The Presidency and the Executive Branch in Latin America: What We Know and What We Need to Know

72
The Presidency and the Executive Branch in Latin America: What We Know and What We Need to Know Alejandro Bonvecchi Carlos Scartascini Department of Research and Chief Economist IDB-WP-283 IDB WORKING PAPER SERIES No. Inter-American Development Bank December 2011

Transcript of The Presidency and the Executive Branch in Latin America: What We Know and What We Need to Know

The Presidency and the Executive Branch in Latin America: What We Know and What We Need to Know

Alejandro Bonvecchi Carlos Scartascini

Department of Research and Chief Economist

IDB-WP-283IDB WORKING PAPER SERIES No.

Inter-American Development Bank

December 2011

The Presidency and the Executive Branch in Latin America:

What We Know and What We Need to Know

Alejandro Bonvecchi* Carlos Scartascini**

*Universidad Torcuato Di Tella **Inter-American Development Bank

2011

Inter-American Development Bank

http://www.iadb.org Documents published in the IDB working paper series are of the highest academic and editorial quality. All have been peer reviewed by recognized experts in their field and professionally edited. The information and opinions presented in these publications are entirely those of the author(s), and no endorsement by the Inter-American Development Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the countries they represent is expressed or implied. This paper may be freely reproduced.

Cataloging-in-Publication data provided by the Inter-American Development Bank Felipe Herrera Library Bonvecchi, A. (Alejandro) The presidency and the executive branch in Latin America : What we know and what we need to know / Alejandro Bonvecchi, Carlos Scartascini. p. cm. (IDB working paper series ; 283) Includes bibliographical references. 1. Executive power—Latin America. 2. Presidents—Latin America. 3. Latin America—Politics and government. 4. Political science. I. Scartascini, Carlos G., 1971-. II. Inter-American Development Bank. Research Dept. III. Title. IV. Series.

1

Abstract*

The presidential politics literature depicts presidents either as all-powerful actors or figureheads and seeks to explain outcomes accordingly. The president and the executive branch are nonetheless usually treated as black boxes, particularly in developing countries, even though the presidency has evolved into an extremely complex branch of government. While these developments have been studied in the United States, far less is known in other countries, particularly in Latin America, where presidential systems have been considered the source of all goods and evils. To help close the knowledge gap and explore differences in policymaking characteristics not only between Latin America and the US but also across Latin American countries, this paper summarizes the vast literature on the organization and resources of the Executive Branch in the Americas and sets a research agenda for the study of Latin American presidencies. JEL classifications: D78, D73, H00 Keywords: President, Executive branch, Policymaking process, Institutionalization, Cabinet, Civil service, Bargaining, Budget process, legislatures

* The authors would like to thank Octavio Amorin Neto, Mariana Llanos, Lúcio Rennó, Ernesto Stein, an anonymous referee, and participants at seminars in Universidad Torcuato Di Tella, Universidad de San Andrés, and the 6th ECPR General Conference for their useful comments. The usual disclaimer applies. Opinions expressed in this document are exclusively those of the authors and should not be attributed to the Inter-American Development Bank.

2

“The second office of the government is honorable and easy; the first is but a splendid misery.” -Thomas Jefferson to Elbridge Gerry, PA 1797.1

“In government, for one to be able to do 50% of what one wants, one must allow the others to do 50% of what they want. One has to have the skill so that the 50% one gets to do is what really matters. Those who always want to have their way end up not having it at all”. - Juan Domingo Perón.

2

1. Introduction

Presidents and presidential systems have long been under scrutiny in the political science and

political economy literatures. Presidents are often singled out and blamed or rewarded for the

state of the economy and public affairs.3

The presidential system of government, in turn, has also been singled out in the literature,

mostly as the culprit behind the democratic instability experienced by Latin America throughout

the twentieth century (Linz and Valenzuela 1994). While recent research on regime stability

(Cheibub, 2002, 2007) and coalition politics (Zelaznik, 2001; Amorim Neto, 2006; Chasquetti,

2008) has seriously disputed the indictment against presidentialism, an analysis of how the

organization and resources of the presidency shape public policies as well as presidential and

regime survival is still pending.

This kind of accountability is useful to understand why

presidents may have an incentive to keep government expenditures in check (Persson and

Tabellini, 2000, 2003) and finances under control even in the context of discretion on the use of

public monies (Alston et al. 2008, 2009), as well as why in the short run presidents may also

exploit their powers to manipulate the economy before elections if left unchecked (Alesina,

Roubini and Cohen, 1997). But these insights do not shed light on how the presidency is

organized to operate under these incentives, or on what resources presidents may employ to take

advantage of opportunities or adapt to change.

1 In Foley, editor (1900, p. 716). 2 In Perón (1988). 3 Sometimes presidents are even perceived as the cause behind earthquakes: http://www.telegraph.co.uk/news/worldnews/asia/indonesia/6259005/Indonesians-blame-earthquake-on-unlucky-president.html

3

Thus, despite the importance and recurrence of the debate about presidents and

presidential systems, and regardless of the relevance of presidents in the policymaking process,

the advancement of the literature has been uneven. The literature on presidential politics has

typically dealt with four topics: the organization of the executive branch of government; the

resources of the presidency; the coalitions supporting the presidents; and the specifics of

decision-making in particular presidential administrations. Students of the United States

presidency have generated a wealth of work on all these topics, but the development of research

and knowledge on them for Latin America and other developing countries has not kept the same

pace across some of the topics.4

Research on coalition politics in Latin America has established that coalition

governments are frequent (Deheza, 1997; Amorim Neto, 1998, 2006; Zelaznik 2001; Martínez-

