank); a rural bank operating at

the same level as a general bank according to Act No. 7/1992 BPRS A sharia-based arm of BPR BPS Badan Pusat Statistik (National Statistic Agency) BRC BPD Regional Champion; program initiated by ASBANDA and BI to

improve role of BPD BUKP Badan Usaha Kredit Pedesaan (Village Credit Enterprise); an MFI

developed during the new order era and owned by local government Inkopdit Induk Koperasi Kredit (Credit Union Central)

V I

IPO Initial public offering JETS Jatim (East Java) Electronic Transfer System Korindo Credit insurance company KUR Kredit usaha rakyat (small loans); a program of Coordinating Ministry of

Economic Affairs KSP Koperasi Simpan Pinjam (Saving-Loan Cooperative) LDKP Lembaga Dana Kredit Pedesaan (Village-owned Credit Fund Enterprise);

another form of MFI that is similar to BUKP LKM Lembaga Keuangan Mikro (Micro Credit Institution) LPD Lembaga Perkreditan Desa (Village-owned Credit Institution); a village-

owned credit organization that is supervised by the local government of Bali LPH Lumbung Pitih Nagari (Local Saving-Loan Agency); a agency similar to

LPD, but from West Sumatera Mindring Credit provider for house appliance purchasing MFI Micro-finance Institution MSME Micro, small, and medium enterprise Nelulasi Common interest rate of Javanese people (about 30% on every maturity date) OJK Otoritas Jasa Keuangan (Financial Service Authority) p.a. per annum p.m. per month Pasaran Weekly days of Javanese people (five days in a week) Patron-client Relationship between lender (bank) and borrowers, in which the lender plays

a role as a supervisor for the customer PBI Peraturan Bank Indonesia (Bank Indonesia’s regulator) Perusda Perusahaan daerah (local-state owned enterprise) PINBUK Pusat Inkubasi Bisnis Usaha Kecil (Center for Micro Enterprise Incubation);

a private organization for micro enterprise development Punggawa-sawi Sharing system in a patron-client relationship for Bugis and Makassar people SOE State-owned Enterprise SME Small and medium enterprise Sparkassen National development bank in Germany

Abstract This study aims to investigate the networking of regional development banks (BPDs) to reach potential customers that are considered non-bankable. A market chain method is used to trace the pattern of networking starting from the BPD down to the final customers. The study involved 13 out of 26 BPDs across Indonesia. In each sampled BPD, interviews were conducted at the head office and two branch offices, one of which was situated in an agricultural area and the other in an industrialized area. Micro-finance institutions (MFIs), which are directly linked with BPDs, were also interviewed and snowballing random sampling has been used to select the sampled MFIs. The results suggest that the network formation between BPDs and MFIs depends on the structure and economic conditions of the area where the BPDs are situated. There is a strong tendency of networking to occur between bank-based MFIs. The cooperation between bank-based MFIs and non-bank-based MFIs tends to be limited since the transaction costs and the risks of establishing such cooperation are substantially high.

Keyword: networking, financial inclusion, microfinance institutions, transaction costs, consumptive credits, productive credits.

JEL Classification: G21, G28.

Executive Summary Financial inclusion is an ingenious way to reach non-bankable households and small and micro scale entrepreneurs (SMSEs) to help them gain access to the formal financial sector. Various studies have found that financial inclusion can aid poverty alleviation. Such programs help low-income households, who predominantly live in rural areas, access capital from the formal financial sector. The challenges of financial inclusion are not only limited to creating new financial institutions, or developing new financial products, which may reach non-bankable households, but also educating targeted groups about the advantages of existing financial institutions and their products. On the other hand, formal financial institutions ought to learn how to serve the targeted groups; particularly where the characteristics of non-bankable households and entrepreneurs may be significantly different from those of bankable customers using developed formal financial institutions.

This study aims to seek the optimum network formation among BPDs and between BPDs and other micro-finance institutions (MFIs). Our research will do the following: a) explore the existing network formations of BPDs, both the internal and external sides, with other small and micro-financial institutions; b) identify the factors that determine the pattern of BPDs with regard to other MFIs; c) estimate the optimum future role of BPDs as either development banks or commercial banks; and d) analyze the existing regulations that may support or need to be revised for the role of BPDs. In order to meet the requirements of a comprehensive study, thirteen out of twenty-six BPDs in Indonesia were involved in in-depth interviews. In addition, networks of BPDs in the financial inclusion process were also interviewed to explore the practices in the field in various places in Indonesia.

This report is organized so that readers may easily understand the implementation of the financial inclusion process of BPDs in Indonesia. Chapter 1 describes the background of this study and our position to explore the implementation of financial inclusion processes by BPDs in Indonesia. Chapter 2 discusses the methodology that was used in this study, including the reason for choosing the BPDs sampled in this study. Chapter 3 explains the role of banking policies and systems in the financial inclusion process, including banking regulations, in Indonesia. Chapters 4, 5, 6, and 7 feature the main analysis of the financial inclusion processes, in which BPDs provide the main point of view, and which includes cultural analysis. Chapters 8 and 9 show the potential role of government and other formal institutions in supporting BPDs and promoting the financial inclusion process. Finally, Chapter 10 offers our conclusions and policy recommendations.

We found that the network formations of BPDs with rural banks and also MFIs depend on the nature of economic conditions in each region. In areas where the structure and performance of the economy tend to be simple, the network formations of financial inclusion of BPDs tend to be short. Surprisingly, the networking of Bank DKI, which is in an economy with the most vibrant and complex structure, tends to be short and simple, similar to those of the areas with economies that have a simple structure. Between two extreme structures of the economy, the networking of BPDs with other financial institutions tends to be extensive and involves various types of financial institutions.

X O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

This creates a relationship between the economic structure and the networking of financial inclusion, which may be depicted as an inverse U-shaped curve.

Indeed, all BPDs are members of ASBANDA (the association of BPDs) and they all have a close relationship with each other. Nevertheless, there is a strong tendency for BPDs to expand their business in other provinces. If each BPD pursues this as its dominant strategy then ASBANDA members will find themselves in direct competition with each other in an attempt to capture market share. Complexities arise because all BPDs tend to embrace similar strategies, and the targeting of similar groups of customers. Thus, the intensification of this expansive strategy by each member of ASBANDA implies that, in the future, competition among ASBANDA members is inevitable.

A network between BPDs and rural banks can be easily established. From the perspective of BPDs, the transaction costs to establish a network of rural banks is much lower than that of establishing a network with other micro-finance institutions (MFIs). This is because the same authority, Bank Indonesia, supervises BPDs and rural banks. On the other hand, linkage programs between BPDs and MFIs are not easily established, yet we found that networking exists between rural banks and MFIs. This occurs because it is difficult for BPDs and rural banks to observe the performance and the credibility of MFIs. The discrepancy in the intensity and the quality of supervision between banking and non-banking institutions is largely due to the complexity of banking and non-banking financial institution networks.

This study found that all sampled BPDs have embraced a similar strategy for channeling their credits to micro-enterprises and low-income households. This channeling has occurred through a cultural approach, where the characteristics of customers or potential customers are the main consideration in making banking decisions. Rural banks and other MFIs have embraced similar strategies. Financial institutions, especially small scale MFIs, in many places in Indonesia are still formed through culturally based approaches. This is reflected in their products, which are easily understandable and accepted by their customers. For example, this cultural emphasis can be seen in the case of mindring in Central Java, LPDs in Bali, and minimizing risk approaches of BPDs and rural banks in West Sumatera.

This study proposes several recommendations to increase BPD’s performance in the financial inclusion process. Firstly, potential rivalry among BPDs may be reduced through good coordination and communication under the umbrella of ASBANDA. Limiting the opening of new branch offices in other provinces, and better cooperation among BPDs in generating funds (supply side), may provide more sustainable strategies than the current race to open branch offices in the other provinces.

Secondly, Bank Indonesia’s supervision of the banking sector has created low transaction costs among the sector’s agents to collaborate and to create networks. In 2014, all financial supervision is going to be conducted by the Financial Service Authority (OJK). OJK faces the challenge of whether it will be able to match the intensity and the quality of supervision across all financial institutions, as the Bank Indonesia has achieved with the banking sector. OJK should endeavor to use its resources to match, or even to improve, the level of supervision across various financial institutions, which may reduce the transaction costs of establishing collaboration across financial institutions.

Third, ideally the measures for BPDs should be distinguished from the measures for commercial banks. BPDs have two main objectives: maximizing profit while operating as corporations, while at the same time acting as agents of regional development (AoRD). These roles may not necessarily converge, and in some circumstances they may be in conflict. The majority of BPDs imposed

E X E C U T I V E S U M M A R Y X I

considerably high net interest margins (NIM) 5%-7%. This may not necessarily be suited to the BRC measure in which the targeted maximum NIM is 5.5%.

1. Background Indonesia is one of the most populated countries in the world after China, India and the USA, with a population of 237.56 million in 2010 (BPS, 2011). The country provides a tremendous potential supply of labor and capital; however, the World Bank (2007) reported that about 60% of Indonesia’s population has no access to the formal financial sector. From this, one may infer that about 60% of the Indonesian population has not been bankable. An un-bankable person includes the impoverished or people from low-income backgrounds. In 2010, about 13.33% of the population lived below the poverty line, and 64.25% of the population lived in rural areas (BPS, 2011). This implies that the source of domestic capital for the formal sector is from the top 40% of income earners in Indonesia, the majority of whom live in urban areas.

Those who do not have access to the formal sector, and/or live in rural areas, may not necessarily have capital. It is common for people in rural areas to have non-monetary capital, even though it is hard for this to be transformed into monetary capital. People in rural areas have suffered from limited access to formal financial institutions.1 Irrespective of whether people live in urban or in rural areas, individuals have a tendency to smooth their consumption over time (Morduch 1995; Kinsey et.al. 1998; Wik 1999; Zeller 2000; Skoufias 2003; Notten & Crombrugghede 2006; and Laczo 2007). Both factors above have encouraged households in rural areas to create informal financial institutions.

Financial inclusion is defined as any method to improve access of economically vulnerable groups to the formal financial system at affordable cost (see Dev 2006, Kamath 2007, Sarma 2010, inter alia). In India, for instance, Dev (2006) reported that there was a strong tendency for farmers to obtain loans more from informal sources than formal ones. The interest rate on credit from informal financial institutions may reach up to 50% or 60% per annum, and moneylenders have exploited many households. Given the fact that the households may bear the credit interest rate of 50% or 60%, a question should be raised as to whether the households are actually financially excluded (Dev 2006).

Zarazua and Copestake (2008) argued that access to financial services depends significantly on educational attainment, employment, and housing status. The main challenge for financial inclusion programs is how to go beyond creating new formal institutions or framing newer rules that call for a renewed thrust of the formal sector in rural areas (Kamath 2007). Formal financial institutions have to learn to serve the poor and vulnerable, which may require focusing on different characteristics than found in the formal banking sector.

The ability of a financial institution to reach non-bankable households or small and micro enterprises depends on the type and the extent of its network with other financial institutions. In cooperative games, the types of networks determine the speed of coordination of all members within the network (Bala and Goyal, 2001). How extensive the network among financial institutions is may determine the

1Case (1995), Dercon (1996), Zeller et al (1997), Robinson (2002), CEPPS and Bank Indonesia (2004), and Roog (2006), among others.

2 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

ability to reach groups targeted for financial inclusion. There are at least three types of network formation: general relations, roundtable formation, and star-formation. The star-formation has the fastest cooperation rate, whereas the general formation has the slowest cooperation rate (Bala and Goyal 2000). Further discussion on the impact of networking on financial inclusion is found in Appendix A.

Figure 1 Challenges in Financial Inclusion

Figure 1 shows the structure of financial inclusion. The focus of the financial inclusion is how to attract non-bankable households and enterprises to formal financial institutions. There are two main challenges in financial inclusion. First, from the supply side, financial institutions need to obtain sources of funding, which may come from enterprises and households. In developing countries, including in Indonesia, it is not necessary for affluent households or small and medium enterprises to use formal financial institutions to save their money. There are various explanations put forward to describe this phenomenon, ranging from cultural and religious factors to educational factors. The complexity of financial products increases for low-income households and micro enterprises.

