The role of Consumer Credit within Neoliberal Capitalism & its expansion to the Surplus Population

25
Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London 1 The Role of Consumer Credit within Neoliberal Capitalism & its expansion to the Surplus Population Paul Smyth Abstract: This study is focused on certain key issues that encompass the expansion of consumer credit to the poorest, lowincome, unemployed and underemployed sections of society, as Marx terms the surplus population. In order to fully examine and interpret the mechanisms through which this has occurred in neoliberal capitalism and the reasons behind the expansion and introduction of credit, this study will analyse money and credit in order to interrogate the social nature of money, and the developments that have occurred within the capitalist system and wider society that has engendered this shift to a population using more means of private finance to supplement their living.

Transcript of The role of Consumer Credit within Neoliberal Capitalism & its expansion to the Surplus Population

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

1

 

       

The  Role  of  Consumer  Credit  within  Neoliberal  Capitalism  &  its  expansion  to  the  Surplus  Population  

 Paul  Smyth  

   Abstract:    This  study  is  focused  on  certain  key  issues  that  encompass  the  expansion  of  consumer  credit  to  the  poorest,  low-­‐income,  unemployed  and  underemployed  sections  of  society,  as  Marx  terms  the  surplus  population.  In  order  to  fully  examine  and  interpret  the  mechanisms  through  which  this  has  occurred  in  neoliberal  capitalism  and  the  reasons  behind  the  expansion  and  introduction  of  credit,  this  study  will  analyse  money  and  credit  in  order  to  interrogate  the  social  nature  of  money,  and  the  developments  that  have  occurred  within  the  capitalist  system  and  wider  society  that  has  engendered  this  shift  to  a  population  using  more  means  of  private  finance  to  supplement  their  living.      

       

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

2

Table  of  Contents      

I. Introduction…………………………………………………………………... 3 II. Neoliberalism in Context…………………………………………………….. 4 III. Theoretical Framework…………………………………………..................... 5

- IV. Money………………………………………………..................... 5 - V. Credit……………………………………………………………... 9 - VI. Capital Accumulation & The Surplus Population……………… 11

VII. Neoliberal trends & the expansion of the UK Credit Card Industry………. 13 VIII. Conclusion………………………………………………………………… 23

                                                     

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

3

I.  Introduction      This  study  is  focused  on  certain  key  issues  that  encompass  the  expansion  of  consumer  credit  to  the  poorest,  low-­‐income,  unemployed  and  underemployed  sections  of  society,  as  Marx  terms  the  surplus  population.  In  order  to  fully  examine  and  interpret  the  mechanisms  through  which  this  has  occurred  in  neoliberal  capitalism  and  the  reasons  behind  the  expansion  and  introduction  of  credit,  this  study  will  analyse  money  and  credit  in  order  to  interrogate  the  social  nature  of  money,  and  the  developments  that  have  occurred  within  the  capitalist  system  and  wider  society  that  has  engendered  this  shift  to  a  population  using  more  means  of  private  finance  to  supplement  their  living.      The  expanding  reliance  on  credit  amongst  the  surplus  population  has  become  a  commonplace  occurrence  within  recent  decades,  with  unsecured  consumer  debt  tripling  between  1993  and  2013,  reaching  nearly  £160bn  by  November  2013  (Credit  Cards,  2015).  With  new  forms  of  credit  inducing  debt  cycles  coming  to  the  fore,  from  credit  cards  and  payday  loans,  these  appear  to  have  now  become  normalised  and  amalgamated  into  the  mainstream  narrative  as  a  way  to  supplement  daily  costs  of  living  in  place  of  decent  living  wages.      This  examination  utilises  elements  of  Marxist  political  economy  and  political  sociology  to  provide  a  conceptual  framework  to  analyse  these  developments  in  the  neoliberal  era,  with  specific  focus  on  the  role  of  money  and  credit  within  capitalist  society,  and  an  analysis  of  its  social  nature  to  formulate  a  more  thorough  understanding  of  how  it  relates  to  the  surplus  population.  This  approach  is  optimal  due  to  the  nature  of  other  analyses  of  credit  and  financialisation,  which,  more  often  than  not,  observe  money  (and  credit  as  it  derives  from  it)  as  'a  given',  rather  than  looking  at  money  less  as  a  thing  in  itself  and  instead,  as  a  social  construct  within  a  capitalist  society.        This  theoretical  framework  is  combined  with  a  case  study  focusing  on  trends  within  the  UK  neoliberal  era  that  have  created  a  space  for  the  expansion  of  consumer  credit.  The  trends  resulting  from  neoliberal  state  action  that  will  be  empirically  analysed  are,  unemployment,  inequality,  poverty  and  so  forth;  this  is  combined  with  a  study  of  statistical  trends  within  the  UK  credit  card  industry  with  specific  focus  on  credit  card  expansion  to  the  surplus  population  and  the  rise  of  indebtedness  over  the  neoliberal  period.  This  informs  the  theoretical  analysis  and  provides  for  an  in-­‐depth  view  on  the  rise  of  credit  within  a  defined  contextual  period  with  a  direct  focus  on  the  largest  aspect  of  consumer  credit;  the  credit  card.      The  neoliberal  era,  a  time  frame  spanning  the  past  three  decades  is  the  temporal  context  of  this  study.  Accordingly,  to  proceed  to  examine  credit  as  a  part  of  this  trend,  I  shall  briefly  recount  a  summarisation  of  the  general  aspects  of  neoliberalism  in  order  to  outline  the  contextual  parameters  of  this  research  and  to  hypothesise  how  this  study  will  move  forward  through  these  parameters  by  first  presenting  a  general  understanding  of  neoliberalism,  its  ideas,  timeframe  and  influence.                    

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

4

II.  Neoliberalism  in  context    Neoliberalism,  the  name  attributed  to  developments  over  the  past  three  decades  which  has  influenced  and  informed  many,  if  not  all  areas  of  the  market,  government  and  society.  It  has  been  termed  many  things,  an  ideology,  a  doctrine,  theory,  political  project  and  more.  Due  to  this,  it  is  important  to  dissect  the  ideas  and  evidence  presented  to  determine  the  nature  of  neoliberalism  itself,  its  trajectory  and  how  credit  encompasses  an  important  aspect  of  this  trend.      Former  UK  Prime  minister,  Margaret  Thatcher  once  said;  "There  is  no  such  thing  as  society.  There  are  individual  men  and  women,  and  there  are  families"  (Womans  Own  Magazine,  1987).  This  type  of  political  rhetoric  is  indicative  of  aspects  of  neoliberal  thought;  the  notion  of  individualism,  a  general  rejection  of  collectivism,  state  planning  and  interference  inasmuch  as  it  impedes  on  'individual  freedom'  correlating  into  economistic  understandings  of  freedom  to  make  profit.        The  recycling  of  neoliberal  rhetoric  flowing  through  political  parties  since  the  1970's,  the  rise  of  the  'New  Right'  in  the  United  Kingdom  and  United  States,  the  subsequent  transformation  of  traditional  social  democratic  parties  such  as  Labour  in  the  UK,  notably  shifting  towards  neoliberal  policies  under  Tony  Blair,  is  indicative  of  the  reach  of  these  trends  and  its  coalescing  into  the  mainstream  narrative  of  government  and  wider  society.      Harvey  (2005)  suggests  it  has  become  a  part  of  the  common  sense  way  that  we  interpret  and  understand  the  world,  which  correlates  to  the  Gramscian  view  of  a  bourgeois  hegemony  within  capitalism  (Harvey,  2005,  p.  3).  Although  it  has  been  charged  with  being  an  ideological  framework,  a  political-­‐economic  way  of  organising  society,  a  mode  of  governance  and  a  complex  permeation  of  society  in  general.  It  is  important  to  understand  that  neoliberalism  cannot  always  be  viewed  as  a  linear  process;  it  straddles  a  wide  range  of  different  phenomena  from  the  economic  to  the  political  and  social  at  different  levels  (Saad-­‐Filho  &  Johnston,  2005,  p.  1).        Saad-­‐Filho  (2005)  demonstrates  that  although  neoliberal  practice  in  every  country  is  different,  the  overall  picture  is  that  the  most  basic  feature  of  neoliberalism  is  the  "systematic  use  of  state  power  to  impose  (financial)  market  imperatives,  in  a  domestic  process  that  is  replicated  internationally  by  'globalisation'  (Saad-­‐Filho  &  Johnston,  2005,  p.  3).  Harvey  (2005)  makes  the  point  that  neoliberalism  from  the  outset  is  a  theory;  one  of  political  economic  practices  that  proposes  to  advance  human  well  being  within  an  institutional  framework  of  strong  private  property  rights,  free  markets  and  free  trade;  with  all  this  being  accomplished  through  the  liberation  of  individual  entrepreneurial  freedoms  and  skills  (Harvey,  2005,  p.  2).        Despite  its  roots  in  classical  and  neo  classical  political  economy,  neoliberalism  as  the  name  infers,  is  something  new  and  is  most  associated  with  twentieth  century  developments;  and  with  neoclassical  (what  is  now  termed  mainstream)  economics,  thus  a  key  insight  in  this  correlation  is,  these  ideas,  that  inform  government  policy,  economics  and  wider  society  as  a  whole  are  underpinned  by  what  I  argue  are  fundamental  flaws  in  the  understanding  of  money  and  credit  money  in  the  existing  literature  on  the  topic  which  are  examined  in  the  proceeding  chapters.            