Gallardo 2005, 2010a; Chasquetti, 2008); that they are more unstable than single-party

governments but less unstable than minority single-party governments (Zelaznik, 2001; Amorim

Neto, 2006; Martínez-Gallardo 2005); and that presidents structure their cabinets in order to

maximize the chances of survival of their legislative coalitions (Amorim Neto, 1998, 2002, 2006;

Zelaznik, 2001; Martínez-Gallardo 2005, 2010b). Studies have also shown that the office of the

president is typically endowed with resources to help build and maintain cabinet and legislative

coalitions (Pereira and Mueller, 2002; Pereira et al., 2006; Amorim Neto, 2006), and that

presidents are generally effective in employing these resources for such purposes (Pereira and

Mueller, 2002; Amorim Neto, 2006). These works have demonstrated that Latin America has

mostly proactive presidents who are able, due to their constitutional and partisan powers, to

While significant pieces have been produced on coalition-

building and management as well as on economic and political decision-making in particular

administrations, there has been remarkably little advance on the organization of the executive

branch and the resources of the presidency. This paper intends to contribute to filling this gap by

proposing a research agenda on the organization and resources of the presidency and their effects

on policymaking processes. This way, this document may set the stage from where to build a

profuse scholarship for Latin America.

4 As an example, a major publication such as The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions includes a chapter about the American Presidency but has not similar chapter either for presidents in general and even less so for presidents in developing countries. Despite its advancement, strong quantitative analysis is still lacking, and much work still ahead. As Howell points out “It remains to be seen whether scholars can build a vibrant and robust body of quantitative scholarship on the presidency” (Howell, 2006: p. 318)

4

impose themselves on assemblies that, precisely due to those institutional imbalances, are mostly

reactive (Shugart and Carey, 1992; Carey and Shugart 1998; Cox and Morgenstern 2002).

Research on economic and political decision-making has established the existence of

common trends in policy orientation and in decision-making sequences on economic adjustment

(Haggard and Kaufman, 1992, 1995; Torre, 1998; Schamis, 1999, 2002), pension reform (Mesa-

Lago and Muller, 2002; Weyland, 2005, 2007), and left-wing social and political turns (Levitsky

and Roberts 2008; Weyland et al., 2010). Numerous studies have also shown the effects of

diverse political variables on presidential decision-making, such as president-government party

relations (Corrales 2000, 2002), the socioeconomic nature of reform coalitions (Schamis, 1999;

Etchemendy, 2001), union political strategies (Murillo, 2001), political party types (Levitsky,

2003), legislative career patterns (Ames, 2001; Samuels, 2003), constitutional powers (Negretto,

2006), public opinion standing (Stokes, 2001; Echegaray, 2005), and presidential leadership

(Novaro and Palermo 1996; Whitehead, 2010). These works have demonstrated that while

presidential administrations in Latin America differ in their outcomes, their stability and even

their survival (Pérez-Liñán, 2007), these differences are underpinned by common variables and

processes.

However, no equivalent knowledge exists on the organization of the executive branch

and the resources of the presidency. This gap, somewhat surprising considering the importance

that the aforementioned literature itself concedes to the office of the president, rests on two main

shortcomings: the lack of a theoretical and methodological agenda; and the lack of information

with which to feed the development of empirical research. This paper intends to contribute to the

solution of the first of those shortcomings. To this end, it purports to develop a research agenda

on the organization of the executive branch, the resources of the presidency and their effects on

policymaking by resorting to what constitutes the undisputed benchmark for such a feat: the

literature on the US presidency. Taking stock of the approaches and the knowledge produced on

those topics by students of the US presidency, this paper identifies a set of relevant pending

questions on Latin American presidencies as well as research strategies for their investigation.

The paper is organized as follows. The first section deals with the literature on the

organization of the executive branch. The second section takes up contributions on the resources

of the presidency. The third section reviews the literature on the effects of executive branch

organization and presidential resources on policymaking processes and outcomes. Each section

5

begins by taking stock of the literature on the US presidency, subsequently reviews in

comparative perspective the works about Latin America, and ends by proposing a set of research

questions still pending for the study of Latin American presidencies. The concluding section

sums up these research questions and suggests how to move forward in addressing them.

2. The Organization of the Executive Branch

One of the main contributions of the literature on the US presidency to the study of the executive

branch in presidential systems of government has been insights on its internal organization. This

literature has produced descriptive findings and explanatory accounts of that organization.

Descriptive research has established that the executive branch is a complex, differentiated

organization typically made up of three components: the presidential center, the cabinet, and a

series of advisory networks in which cabinet members and presidential advisers interact

alongside bureaucratic officials and even non-governmental counselors. Explanatory research

has argued that this organizational structure can be explained by either informational needs or

institutional incentives of the president. Studies have also attempted to show connections

between the organization of the presidential staff and presidential management styles. This

section reviews the research on each of these components and outlines a series of questions that

still need to be addressed in the study of Latin American presidential politics. Consistent with the

literature’s main foci of interest, this review will be primarily concerned with the nature of each

component of the executive branch, its relation to the president, its stability throughout the

president’s term, and its participation in decision-making.