Second, from the demand side, financial institutions need to channel the funding that they obtain to enterprises and households that need money. The challenges on the demand side are similar to those on the supply side. Attempts to incorporate both poor households and small and micro scale enterprises to have a link to the formal financial sector are the main challenges of financial inclusion.

As part of its financial inclusion strategy, Bank Indonesia and ASBANDA (the association of state-own regional banks or BPDs) recently launched the BPD Regional Champion (BRC) program. The program aims to improve the role of BPDs at the province level, both as a financial intermediary institution and as agents of regional development (AoRD). In addition to this, the program aims to accommodate the advancement of economic activities and remittances in local areas.

Two strategies that have been pursued by BPDs include developing a network of cooperation among BPDs (horizontal integration) and BPDs serving as APEX banks in relation to micro-finance

I N T R O D U C T I O N 3

institutions (MFIs).2 As an APEX Bank, a BPD may work collaboratively with rural banks (BPRs) and serve as a “central bank” when rural banks require liquidity.

Thus far, the role of BPDs as APEX Banks is limited only to BPRs (rural banks) and it has not been extended to MFIs, such as Baitul Maal wat Tamwil or BMT, BKD, KSP, etc. The reason behind this policy is the fact that both BPDs and BPRs have been supervised by Bank Indonesia. Bank Indonesia has provided an online system that enables any commercial or rural bank to check the performance of the other commercial banks and rural banks instantly. This implies that the transaction costs and risks of collaboration between commercial banks and rural banks tend to be minimal, if not negligible.

The transaction costs and risks of establishing working collaboration between BPDs and non-banking institutions, such as multi-financers, venture capital, insurance, cooperatives, BMT, and other MFIs, tend to be higher, since those financial institutions have not been supervised by Bank Indonesia. The supervision of the financial institutions is more complex because there is no direct linkage among financial institution supervisory bodies by Bank Indonesia, The Ministry of Cooperative and Small Scale Enterprises, and Bappepam-LK. By 2015, all financial institutions will ideally be supervised by OJK (Indonesia’s financial service agency). Nevertheless there is no guarantee that the quality of supervision under OJK will be better, due to problems of coordination within the new supervisory system for financial institutions (Pradiptyo, et al, 2012).

This study aims to seek the optimum network formation among BPDs and between BPDs with other small and micro scale financial institutions. The purpose of the study, therefore, is to answer the following questions:

1. What are the existing network formations among BPDs and between BPDs with other small and micro scale financial institutions?

2. What are the factors attributable to the pattern of networking between BPDs with other small and micro finance institutions (MFIs)?

3. In terms of prudential rules and regulations, what is the optimum role of BPDs? Should they become development banks or commercial banks?

4. In order to optimize the role of BPDs, are the existing laws and regulations sufficient to support the new role of BPDs? If not, what kind of additional regulations should be prepared to support the new role of BPDs?

2 The APEX bank will enable BPDs to serve as the leader of a flying geese model, whereby BPDs act as a leader and the other micro financial institutions are followers.

2. Methodology There are two ways to trace the networking of a bank with MFIs for the purpose of financial inclusion. First, attempts may be made to trace the networking of a bank starting from the final customers. The end customers may consist of either households or small and micro enterprises that save and/or borrow money from financial institutions. This method may be compelling, however, it may be quite risky to pursue this since there is no guarantee that the financial institutions are willing to participate in the study.

Second, an attempt may be made to trace the networking of a bank starting from the bank itself followed by tracing its marketing chain up until the networking prior to the households/final consumers. There are several banks that focus on customers in rural areas, namely BRI, BTPN, Bank Danamon, and BPDs. In comparison to the other banks, BPDs are the easiest to involve in the study. This is because BPDs have formed an association called ASBANDA, which enables the research team to gain access to BPDs and MFIs within the network of the BPDs. Indeed, this approach may not be ideal, however considering the complexity of conducting the alternative method; the current approach is considered the most attainable method.

There are twenty-six BPDs around Indonesia, and these are situated in twenty-six out of the country’s thirty-three provinces. The BPDs that have been chosen as samples for this study cover 50% of the total (thirteen BPDs). They have been chosen by considering several factors: how representative they are of each region/island, their institutional status, either as a perusda (locally stated-owned enterprise) or as a limited company, and the uniqueness of the cultural factors that influence financial institutions in their particular region. In terms of regions, it is assumed that Indonesia consists of 7 major regions/islands, Sumatera, Java, Kalimantan, Sulawesi, Papua, Moluccas and Nusa Tenggara, for this study. Bank Nagari (West Sumatera) and Bank Aceh (Aceh) represent BPDs on the island of Sumatera. Bank Kaltim, Bank Kalsel and Bank Kalbar represent Kalimantan. Bank Jatim, Bank Jateng, BPD DIY and Bank DKI represent Java. Bank Sulselbar and Bank Sultra represent Sulawesi. Bank Papua represents Papua. BPD Bali represents Moluccas and Nusa Tenggara. The aim of choosing BPDs across various regions is to investigate the pattern of networking between BPDs, BPRs, and MFIs in each region.

Bank Aceh and Bank Papua were chosen because they represent the most westerly and the most easterly of the regions in Indonesia. Another three BPDs that have not yet changed their status from Perusda are BPD DIY, Bank Kalteng and Bank Sultra, and all of them were chosen to be part of the sample of BPDs. These BPDs were sampled in order to investigate whether the networking of a BPD is subject to its status, since the Perusda BPDs tend to have limited capital compared to the limited company BPDs. Bank Bali and Bank Nagari represent BPDs with a particular culture that supports financial operation of BPDs in their regions. In Bali, almost every village has a Lembaga Perkreditan Desa/LPD, and its operation has taken into consideration the culture in Bali. In a similar vein, Lumbung Pitih Nagari (LPH) in West Sumatera operates using a similar approach.

6 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

Initially, Bank Jabar and Banten (BJB) were chosen to represent BPDs with the most successful IPOs3. Unfortunately, BJB decided not to participate in the study, thus Bank Jateng was chosen to replace it. Bank DKI was chosen because it has been operating in the most vibrant and the biggest city in Indonesia. Bank Jatim was chosen because it is the most advanced APEX bank among the BPDs.

A survey was conducted on the sampled BPDs and their respective financial institutions, including rural banks and MFIs that have been working collaboratively with them. For every BPD, interviews were conducted in the headquarters, branch offices, industrial areas and agricultural areas to identify the heterogeneity of its operations. Snowball random sampling has been used to trace any financial institutions that are part of the BPDs’ network. In each branch office, a representative of small and micro financial institutions was interviewed to trace the networking of the BPD up through the lowest financial institutions before households/final customers. This survey aims to find the existing network formations among BPDs and between BPDs and other small and micro financial institutions.

3 BJB is the first BPD in Indonesia that underwent an IPO, in 2010, and soon its stock was part of LQ 45. Currently the BJB has opened branches in several countries, including in Singapore, Hong Kong and South Africa.

3. Banking Policies and Financial Inclusion The role of banking policy in promoting financial inclusion in the past was mostly focused on the provision of relatively small loans to clients with micro, small, and medium enterprises (MSMEs). It is generally hypothesized that these relatively small loan clients have difficulty accessing financial services from formal financial institutions.

Bank Indonesia has been providing support and assisting the development of MSMEs.4 Bank Indonesia’s policies toward MSME development aim to support the banking sector to reinforce MSME credit disbursement (supply side) and to strengthen MSME eligibility and capability to meet bank requirements (demand side). This policy has been pursued through three instruments: credit policy, institutional development, and technical assistance.5

During the period of 2009 – 2012, Bank Indonesia released two Bank Indonesia Regulations (PBIs) and two circulation letters aimed at promoting support for MSMEs. PBI No. 14/22/PBI/2012 recommended that each commercial bank should distribute a minimum of 20% of its total credit outstanding to MSMEs by 2018. In addition, PBI No. 14/26/PBI/2012 regulated a minimum proportion of total credit outstanding by a bank, which should be channeled through productive credits. For a bank whose main capital is less than IDR1 trillion, at least 55% of its credit outstanding should be channeled through productive loans. The threshold of 60% is applicable for the bank whose main capital is between IDR1 trillion to less than IDR5 trillion. The majority of BPDs lie within these classifications, and this goal will ideally be reached in 2018.

These regulations show a relentless commitment and effort by Bank Indonesia to promote the disbursement of credits to the real sector, especially to MSMEs. On the other hand, this policy may not be appropriate across the board due to heterogeneity within the banking sector in Indonesia. However, the policies provide support to MSMEs, create complexities for some banks, and force banks to embrace a homogeneous strategy to channel their credits.

In order to reach potential customers for financial inclusion, Bank Indonesia has promoted a linkage program. The program enables cooperation between financial institutions. This program has three schemes: a) executing scheme;6 b) channeling scheme;7 and c) joint-financing scheme8. The linkage

4 This role has been mandated in accordance with Act No. 23 of 1999 as amended by Act No. 3 of 2004 and Act No. 6 of 2009.

5Indonesian Banking Booklet, 2010 6 In this scheme, a larger scale financial institution lends money to MFIs, which tend to be smaller. The

smaller financial institution then provides additional loans to its clients.

8 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

programs may be implemented either among banking institutions or between banking and non-banking financial institutions. The program may help commercial banks that have not developed advanced micro credit to reach small and micro scale enterprises and low-income households. Through this program, commercial banks may provide small and micro-scale financial institutions with extra funds for their operations. This program also assists commercial banks, the majority of whom are based in urban areas, to reach potential clients in rural and remote areas through the help of non-banking financial institutions.

The linkage program also aims to promote division in target marketing between BPDs and MFIs. As a commercial bank, a BPD is more capable of handling larger scale clients, while MFIs are more capable of handling smaller scale clients. Thus, it will be more efficient if BPDs distribute relatively small loans through the help of MFIs. In reality, however, this division of labor may not necessarily occur as BPDs and MFIs may compete with each other. In some sampled areas, even rural banks may compete head to head against a BPD. This occurs because the scale of the rural banks may not be significantly different from the BPD. These are some of the complexities in promoting cooperation among financial institutions.

A network among banking institutions is much easier to form compared to a network between banking and non-banking institutions. Prior to initiating a linkage scheme with an MFI, a bank must analyze the performance and reputation of the potential MFI partners. Nevertheless, this may not be easy to perform since the MFIs have been supervised by other authorities, which use a different approach and quality of supervision.9 Indeed, this creates a transaction cost to establish a linkage between banking institutions that is much more economical than that of a linkage between banking and non-banking institutions. It should be noted that rural banks (BPRs) are a small portion of banks compared to the other types of MFIs, such as cooperatives, rural savings and credit institutions (LPDs, BKDs, BUKPs, and other LDKPs), and BMTs, which have more advantages in terms of the proximity to groups targeted for financial inclusion (e.g., non-bankable households, especially rural/remote areas, less educated, and low-income households).

In 2011, Bank Indonesia formulated a new strategy to increase public access to financial services. It is in line with the implementation of the “National Framework of Financial Inclusion.” There are five pillars of inclusive financial policy covered in the framework: a) financial education; b) financial eligibility; c) supporting financial regulation; d) intermediation facilities; and e) distribution.10 In addition, various measures have been implemented by Bank Indonesia to support financial inclusion, including Tabunganku (fee-based income saving), financial education development, implementation of the Financial Identity Number, and the implementation of a literacy survey. Bank Indonesia also developed a payment system that is more efficient, reliable, straightforward, and secure by emphasizing infrastructural development, system development, and the strengthening of the legal framework.

7 In this scheme a financial institution recommends potential clients to an MFI, then the former financial institution distributes their funds to the potential clients and gives some fees to the latter financial institution that recommends the potential clients.