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

5

III.  Theoretical  framework      The  first  step  in  analysing  the  emergence,  expansion  and  role  of  credit  within  neoliberal  capitalism,  is  to  set  out  a  theoretical  framework  within  which  to  situate  the  case  study.  This  takes  the  form  of  investigating  money  and  its  derivative:  credit  money  by  drawing  on  the  political  economy  of  Marx  and  more  contemporary  analyses  whilst  evaluating  the  current  literature  on  money  and  credit,  and  their  subsequent  role  in  capital  accumulation  and  relation  to  the  surplus  population.      IV.  Money      The  late  twentieth  and  twenty  first  centuries  have  seen  a  transformation  in  the  capitalist  mode  of  production,  to  a  more  financialised  form  that  coalesces  with  the  rise  of  neoliberalism.  Lapavitsas  (2013)  suggests  that,  "financialisation  is  the  outcome  of  historical  processes  that  have  taken  place  across  the  world  since  the  1970's;  it  represents  a  period  change  of  the  capitalist  mode  of  production"  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  167).  This  period  change  is  an  integral  focus  of  this  study,  but  the  monetary  basis  of  neoliberal  capitalism  needs  to  be  analysed  to  understand  its  role  first  and  foremost.      Money  is  itself  an  important  component  of  the  capitalist  economy,  and  by  analysing  this  through  a  lens  of  Marxist  political  economy;  money  constitutes  the  initial  category,  while  credit  and  finance  derive  from  this  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  69).  This  line  of  enquiry  is  obverse  to  much  contemporary  literature  on  financialisation  and  credit;  as  there  appears  a  gap  in  much  of  the  existing  literature  that  presupposes  the  economistic  understanding  of  money  as  'just  a  thing',  whilst  then  proceeding  to  analyse  the  social  and  institutional  effects  and  relations  of  credit  and  debt,  after  the  fact.  It  is  by  this  mode  of  investigation  that  the  actual  understanding  of  money  itself  as  a  fetishised  commodity,  which  simultaneously  induces  and  conceals  the  exploitative  nature  and  social  power  within  capitalist  society,  is  obfuscated.  In  this  vein,  there  has  been  a  failure  in  the  interrogation  of  the  social  power  of  money  to  sift  through  the  economistic  understanding  of  it  within  neoliberalism.  In  essence,  money  needs  to  be  thoroughly  analysed  as  something  other  than  'just  a  thing'  or  accepted  as  a  given,  in  order  to  understand  the  changes  in  the  wider  dynamics  of  capital  accumulation  which  has  spurred  the  expansion  of  credit  money  to  the  surplus  population.  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  6)        The  neoliberal  era  has  been  characterised  by  a  few  salient  monetary  features  of  financialisation.  One  of  these  is  that  commodity  money  has  been  notably  absent  from  domestic  monetary  transactions;  this  development  emerging  in  the  1970's  has  become  an  increasing  feature  in  recent  years,  coupled  with  the  total  domination  of  the  monetary  realm  by  credit  money,  which  is  mostly  generated  by  private  financial  institutions  such  as  banks.  This  is  indicative  of  the  changes  in  neoliberal  capitalism,  as  what  was  a  minor  feature  prior  to  three  decades  ago  in  the  economy,  credit,  has  now  become  the  primary  form  of  money,  sustained  by  the  credit  system  that  has  developed  in  tandem  with  this  domination  of  private  money  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  69).        Institutional  and  historical  changes  in  the  monetary  sphere  during  the  neoliberal  period  have  determined  the  monetary  underpinnings  of  financialisation.  As  Lapavitsas  (2013)  suggests,  to  fully  comprehend  these  changes,  money  and  by  extension,  credit  needs  to  be  understood  and  analysed  from  its  most  fundamental  starting  point,  what  is  money?  Where  does  it  come  from?  And  what  is  its  role  and  functionality  within  the  capitalist  economy  and  society?  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  71)      

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

6

The  existing  literature  in  the  main,  neglects  to  thoroughly  examine  the  social  nature  inherent  to  money  and  credit.  Academic  accounts  that  have  attempted  to  analyse  money  in  accordance  with  social  and  cultural  dimensions  are  heavily  anchored  in  the  first  instance,  on  an  economistic  understanding  of  money  as  just  a  'thing',  insofar  that  '  they  seek  to  represent  money  as  a  social  relation  by  virtue  of  the  fact  that  people  interact  with  it  and  assign  meaning  to  it.  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  25).  These  sociological  accounts  examining  the  social  power  of  money,  have  initiated  their  hypotheses  presupposing  money  'just  is',  whilst  subsequently  uncritically  merging  their  analyses  with  the  end  result  of  social  and  cultural  dimensions.  This  leaves  a  contentious  gap  in  the  understanding  of  money,  and  how  the  capitalist  mode  of  production  and  exchange  creates  and  enforces  the  illusion  of  the  power  of  things  over  people  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  6).        An  example  of  this  is  in  the  work  of  Zelizer  (1989),  who  argues  that  money  belongs  to  the  market,  but  not  exclusively  so;  she  theorises  in  tandem  with  the  neoclassical  economic  school  of  thought,  that  money  is  indeed  an  objective  means  of  rational  calculation,  but  it  is  not  only  that,  she  proposes  modes  of  'special  monies'  to  incorporate  the  social  and  symbolic  significance  of  money.  Yet  this  approach  contains  the  hypothesis  that  such  a  category  of  'special  money',  namely  'domestic  money'  has  social  and  cultural  dimensions  attached  to  it,  which  is  shaped  equally  by  economic  efficiency  and  by  changing  cultural  perceptions  of  money  and  family  life  (Zelizer,  1989,  p.  344).      This  form  of  analysing  money  and  its  social  relations,  is  indicative  of  the  lack  of  investigation  into  its  emergence  and  role  within  capitalist  society.  The  intent  here  is  not  to  refute  the  latter  claims  of  certain  scholars  on  the  social  and  cultural  effects  that  money  and  specifically  credit  have  in  the  social  and  cultural  dimensions  of  individual’s  lives.  These  poststructural  analyses  may  well  hold  up  to  scrutiny,  nonetheless,  the  intent  is  to  exhibit  how  the  main  literature,  is  too  much  focused  on  the  after  effects  of  'the  thing'  (money,  credit,  debt)  rather  than  interrogating  the  root  of  the  effects.          The  current  literature  is  to  surprising  extent  lacking  on  the  topic  of  money,  especially  from  the  'mainstream'  economic  view,  this  gap  in  the  literature  neglects  to  interrogate  money,  its  emergence  and  role  within  capitalism.  As  Ingham  (1996)  suggests,  within  the  mainstream  school  of  thought,  money  is  perceived  as  merely  a  type  of  'veil'  or  neutral  lubricant  in  the  model  of  the  economy  or  as  just  a  part  of  the  model  of  aggregate  economic  variables  (Ingham,  1996,  pp.  507-­‐508).  This  demonstrates  the  non-­‐debate,  between  the  mainstream  economic  view  one  on  hand  and  the  Marxist,  heterodox  and  post-­‐Keynesian  schools  of  thought  on  the  other.  This  gap  appears  to  sustain,  to  a  point,  the  argument  made  by  Soederberg  (2014)  that  this  lack  of  theoretical  contemplation  of  money  within  neoliberalism  is  indicative  of  the  elusive  character  and  power  of  money  itself.  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  7)      Moreover,  the  neoclassical  school's  theoretical  investigations  of  money  can  be  summed  up  into  two  strains  of  thought,  the  first;  entails  a  view  of  money  that  is  limited  to  an  abstract  measure  of  values  and  means  of  exchange.  This  view,  which  emerges  from  Leon  Walras,  remains  coherent  thus  far  with  our  analysis  of  mainstream  economic  principles  of  money,  as  merely  a  unit  of  value  or  means  of  exchange,  and  does  nothing  to  further  the  understanding  of  the  emergence  of  money  nor  the  social  issues  that  a  Marxist  theory  suggests  money  conceals  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  75).    Nonetheless,  the  second  strain  is  related  to  the  Austrian  School,  whereby  Carl  Menger  focused  his  discussion  of  money  on  strong  individualist  actions  (Menger,  1892,  pp.  239-­‐550).  Yet,  as  Lapavitsas  (2013)  suggests,  this  argument  is  predicated  on  money  as  a  means  of  exchange,  whilst  simultaneously  neglecting  to  acknowledge  other  functionalities  of  money  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  75).  Again,  these  formulations  of  money,  still  merely  regard  it  as  'just  a  

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

7

thing',  these  are  the  most  complex  theorisations  that  emanate  from  the  neoclassical  school  and  still  inform  mainstream  economic  theory.  This  exemplifies  the  continuing  lack  of  debate  on  the  social  power  of  money,  merely  reducing  the  emergence,  role  and  function  of  it  to  pure  economism.      Lapavitsas  (2013)  highlights  some  alternative  theories  that  have  come  to  the  fore  in  the  debate  on  money.  The  German  historical  school,  he  notes;  have  not  produced  a  theory  for  the  emergence  of  money,  but  rather  a  large  body  of  work  which  using  analytical  descriptions,  has  served  to  situate  money  within  a  social  context  that  incorporates  non  market  forces  such  as  ancient  practices  of  remuneration  called  Wergeld,  this  is  evidently  opposite  to  the  pure  economistic  view  of  the  neoclassical  Austrian  school  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  76).      Yet  it  still  falls  short  of  a  theory  of  money,  which  can  be  used  to  explain  and  interrogate  its  emergence  and  role  within  capitalist  society.  Lapavitsas  (2013)  elucidates  upon  the  work  of  Chartalism  in  theorising  money,  their  argument  is  that  it  is  "an  arbitrary  construct,  which  measures  commodity  values  on  the  basis  of  legal  and  customary  conventions",  thus  money  is  a  value  that  is  imposed  by  the  state  through  legal  conventions.  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  76)  This  approach,  as  Lapavitsas  argues,  has  support  in  our  contemporary  society  of  financialised  capitalism,  which  is  inundated  with  credit  money  with  backing  from  the  state.  This  can  thus  give  the  appearance  that  the  state  dictates  what  the  value  of  money  is  and  so  it  originates  with  the  state  also.  Yet,  just  because  the  state  intervenes  in  the  processes  of  money  functioning,  this  does  not  necessarily  mean  that  money  emerges  or  emanates  from  the  state  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  pp.  77-­‐78).      Other  theories  outside  the  mainstream  economic  schools  of  thought  that  delve  deeper  into  the  social  power  and  relations  of  money,  are  exemplified  by  Ingham  (1996)  and  Graebar  (2011),  who  create  complex  sociological  arguments  of  money  as  a  social  relation.  Yet  these  are  essentially  credit  theories  of  money,  where  interaction  among  agents  is  predicated  on  credit  relations  based  on  the  promise  to  pay,  which  removes  money  from  the  economic  sphere,  and  in  doing  so  it  can  be  applied  to  various  pre-­‐capitalist  societies  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  78).  These  credit-­‐based  theories  fall  prey  to  essential  weaknesses  in  their  arguments  in  that  they  offer  no  real  explanation  for  the  collapse  in  financial  relations  and  rise  of  monetary  relations  within  capitalist  societies.  Furthermore,  credit  based  theories  cannot  reconcile  the  fact  that  since  the  commodity  form  of  money  itself  incorporates  value,  they  are  not  just  'promises  to  pay'  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  78).      In  stark  contrast  to  the  other  schools  of  thought  noted  above,  a  Marxist  theory  of  money  and  credit  is  distinct  in  that,  money  is  not  'just  a  thing',  instead  it  encompasses  complex  processes  and  can  be  characterised  as  a  social  relation  of  power,  but  only  if  it  is  analysed  as  such,  within  the  wider  dynamics  of  capital  accumulation  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  15).      In  order  to  fully  appreciate  and  utilise  a  Marxian  interpretation,  it  is  important  to  understand  Marx's  conceptions  of  money  and  credit,  their  role  within  capitalist  society  and  the  social  relations  of  debt.  This  conception  is  inextricably  linked  to  the  aspect  Marx  terms;  fetishism,  where  the  social  relations  of  power  that  are  present  in  money  are  also  concealed  by  it,  as  "the  way  in  which  the  capitalist  mode  of  production  is  organised  masks  social  relations  of  power.  This  veil  or  disguise  is  what  Marx  refers  to  as  fetishism"  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  16).  Marx  (1990)  explains  the  "fetishism  of  commodities'  as  describing  a  state  in  which  'the  relations  connecting  the  labour  of  one  individual  with  that  of  the  rest  appear,  not  as  direct  social  relations  between  individuals  at  work,  but  as  what  they  really  are,  material  relations  between  persons  and  social  relations  between  things"  (Marx,  1990,  p.  73)  