2.1.The Presidential Center

In presidential systems, constitutions and/or special legislation typically outline the executive

branch of government as headed by a president assisted by cabinet departments, or ministries,

functionally differentiated by policy area and charged with advising the president on their

specific turf. But apart from cabinets, presidents are also assisted by a closer group of advisers

with no departmental responsibilities who work under their most direct supervision. These

advisers constitute the office of the president, or presidential center.

The presidential center has been a relatively recent development within the organization

of the executive branch. Presidents have always had confidants and close advisers, but the

6

institutionalization of their role did not come about in the United States until the late 1930s,

when the Executive Office of the President (EOP) was created under the auspices of the

Roosevelt Administration. The rationale for the establishment of the EOP appears to have been

the strengthening of the president’s ability to coordinate the work of cabinet departments and

other executive agencies which, due to their own organizational interests such as budgetary or

power maximization and service delivery to constituents and interest groups, typically have

“little incentive to subjugate their departmental needs to the president’s broader bargaining

interests” (Dickinson, 1997: p. 46). This rationale points to a bi-dimensional explanation of the

emergence of the presidential center: on the one hand, as a device to solve informational

asymmetries within the executive branch that might hurt the president’s decision-making ability,

and on the other hand, as an artifact to secure the political leadership of the president.

The informational explanation of the presidential center stems from the bargaining

paradigm of presidential politics espoused by the definitive work e classic on the US presidency,

Richard Neustadt’s Presidential Power and the Modern Presidents (Neustadt, 1990). According

to this paradigm, in a political system of separated institutions sharing power (Jones, 1994)

presidents are forced to bargain with other actors—Congress, the bureaucracy, interest groups,

and the media—in order to influence government outcomes. To bargain effectively, presidents’

primary need is information. More specifically, they need information that enables them to retain

or augment their influence on the other actors with which they have to bargain—i.e., contrasting

information, from multiple sources, so that presidents can weigh the biases and interests of those

sources and come up with their own assessment and decisions (Neustadt, 1990; Rudalevige,

2002). The presidential center allows presidents to do exactly that: multiply information sources

by charging close advisers with duplicating, supervising or monitoring the task of cabinet

ministers (Ponder, 2000) and contrast policy ideas and political assessments by inciting dissent

between ministers and advisers (Neustadt, 1990; Dickinson, 1997). The presidential center helps

presidents to retain bargaining power by enabling them to escape the informational asymmetries

to which they are inevitably prey: that of ministries concerned primarily with their own turf; that

of bureaucrats concerned primarily with technical criteria and interest group satisfaction; and that

of political advisers concerned primarily with the electoral consequences or public opinion

payoffs of decisions.

7

The leadership explanation of the presidential center stems from the unilateral paradigm

of presidential politics espoused by the leading rational-choice scholar on the US presidency,

Terry Moe. According to this paradigm, presidents have strong incentives to enhance the

autonomy of their office: they are elected by a national constituency that “leads them to think in

grander terms about social problems and the public interest”; they are held responsible for

“virtually every aspect of national performance”; and they are beset by powerful players—

namely Congress and the bureaucracy—with opposing incentives and enough institutional

resources to impose them. To assert their leadership over these players, presidents seek to design

and run “a unified, coordinated, centrally directed bureaucratic system” (Moe and Wilson, 1994:

p. 11) through which they can develop their own policy ideas and use their own unilateral

institutional powers to implement them. The presidential center allows presidents to do exactly

that: centralize decision-making by placing trusted advisers to supervise or simply lead cabinet

ministries from above and control the bureaucracy by imposing a hierarchical decision-making

process through which not only policy alternatives but also information diffusion and political

message are decided at the top (Moe, 1993; Moe and Howell, 1999). The presidential center

helps presidents to lead the government and the policy process by enabling them to escape the

institutional constraints to which they are inevitably prey in a separation-of-powers system, and

to attune their decisions to the general mood of public opinion over the particularistic interests of

legislators, ministers, and bureaucrats.

Regardless of the weight that each explanation may actually have, the emergence of the

presidential center has been linked to the centralization of the policymaking process by the

executive branch in general, and particularly to the hierarchization of that process under the

presidency.5

The increasing political and administrative relevance of the presidential center has

consequently induced scholars to focus on its composition, its relation to presidents, the stability

of its membership and functions, and its participation in decision-making.

5 However, there is little consensus among scholars as to the extent, the consistency, and the effects of this centralization of policymaking. See Section 3 for further discussion.

8

2.1.1 Composition and Characteristics The composition of the presidential center has been investigated with particular emphasis on two

dimensions: the types of staff constituting it, and the size of that staff. The premise of this line of

research has been that the kinds of persons recruited to the presidential staff and the ways its

operations are organized are the critical conduits through which presidents can influence the

performance and outcomes of their government (Burke, 2000: p. 25). Presidents may surround

themselves only with cronies and clerks, or with political and policy advisers with independent

standing; advisers may be pundits or seasoned political operatives, learned students of policy or

experienced policymakers, political system insiders or novice outsiders (ibid.). Presidents may

organize their staff in a hierarchical, competitive or collegial way (Johnson, 1974); they may

develop staff structures congruent to the challenges of their decision settings (Walcott and Hult,

1995); or may suspend centralization altogether contingent to critical variables in their political

and bureaucratic environment (Rudalevige, 2002).