8 In this scheme several financial institutions share their funds and work together in distributing the credits. 9 Bank Indonesia uses three measures to supervise the banking sector; these are micro prudential, macro

prudential and business conduct. Bappepam-LK supervises non-banking financial institutions using business conduct as the primary measure. Lastly, the Ministry for Cooperatives supervises cooperative-based financial institutions by using cooperative principle measures.

10 For the details of the pillars, see Indonesian Banking Booklet, 2010, 2011, 2012

4. Network Formations of Sampled BPDs NETWORK FORMATION AMONG BPDS Theoretically, all BPDs are members of ASBANDA (the association of BPDs). By the end of 2012, Bank BJB (West Java and Banten Province) decided to leave ASBANDA. Today, ASBANDA is comprised of 25 BPDs, and none of them have conducted an IPO (Initial Public Offering). Bank BJB was the first BPD to successfully conduct an IPO. Bank BJB has expanded its operations abroad by opening branch offices in Singapore, Hong Kong, and Johannesburg.

Of the 25 BPDs in ASBANDA, a majority have already transferred their status from perusda (local state-owned enterprise) to “limited company.” Thus far only three BPDs are still under perusda status, Bank Kalteng, Bank Sultra, and BPD DIY. Recently, DPRD-DIY (Regional House of Representative of DIY) has granted approval for BPD DIY to transfer its status to limited company after almost six years of convincing the DPRD DIY.

As a perusda, a BPD may not be able to generate capital easily since any decision regarding capital should be confirmed by all stockholders, which are all municipal governments and the Local House of Representatives (DPRDs). With BPD DIY for instance, they have maintained around IDR 250 billion in capital since 2005. In contrast, all BPDs with limited company status have more flexibility to generate capital because this decision relies on an annual general meeting of shareholders. This explains why the majority of BPDs with limited company status have capital of more than IDR1 trillion.

ASBANDA was founded on March 24th, 1999. The aim of ASBANDA is to drive BPDs to become leading banks in each region through BRC (BPD Regional Champion). The main goal of BRC is to create good corporate governance within all BPDs through three pillars: a) strong institutions; b) the ability to be an agent of regional development; and c) to serve community’s needs.

ASBANDA has made a strong commitment to support financial inclusion. ASBANDA has assisted BPDs to channel KUR (small loans) by working in cooperation with PT Korindo (credit insurance company) and Perum Jamkrindo (Perusahaan Umum Jaminan Kredit Indonesia).11 ASBANDA has played a key role in cooperating with government institutions in channeling the credit programs of BPDs. Through this cooperation, government activities and projects will be funded by BPDs. This strategy aims to help BPDs achieve BRC criteria that require a minimum of 40% of total outstanding credits to be allocated to productive credit by 2014.

11 Perum Jamkrindo is the state-owned enterprise that operates in each province.

10 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

ASBANDA provides a communication forum among BPDs to compare experiences, best practices, and also to discuss any problems that emerge in the banking industry with other associations and with Bank Indonesia. During the process of transformation from perusda to limited company in BPD DIY for instance, they received tremendous support and assistance from the other BPDs. At managerial and official levels, the members of ASBANDA have developed close personal communication among them.

At the business level, it is still not obvious what form of cooperation has been developed among ASBANDA members. Thus far, we found little evidence to suggest that the BPDs have limited liquidity cooperation. Recently, there has been a tendency for several BPDs to extend their operations by expanding their branch offices to other provinces. For example, Bank Jateng and Bank Kalsel have expanded their operations by opening branch-offices in Jakarta. Also, Bank Papua has opened its branch offices in Surabaya, Makassar, and Yogyakarta.

Indeed, for BPDs with excess liquidity, opening a branch office in other provinces is compelling since they can expand their business by getting potential customers there. For example, Bank Papua had benefited from this strategy in which the LDR raised was about 70% in 2012, compared to 40% in 2011, after opening branch-offices outside the province. By early 2013, Bank Papua had opened its branch-office in Yogyakarta, and this is expected to improve the LDR of Bank Papua (Appendix B).

The direction of BPD expansion to the other regions may indicate a financial drain of domestic funds. BPDs in Java are found to absorb more credit than savings and deposits, which are supplied by the outer islands. This means that financial inclusion in terms of channeling credit to domestic customers of their respective BPDs is not comparable to financial inclusion in terms of the savings-deposit funds from the BPDs. We should note that the opening of BPD branches in Jakarta indicates an outflow, where the BPDs channel credits to Jakarta, but not vice versa. Indeed, the reason Bank Papua opened a branch in Yogyakarta was not because there are many Papua people residing in Yogyakarta, but to facilitate credit disbursement in Yogyakarta. A similar reason may apply to Bank Jatim, Bank Jateng, BJB, Bank Bali, and other BPDs for opening branches in Jakarta, since the goal is definitely not for generating funds, but rather for lending. Therefore, a better infrastructure of BPDs tends to channel out funds from surplus areas, regardless of the economy’s structure and performance.

Although becoming members of ASBANDA could benefit BPDs tremendously, the future of this association seems to be in jeopardy because of the tendency of members to enter into direct competition with each other. If the competition to expand the business by opening new branches in other provinces escalates then it is inevitable that fierce competition will occur among BPDs. This competition may jeopardize the existence of ASBANDA in the future.

Will BPDs maintain their roles as agents of regional development in their own regions if they embrace opening branches in the other regions as a dominant strategy? A similar question should be raised about the tendency of BPDs to open branches in other countries once the BPDs have undergone an IPO. It seems there is a conflict between the role of BPD as a commercial bank and as an agent of regional development.

Attempts have been made by BPDs to learn the best practices of Sparkassen, a development bank, which has been operating successfully in Germany. It should be noted, however, that BPDs have fundamentally different business strategies to the Sparkassen. A member of Sparkassen, which is a regional bank similar to a BPD, is not allowed to open branches in other provinces when another Sparkasse has been operating in the region. In contrast, direct competition is permitted among BPDs, and each BPD tends to extend its business to other regions regardless of the existence of BPDs

N E T W O R K F O R M A T I O N S O F B P D S 11

operating there. The majority of BPDs tend to be homogeneous in terms of their size, captive market, and also their potential customers. The homogeneity of BPDs tends to escalate the complexity of direct competition among them, particularly if each BPD thinks that opening branches in the other regions is a route to attraction or a dominant strategy.

NETWORK FORMATION IN BPDS The banking sector operates under a specific type of activity, e.g. bank services. The production process would be under scrutiny if the provision of liquidity to end users (households or businesses) goes through the banking system. Therefore, funds collected from third parties can be redistributed among debtors, who may be overseas, utilizing the centralized banking system.

Under the current network, BPDs are trying to minimize the cost of financial network development and provide liquidity. In addition, there is a further advantage in protecting the networks from financial crisis, which arises from defaults and may also minimize the risk of unbalanced financial reports in the centralized banking system.

In all sampled BPDs, the cooperation between BPDs and BPRs within the APEX Bank has the form of a star network, whereby BPDs serve as the center of the network. This star network is also implemented in non-banking institutions, such as multi-finance, cooperatives, savings-loan cooperatives, BMT, venture capital, and other MFIs. Yet, the star network with non-BPRs was not developed through an APEX Bank system. It should be noted, however, that the likelihood of BPDs forming a network relation with MFIs tends to be lower than that between BPDs and rural banks.

The implementation of the star network was conducted in Aceh. Bank Aceh was forced to embrace a new method of operation in the aftermath of the civil war and tsunami. With the new development of the organization and new market, close control from the center was necessary. With respect to the more mature organizations and the more advanced financial markets, as in Bali, we anticipate the possibility of a more decentralized network being considered.

As an alternative network,12 different from the general network above, we consider a decentralized financial system where each branch is an independent bank, which exchanges liquidity with the other banks. Liquidity may now circulate much more effectively and always be promptly transmitted from agents in surplus (be they banks or depositors) to those in deficit. Moreover, an interbank network for exchanging liquidity represents a safety net for each bank, which may obtain the liquidity it needs from many channels, as well as for the system as a whole, because it warrants that, even in case of default of a single bank, liquidity would still continue to flow to and from every local area of the economy via alternative channels.

In Bali, Lembaga Perkreditan Desa (Village-owned Credit Institution/LPD) is an established financial institution, and each LPD has a close relationship with the other LPD. BPD located nearby LPDs in tourism areas may collect more funds and then transfer the funds to another BPD branch with high credits. It should be noted that not all branches of a BPD have a fully decentralized network because not all of the branches have potential extra funds. Otherwise, the system is very costly because each bank has to gather information about every other bank with which it exchanges liquidity, as well as about each of its partners’ partners (because financial troubles of any of the latter may impact the

12 Giocoli, Nicola, Network Efficiency, the Coase Question and the Banking System (January 13, 2011). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1739611 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1739611, downloaded on Dec 1, 2012.

12 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

bank’s direct partners’ ability to repay debts). Still, under a very strong central BPD and the very strong social and cultural punishment of mismanagement, the costs may be minimized.

BPD Bali may exercise a transition to operate under a decentralized network. In sum,13 should the BPD Bali consider operating under a decentralized network, there are four elements to take into account when evaluating the banking system case: 1) the cost of establishing a communication channel (say, a contract) between two agents; 2) the effectiveness in the transmission of the inputs/information among the agents; 3) the robustness of the entire system, or of parts of it, to the breakdown of an agent or a communication channel; and 4) the cost of providing each agent with the capacity to manage the inputs/information received. Comprehensive networks may improve the interbank deposit market so that the exchange of liquidity is efficient. The better the interbank transfer through the network, the more efficient their allocation of public funds. Therefore, a measure of the efficiency of the network is how far and how fast the funds can be transferred between banks/financial institutions.

The networking between BPDs and MFIs vary from one BPD to another. There are various candidates of factors that are attributable to the variation of the financial network, including the value of capital, the status of BPD either as perusda or as a limited company, and economic conditions in areas where the BPDs have been operating. The results show that the pattern of the network depends on the economic conditions in areas where the BPD has been operating as opposed to the other factors.

Box 1. BPD Bali and Its Linkages Bank BPD Bali is a closed liabilities company owned by the Local Government of Bali, and was established in 1962. By the end of 2011, it had 11 branch-offices, 30 auxiliary-offices, 44 cash payment points, and 79 ATMs. This network enables BPD Bali to reach clients in almost all sub-districts and most villages in Bali province. Through its wide channel of distribution, BPD Bali has been able to maintain their growth performance in the recent years. Their assets grew from 5 trillion to 10.5 trillion rupiahs during 2007–2011, while it revenues rose from 0.4 trillion to 0.7 trillion rupiahs in the same period.

Their third party funds and loans outstanding grew by almost 30 percent (on average) year after year. This has been supported by an increasing trend of operational efficiency and better asset quality performance. Although BPD Bali is a commercial institution, it also acts as a development agent who must contribute to regional economic growth and welfare. In reaching these goals, BPD Bali focuses on the promotion of financial inclusion, especially in serving micro, small, and medium enterprises in Bali province.

To achieve this objective, BPD Bali has developed into an APEX Bank, a group of rural banks and other viable microfinance institutions linked through a program mechanism. In the linkage program, BPD Bali not only gives credit to its linkage partners, but also gives them training and applies close monitoring to track the usage of the linkage funds. It is important to note that the collaboration between BPD Bali and microfinance institutions is still limited to rural banks and cooperatives. For example, BPD Bali wants to collaborate with Lembaga Perkreditan Desa (LPD), a sub-village level community-based microfinance institution. However, it is constrained by government rules, as LPD does not pay taxes. Beside the linkage program, BPD Bali has also adopted other strategies to support

N E T W O R K F O R M A T I O N S O F B P D S 13

their financial inclusion promotion efforts, such as product diversification, competitive interest rate promotion, network expansion, coordination with the government on MSMEs credit funding and guarantee, and human resource and cultural advantage utilization..

The variation of financial networking depends on the economic situation and its structure. In regions with less vibrant economic conditions, the pattern of financial networking tends to be less complicated and less extensive. On the other hand, in regions with a more vibrant economic situation, the pattern of financial networking tends to be complicated and extensive.