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

8

   Harvey  (1989)  posits  a  useful  explanation  for  the  fetishism  of  commodities,  wherein  daily  life  the  social  processes  of  even  the  simplest  things  such  as  a  meal,  are  obscured  through  the  exchange  of  things  in  the  marketplace.  If  one  traces  the  processes  and  roots  of  a  meal,  one  would  come  across  a  whole  swathe  of  people  involved  in  the  process  of  creating  the  products  that  finally  arrive  on  the  dinner  table.  Yet  the  exploitation  of  the  workers  and  the  social  processes  involved,  are  hidden  by  the  effect  of  market  exchange.  This  is  what  Marx  describes  as  the  fetishism  of  commodities  and  it  is  what  has  to  be  contended  with  when  analysing  the  emergence  and  role  of  money  and  credit  within  capitalist  society  (Harvey,  1989,  p.  8).  As  Harvey's  (1982)  earlier  insight  suggests,  this  notion  appears  in  Marx's  theory  directly  after  the  conception  of  the  money  form  of  value,  as  Marx  (1990)  explains  "It  was  the  common  expression  of  all  commodities  in  money  that  alone  led  to  the  establishment  of  their  character  as  values.  It  is,  however,  just  this  ultimate  money  form  of  the  world  of  commodities  that  actually  conceals,  instead  of  disclosing,  the  social  character  of  private  labour,  and  the  social  relations  between  the  individual  producers"  (Harvey,  1982,  p.  17;  Marx,  1990,  pp.  75-­‐76).      Consequently,  it  becomes  clear  that  analysing  money  and  credit  in  the  sphere  of  exchange  becomes  problematic;  this  is  where  previous  attempts  as  seen  above  have  started  their  analyses.  The  existing  literature  either  starts  in  the  sphere  of  exchange  in  order  to  explain  financialisation,  and  so  begins  where  it  should  end,  or  they  conclude  with  money  as  'just  a  thing'  or  consisting  of  social  relations  due  to  our  interaction  with  it.  Considering  that  the  exchange  process  is  saturated  with  a  monetary  fetishised  view,  which  conceals  exactly  the  social  relations  that  are  concealed  by  money,  as  Harvey  suggests,  this  "exchange  of  commodities  for  money  is  real  enough,  yet  it  conceals  our  social  relationships  with  others  behind  a  mere  thing  -­‐  the  money  form  itself"  (Harvey,  1982,  p.  17).  What  results  from  this  is,  a  dissolution  of  communities,  social  relations  and  a  transformation  into  relations  mediated  by  money,  which  "becomes  the  real  community"  (Marx,  1993,  pp.  224-­‐25)      This  has  profound  implications  for  analysing  money  and  credit  within  the  realm  of  exchange,  considering  that  this  transformation  to  a  community  of  money  is  "marked  by  individualism  and  certain  conceptions  of  liberty,  freedom,  and  equality  backed  by  laws  of  private  property,  rights  to  appropriation,  and  freedom  of  contract"  (Harvey,  1989,  p.  168).  Therefore,  in  order  to  see  through  the  money  fetish  for  what  it  really  is,  Marx  developed  his  labour  theory  of  value,  which  in  its  entirety  highlights  numerous  points  that  give  insight  to  the  social  power  of  money  and  how  it  operates  within  the  capitalist  system.  This  is  what  Marx  (1990)  calls  the  socially  necessary  labour  that  has  gone  into  producing  a  commodity.  What  gives  exchange  value  to  commodities  is  the  labour  gone  into  it,  coupled  with  the  drive  for  surplus  value,  this  results  in  the  exploitation  of  the  worker.      The  Marxian  idea  of  value  is  important  in  understanding  what  the  money  form  masks  in  the  realm  of  exchange,  because  value  is  a  social  relation  embodied  in  the  socially  necessary  labour  time  that  is  represented  by  money  as  a  measure  of  value.  As  Soederberg  (2014)  suggests,  money  is  not  just  'a  thing'  nor  a  commodity  but  an  expression  of  value  embodied  in  price.  Moreover,  it  is  by  analysing  money  in  the  realm  of  production,  where  the  exploitation  of  the  worker  and  the  value  resulting  from  that  is  evident,  that  the  money  fetish  can  be  understood  in  its  real  capacity  as  a  social  relation  (Soederberg,  2014,  pp.  18-­‐20)      This  money  form  of  commodities  is  that  which  hides  the  social  relations  between  people,  and  instead  makes  these  relations  appear  as  relations  between  material  objects.  Henceforth  money  conceals  the  exploitation  involved  in  the  process  of  creating  value,  and  the  'finished  form  of  the  world  of  commodities',  which  result  from  the  exploitation  and  value  creating  

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

9

process.  As  such,  money  appears  as  the  universal  equivalent  concealing  the  relations  that  underpin  money  and  credit  within  capitalist  society  (Marx,  1990,  pp.  168-­‐9).  This,  in  turn  reinforces  the  community  of  money,  which  as  Soederberg  (2014)  argues,  although  real,  "it  is  a  fetishised  view  of  capitalist  society"  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  24).  In  this  community,  individuals  who  had  previously  depended  on  others,  interacting  with  one  another  through  social  relations  not  just  limited  to  the  monetary  realm,  are  now  governed  by  money  based  abstractions  such  as  prices,  interest  rates,  credit  ratings  etc.  This  is  indicative  of  the  changing  modes  of  governance  under  neoliberal  capitalism,  in  which  by  and  large  the  community  of  money  has  been  realised,  moreover,  these  abstractions  highlight  that  class-­‐based  power  and  exploitation  seems  to  appear  less  visible,  unlike  in  the  direct  confrontation  between  a  worker  and  his  employer  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  23).        What  results  from  this  analysis  is  a  more  thorough  understanding  of  the  social  power  of  money,  not  as  'just  a  thing'  or  a  mere  medium  of  exchange.  Rather,  as  something  that  embodies  social  power  due  to  the  exploitation  inherent  within  the  production  of  value,  and  the  coalescing  of  this  exploitation  and  inequality  with  a  concurrent  masking  of  it  by  the  money  form  itself.  As  Marx  (1990)  argues,  "money  itself  is  a  commodity,  an  external  object  capable  of  becoming  the  private  property  of  any  individual.  Thus  the  social  power  becomes  the  private  power  of  private  persons"  (Marx,  1990,  pp.  229-­‐30).  In  this  vein,  it  logically  follows  that  the  more  money  or  wealth  accumulated  results  in  the  vast  accumulation  of  social  power.  Soederberg  (2014)  suggests,  the  social  power  concealed  and  contained  within  money  as  a  mediator  of  commodity  exchange,  can  radically  transform  the  meanings  of  space  and  time  in  social  life,  particularly  as  these  relate  to  debt  and  credit  relations.  This  is  because  those  who  possess  vast  amounts  of  money  simultaneously  "possess  the  power  of  social  control  along  temporal  and  spatial  lines"  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  25).  As  money  does  function  as  a  store  of  value  within  the  capitalist  system,  it  functions  as  social  power  and  "allows  individuals  to  choose  between  present  and  future  satisfactions  and  even  allows  consumption  to  be  moved  forward  in  time  through  borrowing".  This  has  profound  consequences  for  the  credit  system  as  "those  who  can  afford  to  wait  always  have  an  advantage  over  those  who  cannot"  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  25).      V.  Credit      The  credit  system  encompasses  vast  complex  processes  with  different  forms  of  credit  money;  the  focus  of  this  study  is  consumer  credit,  which  is  supplied  to  the  surplus  population  or  in  modern  day  terms  'consumers'.  This  population  and  its  increasing  reliance  on  credit  money  is  an  important  aspect  of  the  neoliberal  era,  and  plays  an  important  role  in  the  capitalist  system  and  capital  accumulation.      Credit  derives  from  commodity  money,  and  though  it  shares  similarities,  it  is  also  different;  essentially  it  is  a  form  of  money  different  to  commodity  and  fiat  money  in  that  it  is  privately  issued,  and  unlike  commodity  money  it  is  a  'promise  to  pay'  (Lapavitsas,  2013,  p.  84).  As  a  form  of  money,  it  is  similar  by  way  of  its  fetishisms,  in  the  same  way  that  money  embodies  the  illusory  aspects  of  freedom  and  equality  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  27).  Furthermore,  Marx  (1990)  notes,  that  credit  works  directly  through  the  same  mechanism  as  money,  functioning  as  a  means  of  payment,  therefore  the  similarities  appear,  at  least,  on  a  surface  level  to  be  close  together  (Marx,  1990,  p.  238).  What  makes  credit  different  is  that  it  originates  in  privately  contracted  bills  of  exchange  and  notes  of  credit,  which  as  soon  as  they  begin  to  circulate  as  a  means  of  payment  they  acquire  the  social  form  of  money  (Harvey,  1982,  p.  245).  Furthermore,  Harvey  (1982)  notes  that  unlike  other  forms  of  money,  credit  must  always  return  to  its  point  of  creation  for  redemption.  Conversely,  money  that  has  been  accumulated  through  wages  can  circulate  throughout  the  system,  without  ever  returning  to  