The types of staff recruited to the presidential center in the United States have evolved

from an exclusively organizational capacity to a complex network of personal assistants, policy

advisers, political strategists, communication personnel, and legal counselors (Arnold, 1998;

Lewis, 2008). When the EOP was created in 1939, it comprised five agencies with distinct types

of staff and functions: the White House Office, where the president’s personal assistants (e.g.,

secretaries, chauffeurs) and closest political advisers served; the Bureau of the Budget, a highly

institutionalized executive agency (Stewart, 1989) charged with elaborating the yearly budget

and reviewing legislative proposals from cabinet departments; the National Resources Planning

Board, a New Deal agency specialized in long-term policy planning; the Liaison Office for

Personnel Management, which served as a link to the independent Civil Service Commission;

and the Office of Government Reports, which pulled together several information-producing

agencies (Dickinson, 1997). But since the Cold War the scope of EOP functions and staff types

has significantly increased, with the establishment of the Council of Economic Advisers (1946),

the National Security Council (1947), the Office of the US Trade Representative (1963), the

Council on Environmental Quality (1969), the Office of Policy Development (1970), the Office

of the Vicepresident (1972), the Office of Science and Technology Policy (1976), the Office of

Administration (1977), the Office of National Drug Control Policy (1988), and, in 2001, the

Homeland Security Staff (Dickinson, 2005). In addition to this, the White House Office

9

experienced its own internal differentiation: among personal assistants to the president,

communications officers, political advisers, and legal counselors (Sullivan, 2004).

The expanded scope of direct presidential jurisdiction has been explained as the joint

outcome of environmental pressures for increasing government activity, congressional action in

response to those pressures, and particular presidential initiatives to seize control over specific

policymaking areas (Ragsdale and Theis, 1997). But such increasing complexity within the

presidential center also appears to have pressured presidents into concentrating the control of

decision-making in their own office in detriment of the very agencies established within the

EOP. This dynamics has generated what has been labeled the paradox of politicization: the

recruitment of politically loyal but administratively inexperienced aids into the EOP has

increased presidential control over decisions but diminished the technical ability of EOP

agencies to advice the president on policy matters (Dickinson, 2005). Environmental pressures

and politicization may have thus driven the growth of the presidential staff (Lewis, 2008) but not

necessarily that of its technical capacity.

The staff in the presidential center of the United States does not seem to enjoy much

stability. Four not necessarily exclusive explanations have been advanced for this pattern. One is

partisan turnover: when the governing party is ousted, most of the presidential staff is also

changed. Another is the duration of organizational units within the presidency—which, though

increasing since the 1950s, has varied considerably from one year to another, particularly in the

late 1950s and early 1970s (Ragsdale and Theis 1997). A third explanation is administrative

overhaul, which has been frequent in the twentieth century (Arnold, 1998). A fourth explanation

is the changing nature of presidential campaigns—which which has forced prospective

presidents to invest more on specialized campaign staff rather than policy or administrative

experts, and has thus led to increased turnover rates after the campaign-turned-governing staff

proves inadequate for their new function (Dickinson and Dunn Tenpas, 2002). High turnover

rates help foster centralization of decision-making in the president but, at the same time, increase

the leverage of career bureaucrats over the policymaking process.

The tradeoffs between centralization and isolation before bureaucracy, between

politicization of the administration and technical expertise, suggest that the staff in the

presidential center must perform several functions within decision-making processes. Research

has defined these functions according to the specialization of staff types (Walcott and Hult,

10

1995), or to forms of staff involvement in the policy process (Ponder, 2000). The staff

specialization perspective, stemming from organization theory, argues that the president’s staff

participates in decision-making in one of three capacities: outreach, policy processing, or

coordination and supervision. Outreach tasks include liaison with Congress, press relations and

publicity, contacts with interest groups, executive branch staffing operations, and presidency-

executive branch relation management. Policy processing, in turn, encompasses information

gathering, analysis and proposals in domestic, economic, and national security policy—as well

as specific inter-branch policy structures such as task forces or commissions. Finally,

coordination and supervision include speechwriting, managing the president’s schedule, and

governing the presidential center itself (Walcott and Hult, 1995). Each of these tasks falls to

different offices within the White House, and each office is staffed either by specialists whose

specialization is based upon previous government experience, or by novices who owe their jobs

to their campaign work, their party connections, or their personal relation to the president

(Lewis, 2008).

The staff involvement perspective, privy to information theory, argues that the

president’s staff has three ways of participating in decision-making: as director, facilitator, or

monitor (Ponder, 2000). The staff as director centralizes policymaking tasks and reports only to

the president. The staff as facilitator brokers agreements among policy jurisdictions under the

president’s supervision. The staff as monitor delegates policy to other agents within the

executive branch but “keeps a watchful eye on the progress and substance of policy

development” (ibid: 14). These forms of involvement in the policy process need not be exclusive

of any particular staff member or structure; in fact, according to Ponder, presidents practice

“staff shift”—the movement of staff members and structures from one function to another—in

tune with the issue at hand and the availability of technical expertise and political capacity to

control the substance of policy outcomes (Rudalevige, 2002).

2.1.2 Relationship This organizational complexity transforms the relationship between presidents and their staff into

a critical issue. To work with their staff, presidents have developed different managerial styles.

Drawing from management theory, Johnson (1974) identified three: a competitive style, in which

the president stands at the center of decisions by fostering the overlapping of jurisdictions, the

11

duplication of assignments, and the development of rivalries; a formalistic or hierarchical style,

in which the president delegates authority on top advisers who run a hierarchical organization

with clearly specified, differentiated functions, and who filter the information and policy

alternatives that reach the presidential desk; and a collegial style, in which the president operates

as the hub of a wheel the spokes of which are a group of advisers who discuss and propose

collectively to their boss. As Johnson argued, each style has its own strengths and weaknesses:

the competitive style maximizes presidential control and considerations of bureaucratic

feasibility and political viability in decision-making, but demands an enormous investment of

time from the president to manage and solve staff tensions; the formalistic style maximizes

diversity in information gathering and advice, but may generate upwards distortions and

slowness in crisis situations; the collegial style maximizes technical optimality and bureaucratic

feasibility, but requires skilled presidential management to maintain a working group dynamics

(Burke, 2009).