Financial networking in Bank Kalteng is considered a simple financial network. In order to reach final customers, Bank Kalteng does not need to have an extensive and complicated networking system. Figure 2 shows the financial network of Bank Kalteng; channeling from the bank to the end customer tends to be short.

Figure 2 Financial Network Formation of Bank Kalteng

Figure 2 shows that the bank may reach end customers from its branch offices and/or auxiliary offices. It should be noted that end customers comprise four groups:

1. Medium and large scale enterprises, 2. Small and micro enterprises, 3. Medium and high income households, and 4. Low-income households.

In the case of Bank Kalteng, the majority of credits are in the form of consumption credit channeled to civil servants, either directly from their branch or through collaboration with civil servant cooperatives. This occurs because the risk of providing credit to civil servants and channeling credit

14 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

through civil servant cooperatives is much lower than providing credit to customers from other occupations.

A similar pattern of networking has been found at Bank Sultra and Bank Papua- the structure and the economic conditions in those areas are similar to those of Bank Kalteng. In comparison with other provinces, the structure and the economic conditions in Papua, West Papua, South East Sulawesi and Central Kalimantan are less vibrant than those of other sampled provinces.

Indeed, there are simultaneous correlations between economic activities of an area and the performance of a bank. The economic activities of an area may be improved by the role of a bank, yet the performance of a bank depends on the economic activities of an area where the bank is situated. The development of BPDs in Papua, West Papua, Central Kalimantan, and Southeast Sulawesi has been hindered by the limited economic growth in these areas. For instance, prior to operation of their branches in Surabaya and Makassar, the LDR of Bank Papua was only 40%. This number has increased to nearly 70% after the operation of their branches in Surabaya and Makassar, since both cities provide more potential customers.

Although Bank Indonesia has promoted the linkage program between commercial banks and MFIs, the program may not be as easy as it seems. The main challenge faced by BPDs in establishing a linkage program with MFIs is the fact that it is quite difficult to access reliable information about the performance of non-banking financial institutions. BPD Sultra is a perfect example of this problem. There are many cooperatives spread across various areas in Southeast Sulawesi province. Nevertheless, BPD Southeast Sulawesi was skeptical about the performance and the prospects of these cooperatives. As a consequence, BPD Sultra was reluctant to give credit to these institutions. The existence of rural banks in this province is very limited. For this reason, it has been difficult for BPD Southeast Sulawesi to build a linkage relationship with other MFIs, at least in the short to medium term.

Bank DKI has a similar financial networking pattern to Bank Papua, Bank Kalteng, and Bank Sultra (see Figure 3). Indeed, the economic structure and performance in DKI Jakarta are the most vibrant and complex in Indonesia, even though Bank DKI has a simple pattern of financial networking. This is due to the fact that there are plenty of medium and large-scale enterprises and also affluent households in Greater Jakarta (Jabodetabek).

Bank DKI has distributed their credit through multifinance, which has flourished in Jabodetabek. When the transaction costs of providing micro scale credit are similar to medium and large-scale credit, any BPD that is operating in a more vibrant economy tends to focus their efforts on providing medium and large-scale credit. This was the case for Bank DKI, which is totally rational. As an intermediary institution, it is rational for Bank DKI to minimize transaction costs and also risks.

N E T W O R K F O R M A T I O N S O F B P D S 15

Figure 3 Financial Networking of Bank DKI

In contrast to the four banks above, the financial network of Bank DIY is much more complex, and involves MFIs channeling credit to small and medium enterprises and low-income households (see Figure 4). BPD DIY reaches their end customers through their branch offices and sharia branch offices. These branch offices have been supported by auxiliary offices, which are situated at Kecamatan (municipal) level.

The conventional branch offices have established cooperation with BPRs (rural banks), KSPs (saving-loan cooperatives), LKMs (micro=credit institutions) and also BMTs (sharia-based rural banks). At the next level, rural banks have cooperated with BUKPs and LKDs (rural credit institutions) before the BUKPs and LKDs reach their end customers. Similarly, mindring (informal commodity credit) may distribute credit that they obtained from LKM to their end customers. The typical mindring entrepreneur obtains capital from LKM, and buys some house appliances to sell to customers. The customers then will pay back the credit on a regular basis, either daily or weekly, to the mindring entrepreneur, who regularly visits the clients’ houses to collect the payment. A similar pattern can be found for the sharia branch offices, which have established cooperation with BMT and other sharia-based micro credit institutions.

16 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

Figure 4 Financial Network in BPD DIY

We observed that the most frequently implemented schemes have been the channeling and the executing programs. In Banda Aceh, cooperatives use the executing scheme, while in Bali, this scheme helps the BPRs increase their loans. In these cases, the amount of credit channeled through these cooperatives and BPR is larger than their capital. Because collaboration between cooperatives tends to be more risky for BPDs, BPDs are usually stricter and more prudent in dealing with cooperatives as opposed to rural banks. So far, though, cooperatives have had excellent repayment rates to both BPDs.

Bank Sulselbar and Bank Kalsel have embraced the third pattern of financial networks, which are more extensive than that of Bank Kalteng or Bank Papua, however they are less complex than those of Bank DIY, Bank Kaltim, and Bank Nagari (see Figure 5). The financial network of Bank Sulselbar is similar to Bank Papua or Bank Kalteng in their conventional branch offices. Nevertheless, the sharia branch offices of Bank Sulselbar has a similar network to that of Bank DIY or Bank Kaltim, whereby they have established collaboration with BMT and also BPRS.

N E T W O R K F O R M A T I O N S O F B P D S 17

Figure 5 Financial Network of Bank Sulselbar

Bank Kalsel shares a similar financial network to that of Bank Sulselbar, however, its conventional bank has a more complex financial network rather than the sharia bank side. Bank Kalsel has established cooperation with multifinances, sharia-based venture capital, cooperatives, and also rural banks in order to channel their credit to end customers.

The financial network of BPDs will depend on their economic performance and structure. As shown in the figures above, the lower performance and simpler structure of the regional economy, the shorter financial network chain of BPDs in financial inclusion process. Nevertheless, there is an extreme point of this phenomenon, since the most complex economic conditions (DKI Jakarta) take Bank DKI to the “simple financial network.” It resembles a “reversed U-shape curve” in its relationship between economic performance and structure and length of financial network of BPDs.

PATTERN OF NETWORKS AND TRANSACTION COSTS From the perspective of BPDs, establishing cooperation with rural banks (BPRs) and sharia rural banks (BPRSs) is simpler than with the other MFIs, such as BMTs, KSPs and LKMs. This is due to the fact that BPDs, BPRs, and BPRSs have been supervised by Bank Indonesia and the banking sector has been highly regulated. It is very easy for BPDs to learn about the performance and the reputation of any BPR and BPRS since all information may be accessed through Bank Indonesia’s website and monitoring reports. Bank Indonesia also provides a health rating for rural banks. This makes the assessment of a rural bank’s performance easier. The rural banks have received sufficient technical or management assistance from Bank Indonesia.

18 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

Figure 6 Relationship between Regional Economic and Financial Inclusion Process

In contrast, establishing cooperation with the other micro credit institutions requires higher transaction costs and risk. In Indonesia, the non-banking financial industry, such as venture capital, multi-finance, insurance, etc. had been monitored and regulated by Bappepam-LK, and since 2013 has been monitored and regulated by OJK (financial service authority). Cooperatives are regulated and supervised by the Ministry for Cooperatives, some portion of credit unions are supervised by Inkopdit, some part of Baitul Maal wat-Tamwil or BMTs are supervised by PINBUK, and Rural Credit and Saving Institutions are supervised by the regional government. In contrast to Bank Indonesia, which has provided information on the rating of all commercial banks, there is no rating system that ranks non-banking MFIs according to their health. In addition, there are also many non-banking MFIs that are not supervised by a legal institution, such as some village-based groups or various informal lenders.

As a central bank and the lender of last resort, Bank Indonesia has used three pillars in conducting banking supervision: micro-prudential, macro-prudential, and business conduct. In contrast, Bappepam-LK used only one pillar (business conduct) to supervise non-banking financial institutions. Kemenkop-UKM, on the other hand, has used cooperative principles to supervise all types of cooperatives, including cooperative-based financial institutions like BMT. Since BPDs are the part of the banking sector that has embraced prudential measures, it is less risky to establish cooperation with BPR and BPRS, which have been supervised by BI, instead of the MFIs.

Sometimes, MFIs implement a customized method in their operation that is considered too risky for a bank to do. For example, some non-banking MFIs do not ask for collateral and do not need a thorough screening analysis for loan clients that have a good track record of repaying the loan in the previous period. These facts make any commercial bank that wants to build a linkage relationship with non-bank MFIs uncertain and cautious about the real performance quality of non-bank MFIs. Thus, in order to ensure the quality of the non-bank MFIs, the bank tends to make a bigger effort and incur higher costs to analyze the performance of non-banking MFIs. In addition, for the banks that do not want the burden of this extra cost, they simply cancel their plan to make a linkage with non-banking

N E T W O R K F O R M A T I O N S O F B P D S 19

MFIs. Unfortunately, the group of MFIs that is avoided by banks is scattered in many areas and probably has a lot of potential to reach the unbankable population.

The implementation of MFI, especially for the non-banking MFIs, must carefully consider the costs borne by both the oversight body and for the MFIs in terms of compliance costs. These tend to be substantial for microfinance (more than the standard banking system) given the number and diversity of activities that compose the sector, the higher degree of decentralization, and the more labor-intensive nature of inspecting MFI portfolios (Christen, et al. in Pouchous, 2012).

Similar patterns of financial networks to BPD DIY are found in Bank Bali, Bank Jateng, Bank Jatim, Bank Nagari (West Sumatera), and Bank Kaltim. The variation of the financial networks among those banks arises from cultural factors. For instance, Bank Bali has established cooperation with LPDs that are situated at the village level. The driving force of the establishment of LPDs in Bali involves cultural factors that are only applicable in Bali.

It is interesting to see the similarities between the financial networks of BPD DIY and Bank Kaltim. In both cases, mindring (informal commodity credits) are part of their financial networks. In Bank Kaltim, bank plecit (informal money lenders) are part of the financial network, however this phenomenon cannot be found in BPD DIY. These similarities are due to the fact that the majority of financial institutions and the end costumers at both Banks are Javanese.

We know from surveys that most BPDs utilize the intermediation facilities and distribution pillar of the financial inclusion framework through the expansion of their own service units, whether they are branch-offices, auxiliary-offices, mobile cash, cash payments, or ATMs. Almost all BPDs surveyed are in a cooperation program with government institutions (in terms of various credit programs). The linkage strategy, especially with rural banks, also becomes one of the main strategies taken by most BPDs to support financial inclusion.

One unique case that needs to be mentioned is the development of the payment system in BPD East Java. Besides their success in becoming the APEX Bank of rural banks, they also have become the first BPD that is successful in building and implementing a real time payment system for their APEX BPR, called JETS (Jatim Electronic Transfer System). The implementation of the system enables more people to access more complete services from financial institutions.

Patterns of networking by BPDs may be different from those of commercial banks. Although commercial banks have similar micro-credit programs, the banks are used to minimizing transaction costs through financial networking. In this case, the risk of financial institutions being related becomes a focus for commercial banks. For this reason, most commercial banks tend not to have longer financial networks, especially in the micro-finance market. Additionally, commercial banks can divert funds for cooperation with MFIs to other areas.

5. Interest Rates and Prudential Measures The effectiveness of Bank Indonesia’s regulation and supervision may be seen in the interest rates that have been set by BPD, BPR, and BPRS. In general BPD and BPR may only take a 2-3% per annum interest rate margin from their credits, which is considered very conservative. Suppose BPD provides credit to BPR with an interest rate of 13%, and then BPR takes a margin of 2% - 3% and charges the end customer an interest rate of 15% - 16%. This happened to both BPD and BPR implementing the prudential measures imposed by Bank Indonesia. In order to obtain credit from BPDs or BPRs, a potential customer has to fulfill 5C principles, the conditions of economy, capacity, capital, collateral, and character. Any potential creditors that may fulfill these prudential measures, lowers the risk to lend money to him/her in comparison to those who cannot fulfill the measures.