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

10

its  point  of  origin.  As  such  money  is  social  from  its  inception,  from  its  realisation  in  the  production  process  and  the  exploitative  wage  labour  that  induced  it,  yet  credit  is  privately  created  and  can  serve  a  social  purpose  once  put  into  circulation  (Harvey,  1982,  p.  246).      Moreover,  Soederberg  (2014)  highlights  a  key  difference  between  the  two;  "credit  money  entails  what  Marx  refers  to  as  fictitious  value  -­‐  an  imaginary  component  -­‐  whereas  'real'  money  is  tied  directly  to  a  money  commodity"  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  35).  Thus  as  money  is  extracted  through  production  via  a  process  of  exploitation,  credit  contains  aspects  of  fictitious  value  when  it  enters  the  production  process  through  a  loan  by  way  of  creating  surplus  value  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  35).  Marx’s  (1990)  fictitious  value  means  that  credit  money  does  not  contain  any  value  itself,  unlike  that  of  its  relation,  the  money  form.  Comparatively,  credit  has  not  had  value  added  to  it  by  a  process  of  complex  social  relations  and  labour  adding  value,  it  is  privately  created,  which  does  not  mean  it  is  not  real  but  has  no  inherent  value  in  it.  Additionally,  fictitious  capital  is  different  from  the  focus  of  this  study  of  consumer  credit,  as  previously  noted,  fictitious  capital  is  a  form  of  credit,  which  is  specifically  used  to  realise  profit  through  the  production  process  by  way  of  a  claim  against  future  profits.  (Harvey,  1982,  p.  267).  Nonetheless,  it  follows  that  consumer  credit  is  also  fictitious,  as  it  is  not  tied  directly  to  a  money  commodity,  but  this  type  of  credit  money  is  geared  towards  circulating  as  a  money  form,  not  as  capital  to  be  introduced  to  the  production  process.      This  money  form  of  credit,  which  circulates  as  credit  cards,  variations  of  loans  such  as  student  and  payday  loans,  do  not  realise  surplus  value  in  the  traditional  sense  of  the  production  and  labour  process,  nor  through  the  way  in  which  fictitious  capital  operates.  Rather,  the  role  of  consumer  credit  is  a  creation  of  profit  through  fees  and  interest  payments,  which  entails  a  secondary  form  of  exploitation.  As  noted  by  Soederberg  (2014),  an  exploitative  relationship  between  creditor  and  debtor  in  the  sphere  of  exchange  replaces  or  augments  the  more  direct,  and  slightly  more  visible  relationship  between  capitalist  and  the  worker  which  operates  in  the  sphere  of  production  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  37).  Consequently,  If  capitalism  is  all  about  growth,  then  the  commodification  of  areas  that  were  previously  untouched  are  a  defining  feature  of  neoliberal  capitalism.  Of  specific  importance  is  the  process  of  consumer  credit  expansion,  which  can  be  seen  as  a  wider  part  of  the  dynamics  of  capital  accumulation.  After  the  global  financial  crisis  of  the  2000's,  most  criticism  and  focus  that  has  been  brought  to  the  fore  regarding  the  nature  and  causes  of  the  crisis,  tend  to  deviate  around  aspects  of  bankers  greed,  regulatory  failures  and  predatory  lending.        These  aspects  have  a  role  in  the  formation  of  the  crisis,  however  they  obfuscate  the  systemic  contradictions  within  capitalism  that  given  certain  factors  can  culminate  in  crises  of  great  magnitude.  The  understanding  of  money  and  credit  to  this  process  is  fundamental,  due  to  the  social  relations  inherent  to  them.  Just  because  consumer  credit  operates  in  the  realm  of  exchange,  and  bypasses  the  production  process,  it  does  not  mean  that  money,  the  exploitation  and  social  relations  that  occur  in  production  are  of  no  value  to  understanding  consumer  credit.  This  is  due  to  the  realms  of  production  and  exchange  being  intertwined,  furthermore  credit  does  not  appear  from  magic  mechanisms  within  the  market  nor  natural  processes,  it  represents  social  forms  of  power  that  are  utilised  to  resolve  the  contradictions  within  the  wider  dynamics  of  capital  accumulation  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  37).  The  expansion  of  consumer  credit  to  the  surplus  population  can  be  seen  as  tool  of  extracting  money  for  private  profit,  which  serves  to  temporarily  resolve  issues  within  the  accumulation  cycle  and  simultaneously  reproduce  the  surplus  population  as  a  necessity  for  capital  accumulation  itself.      

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

11

VI.  Capital  Accumulation  &  the  Surplus  Population      The  contradictions  within  capital  accumulation  I  am  concerned  with  as  a  point  of  focus  for  this  study  is,  the  over  accumulation  problem,  and  the  reproduction  of  the  surplus  population.  The  over  accumulation  problem  informs  the  second  issue  of  the  reproduction  of  the  surplus  population;  it  can  be  succinctly  described  as  the  instability  in  the  system  which  degenerates  into  crises  of  over  accumulation,  whereby  labour  power  and  capital  exist  unused.  This  can  be  resolved  if  some  way  is  found  to  absorb  these  excesses  of  over  accumulation,  or  else  there  will  be  a  devaluation  and  destruction  of  both  (Harvey,  1989,  p.  18).  The  reproduction  of  the  surplus  population  is  a  tension  within  the  accumulation  process  which  capitalism  also  depends  upon,  this  is  what  can  be  described  as  an  internal  contradiction,  which  can  culminate  in  an  obstacle  to  capital  accumulation  and  if  left  unchecked  precedes  a  crisis  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  32).      Soederberg  (2014)  notes  that,  "the  over  accumulation  of  capital  refers  to  a  situation  in  which  there  is  a  surplus  of  capital  relative  to  profitable  opportunities  to  employ  that  capital.  This  is  sometimes  accompanied  by  surpluses  of  labour"  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  32).  This  problem  is  incisive  in  its  relation  to  the  surplus  population  and  forms  an  issue  that  directly  relates  to  the  reproduction  of  low-­‐income  workers.  As  Harvey  (2001)  argues;  '  various  manifestations  of  crises  in  the  capitalist  system,  chronic  unemployment  and  underemployment,  capital  surpluses  and  lack  of  investment  opportunities,  falling  rates  of  profit,  lack  of  effective  demand  in  the  market  and  so  on  -­‐  can,  therefore,  be  traced  to  the  basic  tendency  to  over-­‐accumulation"  (Harvey,  2001,  p.  240).  This  in  turn,  can  increase  tensions  on  money  as  a  store  of  value,  and  for  money  to  retain  its  aforementioned  social  power  as  the  universal  equivalent;  it  needs  to  function  as  a  trusted  store  of  value.  Subsequently,  if  money  starts  to  depreciate  as  a  trusted  store  of  value  due  to  tensions  within  the  accumulation  process,  then  some  sort  of  fix  needs  to  be  introduced,  lest  the  problem  worsen.  Credit  money,  argues  Soederberg,  functions  as  a  vital  temporary  fix  in  the  accumulation  process  and  additionally  as  a  form  of  money,  albeit  privately  created,  it  wields  immense  power  (Soederberg,  2014,  pp.  32-­‐33).      The  relative  surplus  population  as  Marx  (1990)  infers,  contains  several  categories  of  low  waged,  unemployed,  and  homeless  individuals  in  society.  I  am  concerned  with  addressing  the  surplus  population  as  corresponding  to  the  people  within  UK  neoliberal  society  who  are  mainly  unemployed,  under-­‐employed,  and  those  on  low  wage  jobs,  who  depend  upon  private  forms  of  credit  money  in  order  to  augment  their  living  costs  and  reproduce  themselves  at  least  to  the  basic  subsistence  level.  Marx  used  this  term  to  define  similar  categories  within  society,  as  he  noted,  "the  relative  surplus  population  exists  in  all  kinds  of  forms.  Every  worker  belongs  to  it  during  the  time  when  he  is  only  partially  employed  or  wholly  unemployed"  (Marx,  1990,  p.  794).  Yet  Marx  applied  the  notion  of  surplus  population  to  a  very  different  time  within  capitalist  society,  which  incorporated  remnants  of  agricultural  workers  from  the  previous  feudal  mode  of  production  and  so  on.  Nonetheless,  the  surplus  population  category  is  an  important  aspect  of  neoliberal  society  with  which  Marx's  notion  can  be  applied  and  updated  to  suit  the  analysis  of  the  present  study.        The  surplus  population  is  an  integral  aspect  of  capital  accumulation,  and  as  Harvey  (2010)  argues,  the  management  of  the  labour  supply  is  crucial  for  capitalist  class  interests,  in  order  to  "create  and  perpetuate  a  reserve  army  to  keep  wages  down,  threaten  the  unemployed  laborers  with  being  laid  off,  disrupt  labor  organization  and  increase  the  intensity  of  labor  for  those  employed"  (Harvey,  2010,  p.  281).  Harvey  further  notes  that  this  management  of  the  labour  supply  has  succeeded  in  the  US  since  the  1970's  period  of  neoliberalisation  because  whilst  profit  rates  have  generally  risen,  real  wages  have  mostly  remained  stagnant  (Harvey,  