Inspired by organizational theory, Walcott and Hult (1995: p. 20) argued that managerial

styles are a function of staff structures, and that presidents develop staff structures that are

“roughly congruent with the prevailing decision setting.” Thus, if presidents are confronting

decision settings plagued with uncertainty, they should build staff structures that foster the search

for alternative sources of information and advice, such as competitive or collegial arrangements.

If presidents face decision settings marred by controversy, they should design structures that find

and articulate the contending parties and viewpoints, such as adversarial multiparty advocacy or

adjudicative arrangements in which the president decides after thorough debate. If presidents

encounter decision settings marked by certainty, they should develop staff structures oriented to

enhance control over decision-making, such as hierarchical or collegial-consensual arrangements

(ibid: pp. 21-23).

Combining the above perspectives with transaction-cost theory, Rudalevige (2002)

contended that presidential centralization of the policy process was contingent upon the costs of

acquiring information, and those costs were, in turn, dependent on a number of political variables

such as divided government, size of presidential legislative contingent, presidential public

opinion approval rates, ideological distance between the president and the legislature, policy

area, issue complexity, crisis situation, and length of the presidential term. Presidents would only

centralize decision-making in their office when they can acquire information to do so at the least

12

possible cost—i.e., when policy proposals cross-cut jurisdictions, the presidential center has

stronger policymaking resources, policy approaches are new, and speed is of the essence (ibid: p.

39). Consequently, managerial styles should change according to the conditions that determine

information costs, and staff structures within the presidential center should be prepared to deal

with all possible contingencies.

2.1.3 Evidence in LAC

Research on presidential centers in Latin America is practically non-existent. Bonvecchi and

Palermo (2000) compared the staff types within the presidential inner-circles of Menem and de la

Rúa in Argentina, as did Siavelis (2010) for the Concertación governments in Chile, but their

evidence is more impressionistic than systematic. Aninat and Rivera (2009) described the

functions of the presidential center in the latter administrations, but with a normative orientation

towards proposing a reorganization of the executive branch. Bonvecchi and Zelaznik (2010)

reviewed the Argentine Executive’s governing tools but left out the organizational resources.

A significant field of research is thus open. What countries have and do not have a

presidential center? What are the conditions for the emergence of presidential centers in Latin

America? How are presidential centers structured? What types of staff are presidential centers

made of? How is the staff managed by the president: competitively, hierarchically, or

collegially? How stable are staff structures, staff types and presidential managerial styles in

presidential centers? What accounts for (potential) variations? To answer these questions at least

two types of information must be collected. On the one hand, legal and administrative

information about the structure of presidential centers, its evolution through time, formal powers

attached to each component of the presidential center, and the types of staff recruited. On the

other hand, qualitative and quantitative information on the relation between presidents and their

presidential center: frequency and nature of interaction between presidents and the different

types of staff; forms of staff involvement in decision-making processes; staff turnover rates, etc.

To process this information, at least two research strategies would be profitable. One is

quantitative statistical analysis of the interaction between the aforementioned dimensions of the

presidential center as dependent variables, and a series of independent variables of standard use

in studies of the institutionalization of the presidency: legislative strength of the president’s

party; formal powers of the president; presidential popularity; length of presidential term;

13

economic context; growth of government size; growth of government structural complexity; etc.

Another research strategy is social network analysis of the relationship between presidents and

their staff, in which the frequency, nature, and volume of interactions among presidents and

different types of staff indicate the importance of each staff type in decision-making processes,

and enable the reconstruction of presidential managerial styles and their application to specific

policymaking processes or decisions.

Understanding the functioning, characteristics and capabilities of the inner circle that

surrounds the president is very relevant as it would shed light first on the incentives that

presidents face. Presidents who have incentives for the generation of long-term policies would

tend to surround themselves with a different inner circle than those who are more interested in

short term political survival. Similarly, presidents who come from strong partisan structures

would tend to have a different inner circle than those with no party ties. Second, such an

understanding would also provide insights on the type of policies and the type of bargaining the

president may be able to engage in. Presidents with a small but necessarily thematically broader

inner circle may be able to engage in different negotiations than those with broader but more

specialized groups.

Table 1 summarizes the findings of the US literature, the evidence available for Latin

America, and the research questions emerging from the knowledge gap.