The main difference between BPDs and any other financial institutions is in its interest rate system. All sampled BPDs have been implementing the effective rate system instead of a flat interest rate system, which has been used by the other financial institutions.14 The effective rate system allows debtors to have an amortization system during the payment period. It seems to be effective in capturing the customers in the micro-financial market because they consider the effective rate system to be more beneficial than the flat rate system. Also, this could be a strategy for BPDs in the competitive market by creating price competition through reducing the real interest rate.

This feature may not be found in the related MFIs and commercial banks. Although related MFIs may obtain a loan with the interest rate of 13% (effective rate system) from BPDs, they may lend their credit to either members or customers at an interest rate of 20% (flat rate system) or more.15 This occurred when MFIs do not necessarily need to implement comprehensive prudential measures at the same level as BPDs and BPRs. Furthermore, their existing regulatory and supervisory institutions might not impose prudential measures as strictly as Bank Indonesia. Indeed, this may occur from the difference in the nature of business across the financial institutions. For some cooperatives, for instance, they only lend money to active members. Nevertheless, some cooperatives may extend their business by offering credit to potential members, even though the individuals have not yet become active members.

Concerning the issue of the inadequacy of standard supervisory tools, Christen, et al. in Pouchous (2012) argued that traditional inspection and audit instruments are not appropriate for microfinance. This is because some management situations of bank MFIs (or MFI clients) are different from non-

14 The effective rate system is widely used by all BPDs in Indonesia. This system had implemented the amortization system, in which the real interest rate imposed to the customers was about 60% - 70% of the nominal interest rate.

15 The high interest rate imposed by MFIs is naturally accepted by either members or customers. Flexibility and ease of the MFIs is preferable compared to other formal financial institutions.

22 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

banking MFIs. For example, the documentation management of non-bank MFIs tends to be more poorly reported compared to banking MFIs. In addition, the complexity of policy and characteristics of MFIs ask for more specialized techniques and expertise in MFI supervision. Other examples include the recommendation of capital calls, top lending orders, and mergers that cannot be fulfilled by MFIs.16

Box 2. Prudential Measures of Bank Nagari Bank Nagari has been actively building relationships with other financial institutions in order to participate in the financial inclusion process. This includes rural banks, cooperatives, BMTs, and business units. Its relationship with cooperatives, BMTs, and business units has been problematic, since they are not under Bank Indonesia’s system. This is different for rural banks, yet still causes Bank Nagari to be more concerned about those financial institutions.

In this case, Bank Nagari develops a relationship with the related agencies of local government in monitoring cooperatives, BMTs, and business units. The local government’s agencies can supervise them or give a recommendation to access funds from Bank Nagari. Also, Bank Nagari utilizes the cultural approach, providing a fieldwork team to monitor the debtors.

The monitoring of Bank Nagari serves as an indirect assessment of rural banks. Most rural banks do not take risks in channeling funds to either new or un-recommended debtors according to their neighbors. Those approaches are needed by both Bank Nagari and rural banks in order to minimize the risk of micro-finance institutions.

A higher rate of interest, which has been imposed by the MFIs, also occurs due to social norms around borrowing money from private lenders. In Java, for instance, people are accustomed to using the term nelulasi (Javanese, meaning the rule of thirteen). Nelulasi is a common interest rate of Javanese people in which the lender takes about 30% on each maturity date. It should be noted that this rate is based on a flat rate, thus the variable rate may reach about 40%. The period of borrowing depends on private agreement between the borrower and the lender, thus given the rate of interest, the longer the period of borrowing agreed by both parties, the stronger the advantage for the borrower over the other party. The private moneylender, or bank plecit and also mindring, may use this interest rate as a reference.

In the future, all financial institutions will be supervised and regulated by OJK. The scope of OJK will cover all forms of financial institutions (in both the banking and non-banking systems). It will include cooperatives, BMTs, KSPs, and other MFIs as mandated in Act No. 21/2011 and Act No. 1/2013. BPDs, however, will feel the impact of this act, even though they are not under OJK supervision, since their financial networks are capturing those financial institutions’ forms. The challenge for OJK is whether it can match the performance of Bank Indonesia, which successfully managed the interest rate margin between BPDs and BPRs.17

16 For further information, see “A Guide to Regulation and Supervision of Microfinance” (CGAP, 2012) 17 As it is mandated in Act No 21/2011 and Act No. 1/2013, the OJK have not regulated the technical aspects

of running a micro-financial business. To some extent, this needs to be revised in order to strengthen the supervisory role of OJK to the MFIs.

6. Consumptive versus Productive Credits One of the indicators for BPDs is whether they achieve Bank of Regional Champion (BRC) status, which includes all BPDs with at least IDR 1 trillion of core capital by 2014. Furthermore, they are required to provide more productive credit, which has a consumptive credit ratio of 60%:40%. In December 2012, Bank Indonesia issued a decree, No.14/26/PBI/2012, which rules that banks with core capital less than IDR1 trillion have to provide 55% of their credit for the productive sector. In addition, any bank with core capital between IDR1 trillion to IDR5 trillion should lend 60% of total credit to the productive sector. These bank classifications seem to be suitable for the size of BPDs, but the question raised is: are these objectives achievable?

Based on interviews with the BPDs sampled, the ratio of productive credit against consumptive credit is 20%:80%. In relation to the BRC, regulators need to ask whether BPDs manage to fulfill the ratio of 40%:60% for their credit. Indeed, this is a very steep objective that may not be fulfilled, although we cannot say it is impossible.

There are several factors that are attributable to the complexity of BPDs in achieving some of the performance of BRC indicators. First, in all sampled BPD, the civil servants’ salary in the respective region was paid through BPDs. Second, civil servants are the most contestable customers since the risk to lend money to them is near zero. In Indonesia, civil servants have only a slim probability of losing their jobs, and, moreover, they are subjects of insurance and pension schemes. Consequently, for any BPD, giving consumptive credit to civil servants is a dominant strategy since the risk is low, the transaction costs are low, and the loans are safe because BPD distributes civil servants’ salary every month.

From the perspective of BPD, it is easier and safer to give consumptive credits to civil servants compared to providing productive credit to the other members of society. Although the interest rate of the consumptive credit is about 2% – 3% lower than the productive credits, providing consumptive credit to civil servants is more compelling to BPDs, since the risk and the transaction costs of the credit are low.

The average amount of the consumptive credit given to civil servants is about IDR100 million to IDR200 million.18 After BPD has approved a civil servant’s loan, the civil servant may allocate the money for consumptive purposes or for productive purposes. The problem is, up until now, even the BPDs themselves do not know what portion of the application for consumptive credit sought by civil servants has been allocated for productive activities. This unobserved heterogeneity can be estimated, which puts the expected proportion of productive to consumptive credit in excess of 20%:80%.

18 This micro-credit type is also provided for micro-scale enterprises to some extent.

24 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

All BPDs under ASBANDA must also satisfy the PBI No. 14/26/PBI/2012 in the same way as commercial banks.19 Yet, there is lenience for BPDs to satisfy the requirements of PBI No. 14/26/2012 by the end of 2017, while commercial banks are required to satisfy it by the end of 2015. The main problem for BPDs is the potential conflict of interest between BRC and the PBI on channeling funds to either the productive or consumptive sector. It is widely known that BRC requires a higher portion of productive credits than for PBI (60%:55%).

19 PBI No. 14/26/PBI/2012 will later regulate business plans and activities for all of the bank’s forms according to the core capital.

7. Culture and Financial Inclusion The availability of local and traditional financial institutions influences the development of BPDs. A BPD’s approach to both local culture and people could strengthen financial networks. Yet, the idea of financial inclusion may be defined differently between regions. For example, Bali shows that BPDs can have made a longer financial network, as long as MFIs are bounded with norms. BPD DIY, for example, shows that they are allocating funds for local culture and people in order to achieve customer loyalty. In this section, we introduce the role of related financial BPD businesses that have benefited from and taken a cultural approach.

Bank Plecit are private moneylenders that give loans to people at high interest rates (up to 20% - 50% per month). Such businesses are doing well because of friendships and because bank plecit are usually located far from formal financial institutions. Location is a key reason poor people choose bank plecit to borrow money, even though they impose very high interest rates.

Box 3. The Features of Bank Plecit (private money lender) Bank Plecit mostly operate in Java Island, and serves the customers twenty-four hours a day. Theoretically, customers should not prefer it because Bank Plecit charges a higher interest rate than any other financial institution. Nevertheless, most customers, especially in the traditional market, are accustomed to its service because no significant requirements are needed by Bank Plecit. It seems to be the main competitor for not only for micro-financial institutions, but also for commercial banks.

In some sense, the operation of bank plecit increases the number of poor people with access to financial resources. Indeed, bank plecit mirrors the micro-finance market, as its funds help smooth poor people’s consumption or income. As mentioned by BPD branch managers in Bantul and Kulonprogo, they have to compete against the bank plecit in the effort to include small-scale firms or households. Poor people generally prefer the convenience and easy access to financial sources, rather than preferential interest rates. Informality and ease could be the key for BPDs to attract the poor.

Beside bank plecit, there are mindring,20 a traditional commodity-based lending system. Mindring are conducted by selling goods (usually house appliances), with the clients paying credit on a regular basis, usually every pasaran (every five days according to Javanese lunar calendar) or weekly. The minding business provides commodities, instead of funds, to his/her customers or members whom the

20Mindring is a goods selling business conducted by an individual with other individuals using a credit system. The credit payment is conducted daily or weekly, depending on agreement between creditors and customers. Goods sold and credited include household appliances, electronic equipment, and clothes. The creditor (mindring provider) takes a profit rate between 50% up to100% in two months. So, the interest rate of mindring was about 25% up to 50% per month.

26 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

entrepreneur knows well. Knowing the members/customers is paramount in this business since the system requires trust and kinship from both creditors and debtors, and because there are no provisions to the loans. The mindring providers usually visit the debtors daily to collect payments, and perform monitoring and evaluating debtor’s loan performance.

Box 5. The Features of Lembaga Perkreditan Desa (Village-owned Credit Institution or LPD) Lembaga Perkreditan Desa (LPD) started in Bali around the early 1990s. Almost all villages in Bali established LPD for self-help purposes. LPD are supervised by BPD Bali. The credit is only meant for the local indigenous villages, and generally without collateral. One thing that distinguishes LPD from cooperatives is the scope of the operational area, and lower interest rates compared to the cooperative (about 2.25% to 3%). The operational area of LPD is limited to the area of traditional villages. Because of low interest rates, LPD apply strict sanctions for those who are delinquent on their debt. If there are customers who cannot repay loans for unacceptable reasons, there will be a warning and LPD provides guidance to the customer. If this does not work, the customary council will intervene by imposing sanctions based on awigawig (customary rules) to the customer, with the most severe sanction being exclusion. This supports the repayment of loans to LPD. In the loan transaction process, applicants must get management approval and customary bendesa before receiving a loan. However, to make things easier, management or staff will help the loan applicant (customer) communicate the bendesa customs. LPD can support the success of financial inclusion through the customary rules that can decrease the NPLs of LPDs.

The rapid development of LPDs indicates that the system is growing stronger at the local level. It provides an alternative for communities accessing capital compared to informal financial institutions that charge high interest rates. This means that the efforts of financial inclusion may be achieved by using traditional rules still firmly accepted by the public. Based on the internal data of BPD Bali, as August 2012, there were 1418 units of LPDs located in 1,468-desa adat (traditional village) in nine districts in Bali. The accumulated assets of all BPDs were RP7.5 trillion. The LPDs are able to mobilize savings deposits amounting to IDR3.14 trillion from 1.4 million clients, and time deposits amounted to IDR3.07 trillion from 112.68 thousand clients. They can also distribute loans amounting to IDR5.6 trillion to 423.85 thousand clients. These data give show the wide reach of LPDs, and their ability to help financially excluded people in Bali.