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

12

2010,  p.  281).  I  would  also  add  that  this  trend  of  neoliberalisation  has  performed  similarly  in  the  UK,  with  subsequent  wage  repression,  diminishment  of  organised  labour  and  increased  intensity  of  work  with  stagnant  or  reduced  wages  as  the  proceeding  case  study  exemplifies.      If  Harvey’s  point,  that  this  management  of  the  surplus  population  has  succeeded,  then  by  what  means  has  this  been  so?  How  can  the  reproduction  of  the  surplus  population  occur?  And  by  reproduction  we  infer  the  meeting  of  basic  material  subsistence  needs  in  order  to  survive  as  a  part  of  the  excess  labour  force.      Thus  credit  comes  to  the  fore  and  serves  multiple  purposes,  as  a  temporary  fix  for  over  accumulation,  by  overcoming  the  barriers  through  extracting  revenues  in  new  markets  through  the  credit  system  in  the  form  of  fees,  interest,  admin  charges  and  so  on  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  41).  This  new  expansion  into  hitherto  relatively  unexploited  areas  for  capitalisation  serves  the  purpose  of  temporarily  circumventing  the  barrier  to  accumulation,  and  it  furthermore  brings  people  into  the  economic  system  than  ever  before.  At  a  very  basic  level,  the  short-­‐term  notion  of  expanding  credit  to  the  surplus  population  ensures  new  markets  for  profit  and  an  ever-­‐encompassing  stream  of  revenue.  As  those  on  the  margins  of  society  will  forever  be  in  need  of  money  to  supplement/augment  their  income,  especially  as  previously  noted  by  Harvey  since  the  1970's,  that  wages  have  been  repressed  and  organised  labour  has  been  diminished.  Additionally  this  expansion  of  credit  allows  the  surplus  population  to  reproduce  themselves  to  be  used  and  exploited  in  the  production  process  as  and  when  they  are  required.      Where  this  whole  process  has  become  normalised  and  transforms  into  disciplining  the  population,  is  what  Soederberg  (2014)  refers  to  as  the  class  based  relations  of  power  being  distorted  in  the  realm  of  exchange,  where  as  previously  noted,  most  of  the  literature  on  money  and  credit  are  mainly  concerned  with.  Here,  the  surplus  population  are  reintegrated  into  the  capitalist  system  as  debtors,  and  a  relationship  of  exploitation  is  formed  between  the  creditor  and  debtor  which  subjugates  'consumers'  to  "abstractions  of  interest  rates  and  fee  payments  levied  against  future  revenues,  which  appear  external  and  independent  to  workers  (debtors)"  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  43).  Thus  the  social  power  of  money  rears  its  head,  as  previously  examined,  money  is  the  universal  measure  of  social  power,  and  thus  credit  appears  as  a  similar  form,  containing  similar  illusions  or  fetishisms  of  freedom  and  equality  as  exemplified  in  the  realm  of  exchange.      Soederberg’s  (2014)  persuasive  argument  insinuates  that  the  nature  of  credit  and  its  emergence,  is  the  result  of  capitalists  utilising  it  to  overcome  the  inevitable  contradictions  in  capitalism,  such  as  the  periodic  problems  of  over  accumulation  and  in  addition  it  serves  a  dual  purpose  of  facilitating  the  management  of  the  surplus  population,  through  a  process  she  describes  as  'credit-­‐led  accumulation'.  This  has  necessitated  an  aspect  that  thus  far  this  study  has  only  lightly  mentioned  upon,  an  institution  perceived  as  class  neutral,  outside  of  the  realm  of  production  and  exchange,  which  helps  normalise  and  depoliticise  this  expansion  of  credit.  This  perceived  'class  neutral'  institution,  the  state,  will  be  analysed  in  the  following  case  study  in  its  rhetorical  and  regulatory  capacities  as  facilitating  the  phenomenon  of  credit  expansion.                  

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

13

VII.  Neoliberal  trends  &  the  expansion  of  the  UK  credit  card  industry      This  chapter  comprises  a  case  study  of  the  UK  credit  card  industry,  to  analyse  the  expansion  of  credit  and  levels  of  personal  credit  card  debt  within  the  UK  over  the  neoliberal  era.  This  builds  upon  the  theoretical  framework  of  the  preceding  chapters.  Additionally  it  is  integrated  with  data  on  rhetorical  and  policy  features  of  the  UK  state,  trends  in  unemployment,  poverty  and  equality  to  highlight  changes  that  have  facilitated  a  space  for  the  expansion  and  proliferation  of  credit  to  the  surplus  population.      The  multi  billion  pound  credit  card  industry  has  seen  huge  increases  in  the  amounts  of  lending  to  individuals  in  society.  As  of  February  2015  the  total  outstanding  lending  was  £169.1  billion,  which  is  an  average  consumer  credit  debt  of  £6,332  per  household.  Additionally,  the  total  credit  card  debt  as  of  February  2015  was  £61.2  billion,  which  per  household  is  £2,293,  this,  on  a  credit  card  bearing  the  average  interest  would  take  25  years  and  4  months  to  pay  back  making  the  minimum  repayment  per  month  (The  Money  Charity,  2015,  p.  5).  This  trend  of  minimum  repayments  is  highlighted  by  the  fact  that,  at  the  end  of  2013,  3.7%  (over  1.1  million  people)  of  cardholders  had  made  minimum  repayments  on  their  cards  for  12  consecutive  months;  2.3%  had  made  minimum  payments  for  24  months  (The  UK  Cards  Association,  2014,  p.  9).      The  first  all-­‐purpose  credit  card  was  issued  in  1958  by  Bank  of  America  and  subsequently  evolved  into  Visa.  In  the  UK,  Barclays  issued  the  first  credit  card  in  1966,  yet  as  Richards  (2007)  notes,  it  wasn't  until  the  deregulation  in  the  1980's  that  the  UK  credit  card  industry  expanded  significantly  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  78)  (Richards,  2007,  p.  501).  Since  deregulation  there  was  an  exponential  increase  in  the  total  number  of  credit  cards  issued  by  UK  banks,  from  6,410,000  in  1975  to  71,887,000  in  2004  alone.  Unsecured  consumer  debt,  which  encompasses  different  forms,  yet  is  mostly  made  up  of  credit  card  debt,  almost  tripled  between  1993  and  2013,  reaching  nearly  £160bn  in  November  2013  (Richards,  2007,  p.  501)  (Credit  Cards,  2015).      As  noted  above,  the  deregulation  by  the  UK  government  in  the  1980’s  was  fundamental  in  this  aspect  of  credit  expansion,  especially  upon  looking  at  the  number  of  credit  cards  issued  from  1975  to  2004,  an  increase  of  over  sixty  five  million  credit  cards  does  evidently  not  occur  in  a  vacuum.  Yet,  in  order  to  fully  understand  the  expansion  of  credit  to  the  surplus  population,  it  is  pertinent  to  look  at  the  trends  of  the  neoliberal  era,  which  directly  precede  and  correspond  to  the  credit  phenomenon.  In  this  aspect  the  investigation  turns  to  trends  in  unemployment,  inequality  and  low  income,  which  created  a  space  for  augmentation  of  regular  and  stable  wages  with  credit  for  the  surplus  population.      Major  changes  in  policy  starting  predominantly  with  Thatcher’s  Conservative  government,  are  indicative  in  establishing  the  emergence  of  the  neoliberal  period  and  the  results  of  such  policies,  which  created  a  role  for  credit  expansion.  In  1980  the  Medium  Term  Financial  Strategy  was  introduced,  a  four-­‐year  plan  with  its  stated  aim  of  reducing  inflation  and  changing  fiscal  policy  to  achieving  monetary  targets  (Miller,  1981,  p.  50).  This,  Arestis  (2005)  notes,  was  a  major  shift  from  the  post  war  Keynesian  fiscal  strategies  of  macroeconomic  policy,  with  aims  of  high  levels  of  employment,  growth  and  low  inflation.  This  shift  to  a  belief  in  monetary  policy  in  line  with  neoliberal  proponents  such  as  Milton  Friedman,  was  implemented  on  the  basis  of  arguments  which  claimed  that  "people  would  adjust  their  inflationary  expectations…any  unemployment  would  be  temporary,  as  the  economy  soon  bounced  back  to  the  'natural  state  of  employment'"  (Saad-­‐Filho  &  Johnston,  2005,  p.  205).      

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

14

               Figure.1:  UK  Unemployment  in  millions,  1976-­‐93  (BBC,  2013).    This  was,  as  Arestis  (2005)  argues,  a  'false  prophet',  monetary  policy  failed  in  controlling  the  money  supply,  with  unemployment  (see  figure  1)  reaching  over  three  million  and  inflation  rose  and  remained  high  (Saad-­‐Filho  &  Johnston,  2005,  p.  205).  Further  to  this,  the  only  real  success  if  it  can  be  called  such,  is  that  this  shift  in  policy  continued  after  Thatcher,  through  to  New  Labour  and  the  present  day,  as  have  many  neoliberal  policies  and  practices  that  have  transformed  government.  Indeed,  when  Thatcher  was  asked  what  her  greatest  achievement  was,  she  replied  "New  Labour",  what  is  indicative  of  this  kind  of  rhetoric  is  that  neoliberal  practice  has  become  normalised  and  continues  (Mcsmith,  2013).  Furthermore,  the  reinforcing  of  this  neoliberal  shift  through  rhetoric,  is  embodied  in  the  words  of  Peter  Mandelson,  who  after  a  New  Labour  policy  gathering  in  2002  claimed  that  in  economics,  "we  are  all  Thatcherites  now"  (Minford,  2002).      

 Figure  1.1  –  UK  Unemployment  as  percentage  of  workforce,  1976  -­‐  2012  (Rogers,  2013)      The  neoliberal  economic  policies  from  the  Thatcher  era  continued  under  New  Labour,  yet  with  more  emphasis  on  a  'third  way'  between  the  market  and  more  social  mobility.  The  unemployment  rate  lowered  under  New  Labour  (see  Figure  1.1.)  and  remains  at  a  steady  4-­‐5%  for  the  duration  of  Tony  Blair’s  premiership  as  opposed  to  the  high  of  12%  during  Thatcher’s  government.  Nonetheless,  what  this  indicates,  taking  into  account  the  Marxian  perception  of  the  surplus  population,  is  that  this  percentage  rarely  decreases,  the  4-­‐5%  of  the  workforce  unemployed  during  the  supposed  ‘boom  years’  never  decreased,  only  

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

15

increasing  during  times  of  financial  crises  such  as  Figure  1.1  shows  in  2008  onwards.  Additionally,  another  integral  section  of  the  surplus  population,  the  underemployed  which  are  not  represented  in  unemployment  figures,  and  as  the  Office  for  National  Statistics  (ONS)  have  noted,  these  parts  of  society  have  only  statistically  been  represented  since  the  year  2000  (Office  for  National  Statistics,  2012).  