14

Table 1. State of the Art and Research Agenda on the Presidential Center

Topic United States Latin America Research Agenda Emergence Bargaining Paradigm:

reduction of information asymmetries to protect

bargaining power Leadership Paradigm:

centralization of decision-making

No data

Countries with presidential

centers Conditions for presidential

center emergence

Composition Types of staff: increasing complexity in response to

increasing scope of government activity

Staff sizes: unstable due to partisan turnover,

organizational instability, administrative overhaul,

and changing specialization

Staff types in Argentina and Chile

Staff structures in Chile

Staff types

Staff structures Cross-country and cross-

presidency variations

Relationship to President Contingent on leadership styles: competitive,

hierarchical, collegial Contingent on staff

specialization: outreach, policy processing, coordination and

supervision Contingent on staff

involvement: director, facilitator, monitor

Leadership style in

Argentina

Staff specialization and staff involvement in Chile

Leadership styles

Forms of staff involvement

Staff specialization Cross-country and cross-

presidency variations

2.2.The Cabinet 2.2.1 Overview The role of the cabinet within the executive branch in presidential systems of government has

experienced a paradoxical development: while on the one hand the number, size, and policy

responsibilities of cabinet ministries have grown over the past decades, on the other hand their

participation in decision-making processes has been increasingly contested by the presidential

center and by presidents themselves. These tendencies, empirically substantiated for the United

States but hardly at all for Latin America, have been explained by the combination of

governmental responses to environmental demands and the informational and political incentives

of presidents to enhance control over decision-making.

The composition of the US cabinet has gained complexity at the levels of structure and

staff types. As noted by Campbell (2005: p. 254), the cabinet evolved from three departments in

15

1789 (State, Treasury and War), to nine by 1903 (adding Agriculture, Commerce, Labor,

Interior, Navy, and Justice), and 15 by 2002 (substituting Defense for War and Navy, and adding

Education, Energy, Health, Homeland Security, Housing, Transportation, and Veteran Affairs).

The creation of new departments was overwhelmingly due to Democratic presidents—who also

created the largest number of inter-departmental councils, boards, and task forces (Ragsdale and

Theis, 1997: pp. 1292-1295)—although the latter two departments mentioned above were

created during Republican administrations. Thus, the structure of the cabinet has been taken to

reflect both environmental pressures and ideological preferences for increased governmental

activity (ibid.). Based on the recent assignment of some policymaking responsibilities to the vice

presidency, some authors also include this office as part of the cabinet structure (Baumgartner

and Evans, 2009), although the actual participation of vice presidents in decision-making has

experienced significant variations across and even within each presidency.

This evolution has increased the complexity of the cabinet as a set of organizations within

the executive. The reason for this, as scholars have noted, is that not all cabinet departments are

created equal (Rudalevige, 2002: p. 93). Research has distinguished between inner and outer

departments (Cronin 1975; Cohen, 1988). The former—i.e., State, Treasury, Defense, and

Justice—tend to have broad and expanding missions and work closer to presidents than do outer

departments; their performance is generally considered critical to the assessment of any

presidency. The latter—i.e., the remaining departments—usually have more specialized missions

and work closer to interest groups and constituencies than to presidents; their performance is

only assessed as relevant contingent to the weight each president’s program gives each policy

area. Functional differentiation and political differentiation thus intersect in determining the

nature of the United States cabinet.

This combination of functional and political criteria in the development of the cabinet has

also shaped the types of staff that make up departmental leadership and ranks. On the one hand,

inner and outer cabinet members have been found to possess different profiles: while the former

tend to be specialists or personal confidants of presidents (Riddlesperger and King, 1986), the

latter are usually either party activists or individuals with backgrounds in related interest groups

(Cohen, 1988). On the other hand, the politicization of cabinet departments has reached not only

the chief executive officer level but also the policy and support layers—to the point that “one has

16

to bore down four levels below the secretary before reaching strata populated almost entirely by

career officials” (Campbell, 2005: p. 258).

These patterns have been explained, just like the composition of the presidential center,

as outcomes of presidential attempts to cope with information asymmetries and enhance control

over policymaking. Information asymmetries arise from the inevitable fact of functional

differentiation between the presidency and the cabinet departments, and from the position of

departments as agents with multiple principals—namely the president, Congress, and interest

groups. As Weingast (2005: p. 313) has commented on the bureaucracy, cabinet departments are

also “in the middle”: they are located under presidential authority in the executive branch, but

have been created by and receive their funding and mandates from Congress; they serve at the

pleasure of the president to implement government policy but frame policy alternatives in such a

way that they preserve their own turf by pleasing related interest groups. Consequently,

presidents cannot ignore the perils of departmental capture by the particularistic interests of

bureaucrats and socioeconomic constituencies, nor can they risk letting cabinet secretaries freely

propose legislation to Congress, where they can collude with specialized committees also

potentially captured by particularistic interests (Light, 1999: p. 223). The appointment of

political allies and confidants to cabinet positions and the politicization of increasingly deeper

layers of departmental ranks help presidents reduce information asymmetries and assert control

over decision-making processes.

Presidential concerns with information asymmetries and control over policymaking thus

also seem to have affected the stability of cabinet members and the role of departments in

decision-making. As for stability, while only slightly over 50 percent of cabinet secretaries in the

United States completed a full presidential term or more between 1789 and 1989 (Nicholls,

1991), this percentage rose significantly in the 1990s (81.3 percent and 66.7 percent in each

Clinton term) and 2000s (87.5 percent and 65.2 percent in each of G.W. Bush’s terms) which

would reflect the upside of politicizing the cabinet and controlling policymaking from the

presidency (Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson, 2010). However, the increasing use since

the 1960s of inter-departmental bodies as forums to develop and discuss policy alternatives has

in effect limited the ability of cabinet secretaries to influence decision-making (Hult, 1993).

Councils, task forces and presidential commissions have effectively undermined the authority of

cabinet secretaries by carving departmental subunits for specific purposes, pitting them against

17

presidential center and extra-governmental advisers, and shifting their staff from one function to

another within policymaking processes (ibid; also Ponder, 2000). Therefore, as scholars have

consensually concluded, there is no such thing as cabinet government in the United States.