Based on mindring provider experiences, customers with a fairly good understanding of religion do not have problems with credit payments. All costumers enjoy this system, even when they know how much profit mindring providers generate. Since both of them are happy, mindring should be able to continue in the future.

The mindring providers obtain funds from rural banks, MFIs, and/or cooperatives. MFIs/cooperatives may still want to give loans even when they know that the funds will be utilized for mindring business. Nevertheless, this may not be applicable to banks, which tend not to provide credit to mindring providers since the business is considered quite risky. There is no guarantee that the customers of mindring providers will be able to repay their loans.

C U L T U R E A N D F I N A N C I A L I N C L U S I O N 27

Box 4. The Features of Mindring Mindring businesses are a unique part of the micro-finance process. They provide goods from traditional merchants through a credit system. The goods provided in mindring business are usually household appliances, electronic equipment, clothes, etc. They use a daily, weekly, or traditional market day payment system, depending on the agreement that has been made. This business potentially operates with a profit rate up to 50% - 100%, measured by nominal values, not percentage values. Nevertheless, many customers need this type of credit, and mindring provides flexibility on requirements.

The strengths of mindring are: a) popular among people; b) run through trust and social controls; c) provides goods directly; d) less vulnerable to disaster or crisis; e) relatively small loans; f) no advertisement cost; and g) high profit. Yet, the weakness are: a) high transportation costs; b) no penalty for the customers for violating the agreement; c) vulnerability from lack of collateral requirement; and d) it relies on the social conditions of a communities.

Bank Plecit and mindring help the poor and vulnerable to get loans with the easy requirements. Actually, mindring is one of the systems that can help society get credit and improve their welfare. This is because vulnerable groups cannot afford the price of some goods using cash payments. They need the mindring system to get goods, and are able to fulfill their needs with credit. But, the high interest rate is a major negative aspect of mindring. Mindring providers argue high rates are required because the mindring business involves high risks and is costly (time consuming)21. This phenomenon supports the argument of Dercon (1996), Zeller et.al (1997), Robinson (2001) that in reality, a high proportion of the poor in the world have limited access to financial institutions (insurance or credit) in smoothing their consumption.

In contrast to banks, rural banks and MFIs, mindring and bank plecits operate in an informal manner. Formal financial institutions require customers to have a savings account at their institution. Neither mindring nor bank plecits have this requirement, thus, in a formal sense, their operations may not necessarily improve financial inclusion.

Mindring are found in Yogyakarta, Central Java, East Java, and also East Kalimantan. Mindring providers usually originate from Kuningan, West Java. They live together, renting a house, and start their operations in the morning to sell home appliances, such as mats, teapots, plates, and even electronic appliances. Many of them still ride bicycles, but mostly they go by motorcycle. Selling by credit is their main service. For poor people, buying goods using credit is the best way of saving (accumulating wealth). Thus, if financial inclusion is meant to help the poor accumulate wealth and to manage their expenditures, it has to compete with the mindring. Since access to cities and local stores is difficult for poor people, and credit is not available to them, the mindring system serves as an alternative.

Another traditional financial system in society is LPD, Lembaga Perkreditan Desa (in Bali). One thing that distinguishes LPDs from cooperatives is the scope of their operational area, and the interest rates of their loan are lower than cooperatives (2.25% to 3%). LPDs’ operation area is limited to the

21The mindring provider should collect money for repayment regularly (daily or weekly)

28 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

traditional villages. If there are customers who cannot repay loans for unacceptable reasons, the LPD will warn the customer and provide guidance. If this does not work, a traditional council will intervene by applying sanctions based on awigawig (customary rules) to the customers. The most severe sanction is exclusion. This supports loan repayment by customers of LPD. In the process of loan transactions, the applicants must get bendesa adat and management approval before receiving a loan. However, to facilitate the process, management or staff will help the loan applicant (customer) communicate with the bendesa adat regarding the loan application. LPDs can support the success of financial inclusion through the customary rules that can decrease NPLs.

Another challenge faced by BPDs is their perception within the society, especially in rural areas and those with low educational backgrounds. In some areas, people think that credit from BPDs is a grant from the government, thus once they obtain the credit, and they do not need to repay it. This attitude causes the NPLs of some BPDs in micro-credit to be considerably high. In fact, the majority of people in the sampled BPDs do not have this attitude, however in some areas of Aceh and in Papua this attitude is still prevalent.

Box 6. The Role of Culture in Interest Rate Determination in Bali Based on the observation of the BPD Bali credit channel, we found that that BPD Bali lends money to BPRs, cooperatives, and LPDs. The interest rate charged by BPD for the loan distributed to the customers is about 11% p.a., yet the NIM could be 7.79% in 2011 (with the saving and deposit taking an interest rate for about 4% - 5%). In the operation of BPD linkage partners, the loan is distributed to the end users with various interest rates. According to the survey, rural banks charge an interest rate of 1.8% – 2.2% p.m. (or 21.6% –25.2% p.a.), the cooperatives charge about 1.65% – 3% p.m. (or 19.8% – 36% p.a.), and LPD charges an interest rate of 1.4% - 2.2% (16.8% – 26.4% p.a.). This means that there are about 10% – 20% of NIM between the credit interest rate of BPD Bali and their linkage partners. Cooperatives are found to take higher NIM in comparison with rural banks and LPDs.

Bank Jatim has made the education of BPD clients its first priority in establishing a sustainable link to customers. In this case, the staff of Bank Jatim has been actively involved in disseminating the bank’s products to community groups and engaging with them. Various discussions, workshops, and trainings have been conducted to improve the skills of clients for managing their businesses wisely and strategically.

Based on interviews, we found that the volume of credit disbursement is the last priority of Bank Jatim. The most important thing for the BPD is how to make the customers loyal and educated. Some practices of BPDs show that the concern of other BPDs to educate their customers were not as intensive as at Bank Jatim. For example, in Southeast Sulawesi and East Kalimantan, the advisory from BPD to their clients was limited. The main problems are that the location of the customers is very diverse, and resources are not sufficient to handle customer education. In addition, BPD in each region actually has an advantage (for approaching people) to educate their customers because most BPD staff are local people that belong to the local culture.

There are some habits and cultural factors that have had an adverse impact on the financial inclusion process. Some people may be reluctant to go to the bank because they are are ashamed of being considered “debtors” by their neighbors. Also, some people do not want to go to banks because of

C U L T U R E A N D F I N A N C I A L I N C L U S I O N 29

transportation difficulties.22 Applying for credit is also considered cumbersome since it requires red tape and signatures, which the bank needs for administrative and prudential purposes.

Considering all the factors above, some people may be inclined to apply for credit from MFIs, mindring, and even bank plecit instead of from formal banks and rural banks. The majority of MFIs, mindrings, and bank plecits offer higher interest rates, however, their approach to potential customers is less formal because they know the local culture.

Traders in traditional markets in Java tend to be reluctant to visit banks because they are aware of the opportunity costs. They consider visiting a bank a costly activity since they may have to get close to the customers rather than going to banks. Bank plecits, or private moneylenders, are well aware of this issue, and they actively approach traders on a daily basis. Nowadays, a similar strategy has been embraced by commercial banks, such as Danamon Bank, BRI, BTPN, and also BPD.

Informal financial institutions were also found in the form of patron-client relationships in some sampled areas. The patron-client relationship can lead to economic benefits for both parties. As customer dependence on the patron intensifies, the patron may benefit politically because the customers are possible voters. In the economic context, the patron-client relationship can be described through the relationship between a bank (lender) and its customers (borrowers). The customers while borrowing money from the patron can initiate this relationship. For the specifics of the patron-client relationship in South East Asia, Scott (1972) listed five social conditions to support the development of patron-client relationships, namely social stratification, power stratification, wealth stratification, social insecurity, and kinship and kinship unit. These factors will trigger the relationship between the clients and the patron.

Bugis and Makassar ethnic groups have enjoyed a long history of practicing patron-client relationships. The earliest written report is by Kooreman (1883), which describes the patron-client as an anakaraeng relationship, where the ana (client) obtains a personal guarantee from a noble woman saying that they are free from haughtiness and cruelty. As a consequence, it was compulsory for ana to follow orders from the noble woman. Such a relationship is much like the surrender described by Mattulada (no reference year) and Mallinckrodt (ARB, 1933). Peltras (1981) and Ahimsa-Putra (2007) reported that such patronage is still observed in the current era.

22 Several problems arise, such as wearing formal clothes, the procedures, and other inflexibilities.

30 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

Box 7. A Cultural Role in Financial Inclusion; the Case of Makassar Patron-Client, Case: Cambayya small fishermen in the coastal city of Makassar. In this area, most of the fishermen have traditionally been involved in a patron-client system (known as punggawa-sawi). There is an agreement that sawi must provide all of the catch to the punggawa, and that the money from the sale of the catch will be divided between patron and client. This is collateral for a loan that has been given to the client’s patron. In addition, patrons also provide loans to fishermen who are not clients. Typically, patrons determine the price of fish before clients go to sea. If fishermen agree to the terms, which may include interest charges, the total catch must be sold to the patron. A loan payment is calculated and the rest of the fish goes to the fishermen.

As the patron-client relationship grows, then reputation and trust are formed. The borrowing relationship develops into a social relationship. The client can soon easily get a loan or assistance at any time without giving collateral. In addition, the patron may provide other social services to the client, for example assistance for a client’s marriage, or other purposes. Patrons can act as a medium for the client to perform income smoothing. The role of the punggawa is seen through their extensive network, which shows their current importance in the fish market. Their ability to set the price of fish and determine the interest charged, combined with sawi’s inability to provide collateral for their loans, allows the patron-client to survive and restricts sawi’s access to formal financial institutions. Cooperative Fishermen (koperasi nelayan) have been introduced to help clients, but patrons dominate the fish market, so the sawi’s income remains in their hands.

With reference to the case of patron-client relationship in Sulawesi (Bugis–Makassar), Ahimsa-Putra (2007) underlined the role of the social system amongst the Bugis and Makassar, which supports the existence of patronage. In these societies, mutual help among people is maintained through blood relationships.23 Ahimsa-Putra (2007) argued that in order to develop a patron-client relationship, there must be an additional “transaction” between the patron and the client, namely the patron asks for help from the client (e.g. taking care of the house while the patron is on leave, cleaning the field, harvesting coconuts). Without such further “dependency” by the patron on the client in the mentioned activities, the relationship (patronage) with the client will not continue. When such relationships develop, the client will depend on the patron in many dimensions that are related to financial needs (expenditure), such as when a family member gets sick, new school year expenses etc. The clients treat the patron as their bank (or insurance company).

23 The Bugis and Makassar people believe that they have to help each other, regardless of the blood relationship. Conversely, their social status decreases from asking from help from outside of blood relationships.

8. Local Government Policies Local Governments enact some policies to support financial inclusion for local people. Generally, the local government has cooperation and/or ownership share in BPD.24 There were some credit products of BPD where the funds came from the Local Government to help MFIs in the area/district. A specific amount of funds are embedded in a specific program for the development of MSMEs.25 The most common financial institution that receives funding from a BPD in term of loans is the cooperative. The Local Government of East Kalimantan, particularly in Kutai Kertanegara District, has been actively promoting the role of cooperatives. The District covers a vast area and there are many cooperatives spread across it. It is easy and economical for any cooperative to reach customers, however, this may not be the case for Bank Kaltim in reaching customers in the District. In order to reduce the transaction costs, Bank Kaltim works collaboratively with many cooperatives in order to reach customers in remote areas.

Another effort by local governments to support financial inclusion is by creating credit guarantee schemes within BPDs to reduce the risk of lending to micro enterprises. The local governments of East Java, Papua, and Aceh have embraced this policy. The BPDs may reduce the current account of the local government, in the case of whether the credit in this scheme defaults or not. In East Java, the program has been run successfully to reduce the NPL of Bank Jatim, which was 0.97% (2011). A similar feature can be found in Aceh, where Bank Aceh’s NPL was 3.95% (in the first quarter of 2012). Those achievements may not be shared in Papua, where thus far the credit guarantee in Bank Papua has decreased by 50% due to the high rate of defaults in this credit scheme.