     Figure  1.2:  UK  Underemployment,  2000-­‐2012  (Office  for  National  Statistics,  2012).    The  underemployment  rate  (see  Figure  1.2),  those  workers  who  want  to  work  more  hours,  of  whom  the  majority  according  to  the  ONS  in  2012  expressed  a  desire  to  increase  their  hours  either  in  their  current  job  or  an  additional  role,  can  be  seen  as  a  steady  rate  of  around  two  million  during  the  New  Labour  years  and  rose  during  the  financial  crisis  and  continues  to  rise  presently  (Office  for  National  Statistics,  2012).  This  often  unrepresented  category  of  the  surplus  population,  in  addition  to  the  millions  of  unemployed,  are  the  parts  of  society  that  tend  to  rely  upon  credit  to  supplement  their  economic  status  and  daily  income.  This  excess  labour  force  kept  at  the  margins  of  society  is  representative  of  the  inherent  tensions  within  capital  accumulation,  and  its  production  of  a  surplus  of  labour.  This  surplus,  as  the  theoretical  chapter  of  this  study  indicated,  functions  as  a  tool  to  be  a  ready  source  of  labour  to  be  exploited  as  and  when  needed,  but  as  previously  stated,  this  surplus  needs  to  reproduce  itself  at  least  to  the  basic  requirements  to  function  as  an  'industrial  reserve  army'  as  Marx  (1990)  aptly  names  it.    

 Figure  1.3:  Gini  coefficient  measure  of  income  inequality,  1979-­‐2009  (Poverty.org,  2010).    The  dramatic  rise  in  inequality  (see  Figure  1.3)  during  the  neoliberal  era  started  in  1979  and  rose  until  the  end  of  Thatcher’s  premiership  in  1990.  Yet  as  Figure  1.3  indicates  it  continued  to  rise  at  a  steady  rate  through  the  New  Labour  years  and  has  continued  rising.  As  Figure  1.3  shows,  the  Gini  coefficient  measure  of  overall  income  inequality  in  the  UK  as  of  2009  is  

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

16

higher  than  at  any  previous  time  in  the  past  thirty  years.  There  has  also  been  a  marked  increase  in  the  number  of  people  in  low  income  households  from  under  eight  million  in  the  same  period  from  1979  to  over  thirteen  million  in  1990,  levelling  off  between  twelve  and  fourteen  million  in  2009  (See  figure  1.4).  Aretsis  (2005)  argues  that  the  neoliberal  agenda  of  the  Thatcher  years  was  a  major  contributor  to  inequality,  through  unabashed  promotion  of  the  market  and  rhetoric  of  incentives  along  with  attacks  on  trade  union  power  and  collective  bargaining  as  contributory  factors  in  the  rise  of  inequality.  (Saad-­‐Filho  &  Johnston,  2005,  p.  206)    

 Figure  1.4:  Number  of  people  in  low-­‐income  households,  1979-­‐2009  (Poverty.org,  2010).    Moreover,  attacks  on  trade  unions,  which  has  led  to  subsequent  diminished  trade  union  membership  (see  figure  1.5),  has  a  direct  correlation  with  wage  repression.  As  can  be  seen  from  Figure  1.6,  even  with  diminished  trade  union  membership,  those  employed  and  a  member  of  a  trade  union  as  of  2011  generally  enjoy  higher  rates  of  pay,  as  Figure  1.6  further  indicates,  only  one  in  nine  workers  earning  less  than  £7  belong  to  a  trade  union,  much  smaller  than  those  with  higher  hourly  wages.  The  neoliberal  tactics  of  attacking  trade  unions,  and  subsequent  decline  in  membership  and  restrictions  imposed  upon  union  rights,  proved  an  effective  tool  in  combatting  the  power  of  labour  in  the  interest  of  capital.      

 Figure  1.5:  Trade  Union  membership,  1892-­‐2007  (Pettinger,  2013).    As  Figure  1.6  indicates,  even  with  low  levels  of  union  membership,  people  are  far  more  likely  to  have  higher  wages  and  increases  through  being  unionised.  The  restrictive  anti  union  laws  that  The  Trade  Union  and  Labour  Party  Liaison  Organisation  (2007)  regard  as  "inherited  from  

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

17

the  Thatcher/Major  era  remain  in  place,  seriously  circumscribing  trade  union  freedom"  (The  Trade  Union  and  Labour  Party  Liaison  Organisation  ,  2007,  p.  2).      These  anti-­‐union  laws  indicate  the  continuation  of  the  neoliberal  trend  under  New  Labour,  furthermore  the  International  Labor  Organisation  recently  found  that,  "the  British  government  is  now  regularly  found  to  be  in  breach  of  ILO  conventions  on  fundamental  trade  union  rights  by  the  ILO  committee  of  experts…most  recently,  the  United  Kingdom  was  found  to  be  in  breach  of  article  11  of  the  European  Convention  on  Human  Rights"  (The  Trade  Union  and  Labour  Party  Liaison  Organisation  ,  2007,  p.  1).    

   Figure  1.6:  Proportion  of  pay  group  that  belong  to  a  trade  union,  2011  (Poverty.org,  2010)    The  actions  of  government  through  the  neoliberal  era  that  have  been  elucidated  on  through  the  above  statistics  have  evidently  played  significantly  into  issues  of  poverty,  unemployment,  underemployment,  wage  repression  and  the  negative  consequences  of  a  vastly  unequal  society.  In  pure  economic  terms,  this  causes  issues  due  to  the  fact  that,  if  large  proportions  of  the  population  are  being  reduced  to  low  wages,  unemployment  and  underemployment  for  the  benefit  of  capital  at  the  expense  of  workers,  then  where  does  the  demand  come  from?      Thus  credit  appears  to  have  served  as  the  answer,  as  Harvey's  (2010)  key  insight  suggests;  "With  real  wages  stagnant  or  falling  after  1980,  the  deficit  in  effective  demand  was  largely  bridged  by  resort  to  the  credit  system…wage  repression  produces  a  deficit  of  effective  demand  that  is  covered  by  increasing  indebtedness,  that  ultimately  leads  into  a  financial  crisis  which  is  resolved  by  state  interventions,  which  translates  into  a  fiscal  crisis  of  the  state  that  can  best  be  resolved,  according  to  conventional  economic  wisdom,  by  further  reductions  in  the  social  wage"  (Harvey,  2010).        Credit  has  seen  an  exponential  increase  since  the  early  1990's  and  a  corresponding  increase  in  debt  as  a  result.  As  can  be  seen  in  Figure  1.7  a  majority  of  this  is  secured  (mortgage  debt)  but  a  corresponding  rise  in  consumer  credit  and  debt  can  also  be  seen,  with  an  increase  in  net  consumer  borrowing  by  £207  billion  since  1993  with  a  subsequent  outstanding  unsecured  debt  of  up  to  £158  billion,  a  total  trebling  from  £52  billion  in  the  early  1990's  (CSJ,  2013,  p.  36).      

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

18

 Figure  1.7:  Personal  debt  by  Billions  of  pounds,  1993-­‐2013  (CSJ,  2013,  p.  34).      When  consumer  debt  is  studied  overall,  as  Figure  1.8  suggests,  credit  card  debt  appears  as  the  predominant  debt  type  across  all  levels  of  income  of  those  indebted.  For  those  as  part  of  the  surplus  population,  with  an  under  average  or  low  income  bracket,  credit  card  debt  appears  as  the  prominent  type  of  debt,  with  over  50%  of  those  on  incomes  less  than  £10,000  per  annum  being  indebted  on  cards  and  over  65%  of  those  earning  less  than  median  incomes  of  between  £10,000-­‐£19,999  per  annum.      

   Figure  1.8:  Debt  by  product  &  Income,  2014  (StepChange  Debt  Charity,  2014,  p.  18)    These  indicators  of  lower  income  recipients  tending  to  be  in  debt  on  credit  cards,  correlates  with  those  seeking  financial  debt  advice  in  relation  to  their  income.  From  analysing  Figure  1.9,  it  becomes  clear  that  those  from  less  than  average  income  backgrounds  appear  to  be  more  indebted.  As  the  study  over  3  years  shows,  in  each  of  the  years  2012-­‐2014  those  from  income  backgrounds  under  the  median  average  of  £20,000-­‐£29,999  required  the  most  debt  advice,  with  an  average  over  the  three  year  period  of  27%  of  StepChange  clients  requiring  debt  advice  earning  under  £10,000,  and  an  average  of  43%  of  clients  requiring  debt  advice  earning  £10,000-­‐£19,999.      

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

19

 Figure  1.9:  Demand  for  debt  advice  by  income,  2012-­‐2014  (StepChange  Debt  Charity,  2014,  p.  18).    A  qualitative  study  of  household  finances  and  access  to  credit,  by  the  University  of  Bristol  has  indicated  that  households  are  turning  increasingly  more  to  consumer  credit  and  in  turn  becoming  immersed  in  debt  cycles  in  order  just  to  pay  for  everyday  expenses  (Davies  &  Finney  ,  2011).      In  addition  to  this,  there  has  been  a  steady  increase  in  consumer  lending  as  can  be  seen  in  Figure  2.0,  even  with  the  drop  in  2009  due  to  the  financial  crisis,  this,  the  Centre  for  Social  Justice  (CSJ)  (2013)  has  argued  is  insignificant,  when  analysing  the  expansion  of  consumer  borrowing  prior  to  the  financial  crisis,  plus  borrowing  has  continued  to  increase  again  shortly  after  in  2012  (CSJ,  2013,  p.  36).    