2.2.2 Evidence in LAC Research on presidential cabinets in Latin America has grown considerably in recent years, but

this growth has been uneven and accumulated knowledge is still incipient. Studies have focused

mostly on the composition and stability of cabinets. In contrast, little research exists on the

relation between presidents and cabinets, or on the participation of cabinet ministers in decision-

making processes.

The composition of presidential cabinets has been studied on three dimensions: their

partisan makeup; the types of staff recruited; and their structure. The bulk of this research is

concentrated on partisan makeup. Scholars have established that coalitions are the most frequent

form of cabinet composition in Latin America. In comparative work on Argentina, Bolivia,

Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Mexico, Panama, Peru, Uruguay and Venezuela,

Amorim Neto (2006) showed that 76 percent of cabinets between 1978 and 2004 were either

majority or minority coalition cabinets. Working from practically the same list (merely replacing

Panama with Paraguay), Martínez-Gallardo (2005, 2010a) showed that coalition cabinets were in

place 52 percent of the time between 1982 and 2003, while Chasquetti (2008) finds coalition

cabinets in 41 percent of all governments in the sample between 1978 and 2006. All cabinets in

the present democratic periods of Brazil and Chile have been coalition cabinets; in Bolivia,

Colombia, Peru, and Uruguay this has been the case between 80 and 91 percent of the time

(ibid.). Majority coalition cabinets have been more frequent in Brazil, Chile, Colombia, and

Uruguay (Amorim Neto, 2006) while single-party majority cabinets are the least frequent form,

prevalent only in Mexico (ibid.). These patterns have been explained as the joint outcomes of the

size of presidents’ legislative contingents, the number of parties in the legislatures, and the

formal lawmaking powers of presidents: coalition cabinets appear as more frequent when

presidents have minority status, face a large number of legislative parties, and have strong

lawmaking powers (Zelaznik, 2001; Amorim Neto, 2006; Martínez-Gallardo, 2005, 2010a).

The types of staff recruited for cabinet positions have been studied on three dimensions:

their partisanship; their background; and their gender. On partisanship, Amorim Neto’s (2006)

18

data showed an average of 78.2 percent of partisan ministers, with peaks of over 92 percent in

Argentina, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Mexico and Uruguay, and lows of less than 60 percent

in Brazil, Ecuador, Peru and Venezuela. The share of partisan ministers appears to be correlated

with the cabinet’s coalescence rate—i.e., the extent to which the partisan makeup of the cabinet

is consistent with the partisan distribution of seats in the legislature. Again according to Amorim

Neto (2006), average coalescence rates—which vary from 0 (no coalescence) to 1 (perfect

coalescence)—have been above 0.85 in Argentina, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica and Mexico, and

below 0.60 in Brazil, Ecuador, Peru and Venezuela. These patterns have been explained as

outcomes of the “presidential calculus” (ibid.): presidential decisions on the partisan makeup of

cabinets are contingent on the strength of executive lawmaking powers, the size of the

president’s legislative party, the president’s party discipline, the ideological position of the

president vis-à-vis legislators, the elapsed length of the term, and the economic conditions of the

country. The share of partisan ministers and the cabinet coalescence rate should be higher when

presidents’ parties control the legislative majority, are only beginning their terms in office, and

enjoy strong lawmaking powers.

On the background of cabinet ministers, comparative work on Argentina, Chile,

Colombia, Costa Rica and the United States (Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson 2009,

2010) has shown that relevant education or work experience, political insider experience, and

known links to ministry clients are the most important traits for ministerial recruitment. Relevant

education or work experience oscillates between 89.6 percent of ministers in the US and 75.3

percent in Colombia; political insider experience weighs the most in Argentina (63.1 percent of

ministers) and Costa Rica (58.1 percent) and the least in Chile (48.9 percent) and Colombia (42

percent); while links to ministry clients are more important in the US (48.1 percent) and

Argentina (45.9 percent) and least in Chile, at 36.2 percent (Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-

Robinson, 2010: p. 31). Most ministers have primary careers in government in Argentina (67.5

percent), Chile (68.1 percent) and the US (59.7 percent), while primary careers in business are

more relevant in Costa Rica (43.7 percent), and friendship with the president is more relevant in

Argentina (40 percent) than anywhere else (ibid). On gender, the same authors found the highest

shares of female ministers in Chile (35.1 percent) and Costa Rica (24.7 percent), and the lowest

in the United States (18.2 percent).

19

The structure of the cabinet is the least researched dimension of cabinet composition. The

small amount of comparative data available (Martínez-Gallardo 2010a) shows significant

variation in the number of portfolios across countries, from nine in Paraguay in 2008 to 27 in

Venezuela during the same year. Within-country variation has also been established as large for

Bolivia (IDB, 2006) and less so for Brazil (Inacio, 2006) but not for Argentina (Molinelli et al.,

1998). Twelve Latin American countries have a ministerial position with cabinet coordination

responsibility: in some countries it is defined constitutionally (Argentina, Peru) or legally

(Bolivia, Chile, Honduras, Venezuela); in others (Brazil, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico) it is

located within the presidential center; and yet in others (Guatemala, Nicaragua) it is assigned to

the vice president. Complete data collection and explanation of these stylized facts are still

pending.