Support from the local government for the BPDs has only helped the BPDs because they are local state-owned enterprises (perusahaan daerah). This support can generate benefits for regional development (in both profits and poverty alleviation). Many BPD programs are far different from any program or regulation in other financial institutions. In addition, those other financial institutions need to cooperate with BPDs to access local government programs in the financial activities context.

24 For the limited company status of BPDs, local government used to own a share of the BPD. For example, Bank Papua, Bank DKI, and BPD DIY.

25 The local government of East Kalimantan works in cooperation with Bank Kaltim to distribute their funds among target groups on such programs. In this scheme, Bank Kaltim serves as a channeling agent for the local government.

32 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

Box 8. Credit Guarantee to MSME in East Java In 2010, the local government of East Java established a provincial state-owned enterprise called PT. Penjaminan Kredit Daerah Jawa Timur, or PT. Jamkrida Jatim. Te establishment of this institution was motivated by the fact that MSMEs faced difficulties in accessing funds to support their business due to lack of collateral. PT Jamkrida Jatim serves a credit guarantee for MSMEs and cooperatives. This institution is responsible for defaults made by Bank Jatim’s customers.

The scheme provided by PT. Jamkrida Jatim has three advantages. First, it is easier for prospective but un-bankable MSMEs to access credit from banking institutions. Second, banking institutions become less cautious in giving credit to MSMEs, which supports credit expansion. Third, PT. Jamkrida can be a source for local government revenues and its business has the potential to support capital provision for business activities in East Java, which is dominated by MSMEs.

To prevent the moral hazard of clients, PT. Jamkrida Jatim implements a blacklist scheme for debtors who intentionally default. The blacklist record will be spread through the Bank Indonesia system and widely distributed to all branch-offices By the end of 2011, PT. Jamkrida Jatim realized a credit guarantee of up to RP315.84 billion, an increase from RP93.29 billion in 2010 (Bisnis Indonesia, 2012). This is quite a lot higher compared to the initial capital given by the BPD, which was up to RP50 billion. This means that PT. Jamkrida is well managed in their operations and the existence of this institution has been utilized effectively by MSMEs in East Java.

9. Other Support for Financial Inclusion In addition to the support from government, at both central and local level, private institutions provide support to BPDs for financial inclusion. The following is a list of types of support from non-government institutions to BPDs for financial inclusion:

PT Askrindo (Asuransi Kredit Indonesia) PT Askrindo is a state owned enterprise (SOE) in Indonesia, and was founded in April 6th, 1971. It plays a role as a collateral substitution institution for SMEs (Small and Medium Enterprises) to access credit from financial institutions. Several products have been introduced by PT Askrindo to give guaranteed service for six cooperating institutions (BRI, BNI, Bank Mandiri, BSM, Bank Bukopin, and BPD).

PT Askrindo has been working collaboratively with BPDs to provide insurance for KUR, with maximum loans of RP500 million. It helps BPDs maintain their performance (by NPL indicator) in channeling credit, especially for non-bankable agents and micro enterprises. Thirteen BPDs have been cooperating with PT Askrindo to guarantee KUR, and other BPDs are expected to follow suit in the near future.

Perum Jamkrindo (Jaminan Kredit Indonesia) Similar to PT Askrindo, Perum Jamkrindo provides insurance for financial institutions. It was founded in 1970 to be a collateral institution for cooperatives. Since 2008, Perum Jamkrindo has focused on providing guaranteed service to support the development of SMEs and cooperatives. It will take over credit risks of SMEs and cooperatives during repayment periods. Perum Jamkrindo has established cooperation with all 26 BPDs in Indonesia, including BJB Sharia, Bank Kalbar Sharia, Bank Kaltim Sharia, Bank Sumsel Sharia, Bank Riau Sharia, Bank Jatim Sharia, BPD DIY Sharia, and Bank Sulsel Sharia. It is only KUR and KUR sharia-based that Perum Jamkrindo guarantees in their cooperation with BPDs.

PT Jamkrida (Jaminan Kredit Daerah) PT Jamkrida is a regional-based collateral institution that performs similar services to Perum Jamkrindo. Currently, there are two provinces that provide this guarantee service, East Java and Bali. In addition, West Java, South Sumatera, and East Kalimantan will start to operate in 2013. PT Jamkrida in each province has cooperation with the BPD to cover SMEs and cooperatives through KUR, however it has not entered the sharia market yet.

PT Askrida (Asuransi Bangun Krida) PT Askrida is another SOE and was founded on December 2nd, 1989. It was under BPD’s authority until 1996. The main stakeholders of PT Askrida are BPDs and local governments. PT Askrida

34 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

provides insurance for both consumptive and productive assets. The relationship of PT Askrida to BPD aims to cover both consumptive and productive credit programs.

Perbarindo (Perhimpunan Bank Perkreditan Rakyat Indonesia) Perbarindo was officially founded on January 24th, 1995 after the transformation of a previous association of rural banks, or BPR. Perbarindo aims to encourage the growth of BPR in financial markets, i.e. both conventional and sharia financial markets. In order to achieve this target, Perbarindo has worked closely with Bank Indonesia and LPS (Lembaga Penjamin Simpanan). Perbarindo accesses BPR to cooperate with potential parties to raise their coverage in financial markets.

The relationship between Perbarindo and BPDs in financial inclusion is interesting. BPDs serve as APEX banks to BPRs through a linkage program. By the end of 2012, there were six BPDs that had become APEX banks to BPRs. All six BPDs were BPD Riau, Bank Nagari, BPD Kalsel, Bank Jatim, BPD Jateng, and BPD Kaltim. Interest rates on credit are expected to be reduced through this linkage program and the widening of coverage for both BPDs and BPRs in channeling credit.

10. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations CONCLUSIONS The network formation between BPDs and MFIs depends on the structure and economic condition of the areas where the BPDs are situated. The complexity of a network depends on neither the status nor the size of the capital of BPDs. This finding shows that, as long as the BPDs only operate in their respective province, the scope to improve the networks is minimal.

There is a strong tendency for BPDs to establish collaboration easily with rural banks (BPRs). This occurs when the same authority, namely, Bank Indonesia, has supervised them. This tendency may not necessarily be found in the cooperation between BPDs and the other MFIs. The fact that the other MFIs were not supervised by Bank Indonesia, and the diversity of measures used by Bank Indonesia and Bappepam-LK (OJK) and the Ministry of KUKM (Cooperatives and SMEs) to supervise financial institutions has created formidable obstacles for such cooperation.

It is not easy for BPDs to reach potential customers, especially in remote areas and outside the island of Java. A linkage program between commercial banks, including BPDs and MFIs, has been promoted; nonetheless the program is mostly concentrated among bank-based MFIs. The linkage program between BPDs and BPRs with other MFIs has been limited. This has occurred due to separation between banking and non-banking sectors in terms of supervision, and each authority has used different measures in regulating and supervising MFIs in their jurisdiction.

In channeling credits to micro enterprises and low-income households, BPDs and other MFIs tend to use a less formal approach by capitalizing the cultural factors that flourish in their area. BPDs tend to embrace strategies that have been used by bank plecits, or private moneylenders, to actively approach customers and potential customers. This strategy may not be implemented with medium and large enterprises, however for micro enterprises this strategy is very suitable.

According to the survey, it was acknowledged that BPDs have financial inclusion strategies from the demand and supply sides; however, the achievement from the supply side has not increased significantly. It may not be surprising, therefore, that in 2011 the percentage of the population aged 15+ with an account at a formal financial institution was about 20%. Thus, it is imperative for BPDs to improve and to focus on strategies for collecting funds from the savers and depositors. Through the program ‘Tabunganku’, BPDs capture savings from school children. Nevertheless, this strategy may not be sufficient in covering financial inclusion from the supply side. Alternative strategies are required in capturing deposits and savings. Moreover, the infrastructure of the financial system, such as branch offices and ATM networks, are far from adequate in Indonesia, in particular for BPDs.

36 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

The other complexity arises due to the fact that the information system in Indonesia is considerably weak. Thus far, there is no single identity system for population registration in Indonesia. As a consequence, information on the ownership of capital across the population is not easily observed.

Our study found that the network formation among BPDs in Indonesia today tends to encourage competition among BPDs. Opening branch offices in other provinces seems to be a dominant strategy embraced by many BPDs to expand their business. As the target clients of BPDs come from similar groups, this strategy may increase rivalry among BPDs. This strategy threatens the sustainability of many BPDs, especially those with small client bases in the medium or long term.

Opening branches in other provinces may accelerate the process of financial inclusion. In accordance with the basic indicators of financial access and usage in the IMF’s Financial Access Survey, such as “commercial bank branches per 1,000 km2,” “commercial bank branches per 100,000 adults,” “outstanding deposits with commercial banks (% of GDP),” and “deposit accounts with commercial banks per 1,000 adults,” the opening of branches in other provinces may improve financial access and usage.

RECOMMENDATIONS There are four recommendations that we propose from this study. First, in order to reduce potential rivalry among BPDs due to mutual expansion of businesses in other provinces, coordination in business among BPDs, credit syndications, and also mergers among BPDs should be encouraged. This strategy covers two important areas. First, the limitations to establishing new branches outside the province where that BPD is located are important. This policy aims to avoid a fierce rivalry among BPDs that operate in the same areas and target the same potential customers. Secondly, the cooperation among BPDs should be intensified in generating funds (supply side), credit syndication, and also potential mergers among BPDs. These strategies aim to reduce transaction costs in each BPD. A BPD that has excess liquidity or lack of liquidity may not necessarily try to open its business in other provinces. Instead they may cooperate with other BPDs that require liquidity with the same terms and conditions, which benefits both parties. This strategy has been implemented successfully by Sparkassen, a networking of regional development banks in Germany.

Second, in 2014 all banking and non-banking sectors will be supervised by OJK. Furthermore, according to the mandate of microfinance Act No. 1/2013, all MFIs will be supervised by OJK. This provides a golden opportunity for OJK to improve the quality and the coverage of supervision, both for banking and non-banking financial sectors. This may be achieved by developing a homogenous standard of reporting and supervising across various types of financial institutions.

Third, the lack of financial sector knowledge in society requires a strategic plan to educate people about financial sectors, especially those in rural areas and those who come from low educational backgrounds. Financial broadening and financial deepening may only be achieved through educating people. In cases where people have a good understanding of financial inclusion and welfare, the need to obtain a loan from informal financial institutions that impose high interest rates may decrease substantially.

Lastly, in addition, to acting as commercial banks, BPDs also serve as agents of regional development (AoRD). These roles may not necessarily support one from another and in some extent they may contradict. The BRC program emphasizes promoting the role BPD to be the AoRD. Nevertheless, the measures of AoRD may not necessarily correspond to the measures for BRC. We recommend that the measures for BPDs be designed separately from the measures for commercial banks.

References Ahimsa-Putra, Heddy Sri. (2007). “Paradigma, Epistemologi, dan MetodeIlmuSosial –

Budaya”.Yogyakarta: Universitas Gadjah Mada.

Allen, F. and D. Gale. (2000). “Financial Contagion”. The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 108, Issue 1, pp. 1-33.

Bala, Venkatesh and Sanjeev Goyal. (2000). “A Noncooperative Model of Network Formation”.Econometrica 68(5): 1181-1229.

BPS, 2007. “Statistical Yearbook of Indonesia 2011: Published Series”. Badan PusatStatistik (BPS): Jakarta, Indonesia.

Case, Anne. (1995). “Symposium on Consumption Smoothing in Developing Countries”. Journal of Economic Perspective, Vol. 9, No. 3, pp. 81-82.

CEPPS-UGM. (2004). “Factors Influence the Low Lending to Deposit Ratio (LDR) in the General Bank in DIY”. CEPPS-UGM Working Paper Series, in collaboration with Bank Indonesia.