 Figure  2.0:  Quarterly  consumer  lending  growth  rates  %,  1994-­‐2013  (CSJ,  2013,  p.  36).    The  CSJ  report  (2013)  has  noted  that  over  the  past  decade  households  have  taken  on  increasingly  high  debt  levels  in  comparison  to  their  income.  Although  the  data  both  objective  and  subjective,  over  the  last  decade  isn't  always  entirely  consistent  to  make  direct  comparisons,  it  is  clear  they  argue,  as  can  be  concluded  from  the  above  figures,  that  problem  debt  has  been  consistently  rising  since  the  early  1990's  and  has  not  significantly  subsided  since  the  latest  financial  crisis  of  2008  (CSJ,  2013,  p.  37).  What  becomes  clear  from  the  data  is  that  the  most  impoverished,  low  income,  under  the  median  average  income,  the  unemployed  and  underemployed  are  the  most  affected  by  debt  due  to  the  need  in  supplementing  their  income,  with  credit  which  can  quickly  surmount  into  cycles  of  debt  which  are  very  hard  to  break.        

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

20

 Figure  2.1:  Reasons  for  debt  in  percentages,  2014  (StepChange  Debt  Charity,  2014,  p.  7).    As  Figure  2.1  shows,  those  who  contacted  StepChange  debt  charity  for  advice  indicated  that  unemployment  is  one  of  the  major  reasons  for  incurring  debt  with  just  under  a  quarter  in  2014  stating  this  as  a  main  reason.  In  addition  a  further  12.8%  cited  reduced  income  as  a  main  reason  for  incurring  debt.  Whilst  the  charity  has  noted  that  around  half  of  their  clients  that  are  employed  on  only  a  part  time  basis,  thus  underemployment  again  features  as  another  indicator  of  reliance  on  credit  and  increasing  debt  levels  (CSJ,  2013,  p.  7).      If  seen  through  the  theoretical  lens  preceding  this  chapter,  then  this  large  expansion  has  dual  purposes,  the  role  of  temporarily  fixing  issues  within  capital  accumulation,  increasing  new  markets  to  extract  profit  and  the  reproduction  of  the  surplus  population.  Soederberg  (2014)  argues,  that  the  increasing  issue  and  use  of  credit  by  the  working  poor  has  come  to  represent  one  of  the  most  profitable  sectors  for  a  handful  of  banks  that  dominate  the  industry.  Additionally,  credit  card  debt  for  the  poor  increasingly  involves  a  vicious  debt  cycle  of  interest  payments  and  fees  that  stall  the  full  repayment  of  credit  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  78).  This  is  corroborated  by  the  fact  that  in  the  UK  the  top  three  companies  in  the  market  as  of  2001  were  Barclay  Card,  Royal  Bank  of  Scotland/Natwest  and  Lloyds  TSB,  which  between  them  accounted  for  52.0%  of  the  credit  card  market  with  no  other  company  owning  more  than  a  13%  share  (Datamonitor,  2003,  p.  7).      Additionally  the  BBA’s  Chief  Economist  Richard  Woolhouse  commenting  on  the  BBA’s  Credit  Card  Statistics  from  November  2014  noted  that;"  It’s  very  interesting  to  see  a  record  43%  of  credit  card  balances  incurred  no  fees  in  November  –  that’s  the  highest  proportion  since  records  began  almost  20  years  ago"  (British  Bankers  Association,  2015).  This  infers  that  even  with  the  highest  proportion  in  twenty  years  since  records  begin,  57%  of  credit  card  balances  in  that  time  period  accrued  fees.  The  data  starts  to  clarify  and  reinforce  the  understanding  of  the  drive  of  consumer  credit,  to  create  profit  through  interest  fees  and  charges  and  as  Soederberg  (2014)  has  previously  noted,  in  turn  it  creates  a  vicious  debt  cycle  encumbered  by  these  concrete  abstractions  of  fees  and  charges.  In  fact,  the  data  suggests  that  the  most  indebted  consumers  who  rely  upon  credit  are  preferable  consumers  for  credit  card  companies,  incurring  the  most  profit  through  fees  and  charges.  These  consumers,  known  as  'revolvers'  who  revolve  their  outstanding  balance  from  one  period  to  another,  by  only  partially  paying  or  paying  the  minimum  repayments  which  result  in  charges  and  higher  fees  on  borrowing;  in  2013,  39%  of  credit  card  consumers  were  classed  as  'revolver's  (The  UK  Cards  Association,  2014).      

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

21

These  practices  of  profiting  off  the  most  indebted  have  recently  come  to  the  attention  of  UK  regulatory  body,  the  Financial  Conduct  Authority  (FCA).  In  the  preliminary  details  for  a  forthcoming  study,  they  have  noted  that  it  is  their  intention  to  investigate  certain  aspects  of  the  UK  credit  card  industry  and  the  practice  of  companies,  to  ascertain  whether  "firms  may  be  charging  revolvers  more  for  their  borrowing  than  the  cost  of  extending  the  debt…and  whether  highly  indebted  customers  are  generating  a  disproportionate  amount  of  revenue  for  firms"  (Financial  Conduct  Authority,  2014,  pp.  17-­‐24).      From  this  data,  it  is  indicative  that  extracting  profits  through  high  interest  rates  and  exorbitant  fees  is  a  common  practice  in  the  actions  of  high  street  banks  and  lenders.  This  corroborates  the  perception  that  expanding  the  market  into  areas  such  as  the  surplus  population,  that  up  until  the  1990's  were  relatively  untouched  by  privately  created  credit,  is  a  vital  barrier  that  capital  has  circumvented  in  the  push  for  constant  growth.  Exploitative  interest  and  fees  in  this  capacity  also  serve  to  reinforce  the  form  of  exploitation  in  the  realm  of  exchange  between  creditor  and  debtor.  As  such,  this  type  of  secondary  exploitation,  unlike  primary  forms  of  exploitation  occurring  in  the  realm  of  production,  takes  place  through  the  extraction  of  interest  and  fees.  As  can  be  seen  in  Figure  2.2.  &  Figure  2.3,  the  debt  charity  StepChange  (2014)  received  the  most  complaints  (close  to  30%)  regarding  debt  from  users  of  High  street  banks,  of  whom,  as  noted  above  control  the  largest  majority  of  the  market  share  of  issuing  credit  cards.        

 Figure  2.2:  Complaints  against  lending  organisation  in  %,  2012-­‐2014  (StepChange  Debt  Charity,  2014,  p.  33)      Figure  2.3  indicates  that  the  majority  of  complaints  about  high  street  banks  were  mainly  the  result  of  excessive  interest  or  charges  being  added  to  debt.  These  abstractions  as  Soederberg  (2014)  argues,  appear  as  a  natural  exchange  of  equivalents  within  the  realm  of  exchange,  since  the  creditor  and  the  debtor  seem  to  enter  into  a  contractual  agreement  voluntarily.  Yet  it  is  exactly  the  social  nature  of  money  and  credit  that  reinforces  this  fetishism,  and  allows  for  the  ever-­‐increasing  exploitation  in  the  realm  of  exchange.  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  35).  This  is  evidenced  by  the  fact  that  those  incurring  fees  such  as  57%  of  those  in  November  2014  or  those  classed  as  'revolvers'  who  make  only  partial  or  minimum  repayments  are  those  more  likely  to  have  to  give  up  part  of  their  income  or  savings  to  repay  the  interest,  let  alone  repay  the  loan  (British  Bankers  Association,  2015)  (The  UK  Cards  Association,  2014).      

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

22

 Figure  2.3:  Issues  for  complaints  by  %,  2014  (StepChange  Debt  Charity,  2014,  p.  33).    As  the  CSJ  has  indicated,  data  from  the  bank  of  England's  NMG  consulting  survey  evidences  this;  statistically  44%  of  households  in  the  poorest  income  decile  are  in  fact  a  part  of  this  debt  cycle  by  spending  more  than  a  quarter  of  their  income  on  debt  repayments  with  generally  an  average  of  half  their  income  paying  back  interest  fees  and  principal  repayments  (CSJ,  2013,  p.  53).  These  abstractions  are  further  normalised  and  subjugate  people  through  the  social  power  inherent  to  money;  through  more  abstractions  such  as  credit  ratings  and  credit  scores  that  serve  to  further  provide  the  illusion  that  these  things  are  natural  and  allow  fees  and  interest  to  be  framed  as  an  equivalent  exchange  for  a  debtors  rating.  (Soederberg,  2014,  p.  38)      The  conclusions  of  the  CSJ  report  (2013)  correlate  to  the  aforementioned  hypothesis  and  empirical  study  in  analysing  the  reasons  for  increased  indebtedness  in  the  UK  and  the  expansion  of  credit  in  a  number  of  coherent  ways.  They  conclude  that  the  factors  that  explain  why  over  indebtedness  disproportionately  affects  those  on  lower  incomes  is  due  to,  lower  levels  in  savings  that  have  been  increasingly  used  to  pay  off  debts,  interests  and  fees.  Additionally,  major  factors  increasing  over  indebtedness  are  higher  levels  of  unemployment  and  underemployment  and  the  fact  that  those  on  lower  incomes  rely  on  high  interest  credit  cards  and  other  forms  of  high  interest  credit.        Moreover,  the  CSJ  (2013)  has  highlighted  that  this  evidence  correlates  with  further  statistical  studies  undertaken  by  StepChange  Debt  Charity  and  the  Citizens  Advice  Bureau.  With  StepChange  concluding  that  of  the  clients  accessing  their  debt  services,  55.7%  receive  at  least  one  type  of  state  benefit  amounting  to  36.6%  of  all  income,  a  further  characteristic  of  a  low-­‐income  background.  The  Citizens  Advice  Bureau  noted  that  37%  of  their  clients  are  unemployed  and  87%  had  an  annual  income  of  less  than  £18,000  (CSJ,  2013,  p.  55).  Analysis  of  these  figures  further  reinforces  the  trend  of  low  income,  unemployed  and  underemployed  workers  relying  upon  credit  as  a  means  of  subsistence.  As  the  findings  from  the  CSJ  further  note,"  Low,  reduced,  or  irregular  household  income  is  a  major  contributory  cause  and  driver  of  problem  debt…Commonly  known  as  the  poverty  premium,  the  cumulative  effect  of  these  costs  can  be  to  push  people  into  problem  debt….  A  large  part  of  the  poverty  premium  results  from  the  increased  cost  and  frequency  of  borrowing  that  often  becomes  part  of  life  for  low-­‐income  households"  (CSJ,  2013,  pp.  63-­‐85).                