Chibba, Michael. (2009). “Poverty Reduction in Developing Countries”. World Economics, Vol. 9, No. 1

__________. (2009). “Financial inclusion, poverty reduction and the Millennium Development Goals.” European Journal of Development Research 21(2): 213–230.

Cross, R., et al. (2001). “Information Seeking in Social Context: Structural Influences and Receipt of Information Benefits”. IEEE Transaction on System, Man, and Cybernetics Part C: Applications and Reviews, 31(4), pp. 438-448.

Dercon, S. (1996). “Risk, Crop Choice, and Savings: Evidence from Tanzania”. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 44(3).

Dev, Mahendra. (2006). “Financial Inclusion: Issues and Challenges”. Economic and Political Weekly 41(41): 4310-4313.

Giocoli, Nicola. (2012). “Network Efficiency, The Coase Question, and the Banking System.” Department of Economics, Faculty of Law, University of Pisa.

Kamath, Rajalaxmi. (2007). “Financial Inclusion vis-à-vis Social Banking.” Economic and Political Weekly 42(15): 1334-1335.

Kinsey, B. et al. (1998). “Coping with Drought in Zimbabwe: Survey Evidence on Response of Rural Household to Risk.” World Development, Vol. 26, No. 1.

38 O P T I M A L N E T W O R K T O S U P P O R T I N C L U S I O N

Kooreman, P. J. (1893). “AanteekeningenBetreffende de Korintjische Adat”.KoninklijkInstituutvoorTaal Journal Library.

Laczo, Sarolta. (2007). “Informal Insurance and Income Inequality.” Universite de Touluse, unpublished paper.

Morduch, Jonathan. (1995). “Income Smoothing and Consumption Smoothing.” Journal of Economic Perspective, American Economic Association, Vol. 9(3), pp. 103 – 114.

___________. (1999). “The Microfinance Promise.” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 27, pp. 1569-1614.

Moser, Caroline O. N. (2006). “Asset-Based Approaches to Poverty Reduction in A Globalized Context: An introduction to asset accumulation policy and summary of workshop findings”. The Brookings Institution 1775 Massachusetts Ave., NW Washington, DC 20036.

Notten, G. and D. Crombrugghede. (2006). “Poverty and Consumption Insurance in Russia.” MGSoG Working Paper, 2006/004, Maastricht Graduate School of Governance, Maastricht University, Maastricht.

Pelras, C. (2000). “Patron-client ties among the Bugis and Makassarese of South-Sulawesi.” KoninklijkInstituutvoorTaal Journal Library.

Pouchous, Anne. (2012). “The Regulation and Supervision of Microfinance: Main Issues and Progress”. Trade Knowledge Network (TKN) Report: International Institute for Sustainable Development (IISD).

Robinson, Marguerite S. (2001). “The Microfinance Revolution: Sustainable finance for the poor”. Washington D.C: The World Bank, Pp. x1vii, 304. ISBN 0-8213-4524-9.

Robinson, Marguerite S. (2002). “The Microfinance Revolution: Lesson from Indonesia”. Washington D. C.: The World Bank and Open Society Institute.

Rogg, C. (2006). “Asset Portfolios in Africa: Evidence from Rural Ethiopia”. Prepared paper for the UNU-WIDER project meeting on Personal Assets from a Global Perspective, 4-6 May, Helsinki.

Sarma, Mandira. (2010). “Index of Financial Inclusion”. Discussion Papers in Economics No.5. Centre for International Trade and Development School of International Studies Jawaharlal Nehru University, India.

Scott, James C. (1972) “Patron-Client Polities and Political Change in Southeast Asia”. The American Political Science Review, Vol. 66, No. 1, pp. 91-113.

Skoufias, Emmanuel. (2003). “Consumption Smoothing in Russia: Evidence from the RLMS”. Economic of Transition, 11(1), pp. 67-91.

Sudarmono, Junaenah Sulehan, Noor Rahamah Hj. Abu Bakar 2012 “Patron-Client Relationship in Urbanized Fishing Communities in Makassar” International Journal on Social Science, Economics, and Art, vol. 2 No. 2 pp.1-5

Udry, C. (1995). “Risk and Saving in Northern Nigeria.” The American Economic Review 85:1287-1300.

R E F E R E N C E S 39

Wallis, John J and North, Douglass. (1986). “Measuring the Transaction Sector in the American Economy, 1870-1970”. In Stanley L. Engerman and Robert E. Gallman (eds.), Long-Term Factors in American Economic Growth, p. 95 – 162, University of Chicago Press, USA.

Wik, Mett. (1999). “Coping with Risk in Agriculture: Income and Consumption Smoothing Strategies in LDCs”. Forum for Development Studies 2, pp. 329-344.

World Bank. (2007). “World Development Report 2007: Development and the Next Generation”. The World Bank Published Series.

Zarazua, Max M. Nino and James Copestake. (2008). “Financial Inclusion, Vulnerability and Mental Models: from physical access to effective use of financial services in a low income area of Mexico City”. Savings and Development 32(4): 353-379.

Zeller, Manfred. (2000). “Product Innovation for the Poor: The Role of Microfinance”. International Food Policy Research Institute Working Paper Series, March, 2000.

Zeller, M., et al. (1997).“Rural Finance for Food Security for the Poor.” Food Policy Review 4: 139.

Appendix A. Literature Review FINANCIAL INCLUSION There are many definitions and studies related to financial inclusion for BPD. Sarma (2010) defines financial inclusion as a process that ensures the ease of access, availability and usage of the formal financial system for all members of an economy. These views seem to be in accord with Kamath (2007), who defined financial inclusion as the process of ensuring access to timely and adequate credit and financial services by vulnerable groups at an affordable cost.

Cooperative, MFI, and informal financial institutions in Indonesia use higher interest rates than banks.26 Nevertheless, most poor people and vulnerable groups get their loans from cooperatives and MFIs with high interest rates. In India, Dev (2006) found that farmer households obtain their loans more from informal sources than formal sources. In the case of credit, many households actually are being exploited by moneylenders at very high interest rates (50% up to 60%) and, therefore, these households should not be seen as being financially excluded (Dev 2006).

This approach to investigating financial inclusion can be made through economic behavior that is a rational and aims to maximize utility, whereas welfare is determined by resource endowments and opportunities (Zarazua and Copestake, 2008). However, this approach contradicts the condition of asymmetric information and bounded rationality (Wallis and North, 1986). For example, Zarazua and Copestake (2008) cited empirical evidence from Mexico City that showed that access to financial services depends significantly on individuals' human and material resources, as measured by indicators such as educational attainment, employment, and housing status.

Financial inclusion has to go beyond creating new formal institutions or framing newer rules that call for a renewed thrust of the formal sector in rural areas (Kamath 2007). This emphasis could be an innovation and create financial instruments that capture the advantages of channeling loans by the informal sector.27 Chibba (2009) argued that financial inclusion has great potential for reducing poverty, promoting pro-poor growth, and addressing the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs).

NETWORK FORMATION OF FINANCIAL INCLUSION A good institutional system is needed for the development of financial inclusion, as the institutional relationship can be an asset accumulation channel. There are two links between the causal mechanism that relate resource profiles to vulnerability and poverty, namely a direct link (from A to C) and an indirect link (from A to B to C) (Zarazua and Copestake 2008).

26The interest rate of cooperatives and MFIs were about 30% up to 36% per month, informal financial institutions was about 20% up to 50% per month. The interest rate of banks (BPD, rural banks) was about 10% up to 26%.

27 It is also useful to be taught on how to save, manage money, calculate interest rates and assess debt capacity by the informal sector in terms of channeling loans (Zarazua and Copestake, 2008).

A-2 A P P E N D I X A

Figure A-1 Causal Links between Resource Profiles, Financial Services and Vulnerability

SOURCE: Zarazua and Copestake (2008).

Moser (2006) defined the asset accumulation policy as an accumulated capital asset of individuals and households. External factors play an important role in determining how easy is it for households to be able to accumulate assets. The institutional system and opportunities determine the possibility of asset accumulation strategies. Institutional systems consist of laws and norms that may block or provide access, or even facilitate the accumulation of assets. Opportunities for asset accumulation may be obtained by pursuing policies that create conducive environments for asset accumulation. This is related to the dynamic of micro-level household life cycles and issues of individual agency, and also macro-political and macro-economic aspects.

In game theory, the analysis of networking matters when individuals play cooperative games, even though the players may suffer from bounded rationality. The speed of cooperation among players in playing coordination games depends on the types of network that are formed among players. There are at least three types of network formation, namely general relations, roundtable formation, and star-formation (Bala and Goyal 2000).

The members of the general form enjoy a direct connectivity with all of the other members (see Figure A-3.). Egalitarian principles apply to this network. A network with a roundtable form is a condition in which each player only has to deal with the player directly to the left and right, but he doesn't have a network directly with the players who are in front of him. While the star network has one player in the middle, other players stay around and connect to the center. Players do not have the circular network between them, but each of them has a direct link with the player in the middle.

A. Resource Profiles - Material - Human - Social - Cultural

B. Access to Financial Services - Savings - Credit

C. Welfare outcomes - Reducing vulnerability - Changing on resource profiles

L I T E R A T U R E R E V I E W A-3

Figure A-2 Asset Accumulation Policy

SOURCE: Moser (2006).

Figure A-3 Networks Formation

The star network system is observed in all of the BPDs. The BPD head office takes the main role for setting policies and information. It can coordinate efficiently and control their branches at district levels (Kabupaten) and also auxiliary offices in municipal areas (Kecamatan). In relation to the BPD Regional Champion (BRC) scheme, a BPD serves as an APEX Bank in relation to rural banks (BPR) and also sharia rural banks (BPRS). It is imperative that BPDs and BPRs should play Coordination Games, and the star network type provides efficient cooperation between BPDs and the BPRs. A network is also formed between BPDs and MFIs, such as rural banks (BPR), sharia BPRs, cooperatives, credit-loan cooperatives (KSP), BMTs and micro credit institutions (LKM), provided that they are involved in the cooperation among them.

The General Network type The Star network type The Roundtable network type

Strategies Determined by individual and collective agency

Assets (Individual, household and collective) - Asset endowment - Asset accumulation

Opportunities - Life cycle - Macro political - Macroeconomic

Institutions - Laws - Regulatory frameworks - Norms

Appendix B. Interprovince Network of Sampled BPDs

Key to Operational Areas

Bank Aceh

Bank Nagari

Bank DKI

Bank Jateng

BPD DIY

Bank Jatim

BPD Bali

Bank Kalteng

Bank Kaltim

Bank Kalsel

Bank Sulselbar

Bank Sultra

Bank Papua

Non-Sampled BPDs

Foreign Country Territory

Details of Branches outside their own provincial area: 1. Bank Aceh:

a. Branch Office Medan

b. Auxiliary Office Tomang Elok

2. Bank Nagari:

a. Branch Office Jakarta

b. Auxiliary Office Kramat Jati, Jakarta

c. Auxiliary Office Tanah Abang Jakarta

d. Auxiliary Office Cipulir Jakarta

e. Branch Office Pekanbaru

f. Auxiliary Office A. Yani Pekanbaru

g. Auxiliary Office Nangka Pekanbaru

h. Branch Office Bandung

i. Cash Office Pasar Baru, Bandung

j. Branch Office Matraman, Jakarta

3. Bank DKI:

a. Branch Office Dago, Bandung

b. Branch Office Raya Darmo, Surabaya

c. Branch Office Slamet Riyadi, Surakarta

d. Kantor Auxiliary Office Cikarang, Bekasi, West Java

e. Kantor Auxiliary Office Solo, Central Java

4. Bank Jateng: Branch Office Jakarta

5. Bank Kaltim: Branch Office Jakarta

6. Bank Sulselbar: Branch Office Jakarta

7. Bank Papua:

a. Branch Office Jakarta

b. Branch Office Surabaya

c. Branch Office Makassar

d. Auxiliary Office Toraja, Makassar

e. Auxiliary Office Yogyakarta