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

23

VIII.  Conclusion   This  study  has  combined  insights  of  Marxist  political  economy,  sociology  and  quantitative  data  in  order  to  examine  money  and  credit  in  the  context  of  the  neoliberal  era  of  capitalism;  this  has  highlighted  gaps  in  the  existing  literature  on  money  and  evidenced  the  case  for  money  as  not  ‘just  a  thing’  but  an  expression  of  value  embodied  in  price.  Moreover,  it  has  been  demonstrated  that  money  is  inherently  social  from  its  inception  due  to  the  exploitation  process  within  the  production  of  value.      Equally,  the  previous  chapters  have  evidenced  that  by  examining  money  in  the  realm  of  production,  where  direct  exploitation  in  the  value  creating  process  takes  place,  provides  an  understanding  of  money  as  a  social  relation,  as  the  exchange  process  is  inundated  with  a  monetary  fetishised  view.  The  money  form  of  commodities  hides  the  social  relations  between  people  and  instead  presents  relations  as  being  between  material  objects,  in  this  vein,  it  also  functions  as  the  universal  equivalent  concealing  the  relations  that  underpin  money  and  credit  within  capitalist  society.  Furthermore,  as  money  is  a  commodity,  representing  social  power  with  the  ability  to  become  the  property  of  private  individuals,  thus  the  accumulation  of  it  by  a  few  private  individuals  results  in  an  accumulation  of  vast  social  power  concentrated  in  the  hands  of  a  rich  minority.    Credit  operates  as  a  form  of  money  and  holds  similar  fetishisms  to  its  counterpart,  such  as  illusions  of  freedom  and  equality  whilst  simultaneously  concealing  the  exploitative  relations  inherent  to  the  money  form.  Yet,  credit  is  distinct  in  that  rather  than  being  social  from  its  inception,  it  can  serve  a  social  purpose  once  it  starts  to  circulate  as  money.  Consumer  credit  has  served  multiple  purposes  in  neoliberal  capitalism,  as  the  previous  chapters  have  demonstrably  shown,  it  does  not  emerge  from  magic  market  mechanisms  but  is  privately  created  in  order  to  resolve  contradictions  within  the  dynamics  of  capital  accumulation.  It  has  achieved  this  by  opening  up  new  markets  for  which  to  extract  profit;  the  surplus  population  being  a  target  market,  as  the  case  study  has  shown,  consumer  credit  has  since  the  1990’s  been  exponentially  expanded  to  this  segment  of  society  and  has  to  reproduce  the  surplus  population  to  at  least  subsistence  level,  in  order  to  function  as  a  reserve  army  of  labour.    The  credit  fix,  has  served  to  decrease  the  tensions  on  money  as  a  store  of  value,  which  as  an  embodiment  of  social  power  as  the  universal  equivalent  must  not  be  allowed  to  depreciate.  Additionally,  a  secondary  form  of  exploitation  in  the  sphere  of  exchange  has  occurred  between  creditor  and  debtor,  which  is  further  obscured  as  a  process  of  exploitation  due  to  the  similar  fetishes  to  money  that  credit  contains.    The  study  has  highlighted  some  neoliberal  trends  in  government  policy  such  as  higher  levels  of  unemployment,  underemployment,  increased  inequality  and  diminishment  of  trade  unions.  These  have  served  the  purpose  of  creating  the  space  for  privately  created  money  to  be  expanded  to  the  surplus  population,  whilst  simultaneously  becoming  embroiled  in  debt-­‐cycles  that  provide  a  constant  stream  of  profit  through  abstractions  such  as  interest  charges  and  fees.  These  abstractions  are  normalised  by  the  social  power  inherent  to  money  and  allow  these  to  appear  as  natural  aspects  within  the  ‘community  of  money’  that  is  capitalist  society    Other  aspects  which  could  be  studied  as  an  extension  of  this  work  that  have  not  been  touched  upon  due  to  constraints  in  this  study,  are;  a  more  in  depth  analysis  of  the  states  role,  social  and  institutional  relations  and  the  disciplining  nature  of  debt  within  wider  society,  along  with  the  new  modes  of  neoliberal  governance  that  impact  upon  this  topic.      

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

24

Bibliography BBC. (2013, April 9). The Thatcher years in statistics. Retrieved April 15, 2015 from BBC: http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/uk-politics-22070491 British Bankers Association. (2015, January 8). November 2014 – Credit Card Market. Retrieved April 15, 2015 from https://www.bba.org.uk/news/statistics/credit-card-market/november-2014-credit-card-market/#.VT0lSYffjwx/ CSJ. (2013). Maxed Out: Serious Personal Debt in Britain. The Centre for Social Justice, London. Credit Cards. (2015, January 30). UK credit and debit card statistics. Retrieved April 14, 2015 from http://uk.creditcards.com/credit-card-news/uk-britain-credit-debit-card-statistics-international.php#sup9 Davies, S., & Finney , A. (2011). Facing the Squeeze 2011: A qualitative study of household finances and access to credit. Retrieved April 15, 2015 from University of Bristol: http://www.bristol.ac.uk/media-library/sites/geography/migrated/documents/pfrc1111.pdf Datamonitor. (2003). United Kingdom - Credit & Charge Cards Industry Profile. Financial Conduct Authority. (2014). Credit card market study: terms of reference. Graeber, D. (2011). Debt: The First 5000 Years. New York: Melville House. Harvey, D. (2005). A Brief History of Neoliberalism. New York: Oxford University Press. Harvey, D. (2010). A companion to Marx's Capital. London: Verso. Harvey, D. (2001). Spaces of Capital: Towards a Critical Geography. New York: Routledge. Harvey, D. (1989). The Urban Experience. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Harvey, D. (2011). The Enigma of Capital and the Crisis of Capitalism. London: Profile Books Ltd. Harvey, D. (2010, August 30). The Enigma of Capital and the Crisis this Time. Retrieved April 16, 2015 from David Harvey: http://davidharvey.org/2010/08/the-enigma-of-capital-and-the-crisis-this-time/#fnref-585-16 ) Harvey, D. (1982). The Limits to Capital. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Ingham, G. (1996). Money Is a Social Relation. Review of Social Economy , 54 (4). Lapavitsas, C. (2013). Profiting without Producing: How Finance Exploits Us All. London: Verso. Marx, K. (1990). Capital: Volume 1. London: Penguin Books. Marx, K. (1993). Grundrisse: Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy. London: Penguin Classics. Mcsmith, A. (2013, April 8). Margaret Thatcher's legacy: Spilt milk, New Labour, and the Big Bang - she changed everything. Retrieved April 15, 2015 from The Independent: http://www.independent.co.uk/news/uk/politics/margaret-thatchers-legacy-spilt-milk-new-labour-and-the-big-bang--she-changed-everything-8564541.html Menger, C. (1892). On the Origin of Money. Economic Journal , 2, 238–255. Miller, M. (1981). The medium term financial strategy: an experiment in co-ordinating monetary and fiscal policy. Fiscal Studies , 2 (2), 50-60. Minford, P. (2002, June 17). We're all Thatcherites now? Retrieved April 15, 2015 from The Telegraph: http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/economics/2765512/Were-all-Thatcherites-now-Not-by-playing-policy-pick-n-mix.html

Paul Smyth Birkbeck, University of London

25

Office for National Statistics. (2012, November 28). People in Work Wanting More Hours Increases by 1 million Since 2008. Retrieved April 15, 2015 from http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/dcp171776_289024.pdf Pettinger, T. (2013, April 19). Economic Impact of Margaret Thatcher. Retrieved April 15, 2015 from Economics Help: http://www.economicshelp.org/blog/274/uk-economy/economic-impact-of-margaret-thatcher/ Poverty.org. (2010, August). Young adults in low-income households. Retrieved April 16, 2015 from Poverty.org: http://www.poverty.org.uk/34/index.shtml?2 Poverty.org. (2010, August). Income inequalities. Retrieved April 16, 2015 from Poverty.org: http://www.poverty.org.uk/09/index.shtml?2 Poverty.org. (2010, August). Insecure at work. Retrieved April 16, 2015 from Poverty.org: http://www.poverty.org.uk/57/index.shtml?2 Richards, M. (2007). Irresponsible Lending? A Case Study of a U.K. Credit Industry Reform Initiative. Journal of Business Ethics , 81 (3), 499-512. Rogers, S. (2013, April 8). Thatchers Britain. Retrieved April 19, 2015 from The Guardian: https://docs.google.com/spreadsheet/ccc?key=0AonYZs4MzlZbdHE0dnFiRmIwM0Y3T1dMeXIwQVZBR2c&usp=sharing#gid=18 Saad-Filho, A., & Johnston, D. (2005). Neoliberalism: A Critical Reader. London: Pluto Press. Soederberg, S. (2014). Debtfare States and the Poverty Industry. New York: Routledge. Steger, M., & Roy, R. (2010). Neoliberalism: A Very Short Introduction. New York: Oxford University Press. StepChange Debt Charity. (2014). Statistics Yearbook: Personal Debt 2014. London. The UK Cards Association. (2014). The UK Cards Association Annual Report 2014. Retrieved April 4, 2015 from http://www.theukcardsassociation.org.uk/wm_documents/UK%20Cards%20Annual%20Report%202014%20interactive.pdf The Money Charity. (2015, April). The Money Statistics. Retrieved April 24, 2015 from http://themoneycharity.org.uk/media/April-2015-Money-Statistics.pdf The Trade Union and Labour Party Liaison Organisation . (2007). Trade Union Rights within a British Bill of Rights: DRAFT TULO Submission to the Joint Committee on Human Rights. Retrieved April 15, 2015 from United Campaign: http://www.unitedcampaign.org.uk/files/briefings/TULOsub.pdf Womans Own Magazine. (1987, September 23). Margaret Thatcher Interview for Womans Own. Retrieved April 4, 2015 from Margaretthatcher.org: http://www.margaretthatcher.org/document/106689 Zelizer, V. (1989). The Social Meaning of Money: "Special Monies". The American Journal of Sociology , 95 (2), 342-377.