Cabinet stability has been investigated considering the duration of both cabinets and

ministers. Cabinet duration appears to be lower in Latin America than in the United States:

Amorim Neto’s (2006) data shows an average of 2.6 years for Latin American cabinets,

compared to 4 years for US cabinets. Cabinets survive longer than average in Argentina, Chile,

Costa Rica, Mexico, Uruguay and Venezuela, and less in Bolivia, Brazil, Colombia, Ecuador,

Panama and Peru (ibid). These patterns have been explained as outcomes of the presidential

party’s legislative status, the share of partisan ministers and the cabinet’s partisan makeup:

cabinets last longer if the president holds a legislative majority, there is a high share of partisan

ministers and a single-party makeup (Amorim Neto, 2006).

Ministerial duration varies considerably across Latin American countries. Measured in

months by Martinez-Gallardo (2010c), ministers last an average 19.8 months, with Argentina,

Chile, Costa Rica, Mexico, Paraguay and Uruguay above average, and Bolivia, Brazil,

Colombia, Ecuador, Peru and Venezuela below average. Measured in years by Escobar-Lemmon

and Taylor-Robinson (2010), ministers serve longer in the United States (3.6 years) than in Latin

America (2.2 years). These patterns have been explained as joint outcomes of the occurrence of

economic or political shocks, the president’s popularity, the electoral cycle, and the president’s

reactive and proactive institutional powers (Martínez-Gallardo, 2010c); and as determined by the

backgrounds of ministers (Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson, 2010). Thus, ministers have

been found to serve longer if inflation and political conflict are low, economic growth,

presidential popularity, and elections proximity are high, and institutional powers strong

20

(Martínez-Gallardo, 2010c); and if they are linked to ministry clients—whereas political,

education or work experience do not increase tenure (Escobar-Lemmon and Taylor-Robinson,

2010).

There is practically no research on the relationship between presidents and cabinet

ministers in Latin America. There are some case studies of presidential administrations that

contain accounts of conflicts between presidents and finance ministers and/or between finance

ministers and the rest of the cabinet (Palermo and Novaro, 1996; Corrales, 2000, 2002; Altman,

2000; Mayorga, 2001; Novaro, 2001; Lanzaro, 2001), but no systematic dataset or account of

presidential-ministerial interaction exists so far.

The role of the cabinet in decision-making processes is also understudied. Martínez-

Gallardo (2010a: 121-122) claims that ministers have “a near-monopoly” in policy design, are

charged with steering presidential bills through Congress, and enjoy a central position in the

implementation stage. Ministers would dominate policy design due to the greater expertise at

their disposal vis-à-vis legislators; they would actively push executive bills through the

legislative process by defending them in committees and controlling amendments at both the

committee and the floor stages; and they would lead implementation by heading their own

agencies and exercising their rulemaking capacity—which is both inherent to their office and

frequently aided by explicit congressional delegation (ibid.). However, no empirical evidence has

been hitherto provided on any of these claims.

Consequently, important research questions remain unanswered. What is the nature of the

portfolios included in Latin American cabinets? Under what conditions has each portfolio

emerged or disappeared? How is the cabinet organized: in functionally differentiated portfolios,

in inter-departmental councils, or both? How is authority distributed within cabinets: is it

institutionally wielded by a coordination portfolio, concentrated in the president, or informally

assigned by the president to one or more ministries? What are the formal and effective powers of

ministers? In what ways are cabinet departments involved in policymaking? How do ministers

relate to the presidential center and its staff? How do presidents manage relations between the

presidential center and cabinet departments? What is the structure of decision-making within the

cabinet and within the ministries? In what ways do presidents intervene in cabinet deliberations

and internal ministerial decision processes? To answer these questions, as in the case of the

presidential center, two types of information would be required and two different research

21

strategies would be adequate for treating that information. On the information side: a) legal and

administrative instruments depicting the organization of cabinets and ministries and its evolution

through time, the formal powers of ministries and their subordinates, the formal powers of

presidents vis-à-vis ministers, and the scope of policy responsibilities of presidents, cabinet

departments, and the presidential center; b) quantitative and qualitative information on the

frequency and nature of interactions among presidents, ministers, and presidential center staff,

forms of involvement of ministries in decision-making processes, turnover rates, etc. On the

research strategy side: a) quantitative treatment of interactions between the aforementioned data

and standard factors used as independent variables in coalition research—such as legislative

strength of the president’s party, formal powers of the president, presidential popularity, length

of presidential term, economic context; b) social network analysis of interaction among

presidents, ministers, and presidential staff.

The relevance of studying cabinets and their role in the policymaking is almost

straightforward to understand from the previous analysis. Cabinet ministers have under their

control most policy initiatives and implementation and control the execution of a large part of

public monies. As such, understanding who they are, how they relate among each other, with the

president, and with the other political actors, and what their incentives are makes it possible to

understand how policies tend to be decided, approved and implemented. Moreover, that

understanding also posits the constraints that the political system may impose on the presidency.

Necessarily by construction, large coalition governments would tend to have more restrictions

than smaller and more cohesive cabinets. Finally, again, understanding the composition of the

cabinet allows understanding better the incentives of the president. Who he chooses, how long

he keeps them in their posts and how much power he gives them go a long way toward

explaining what type of policies the president may be willing and able to pursue.

Table 2 summarizes the findings of the US literature, the evidence available for Latin

America and the research questions emerging from the knowledge gap.

22

Table 2. State of the Art and Research Agenda on the Cabinet

Topic United States Latin America Research Agenda Composition Evolution: functional and

political differentiation Staff types: inner/outer

members and politicization as attempts to overcome information asymmetries

and enhance control

Partisan makeup: majority of coalition governments Staff types: majority of partisan ministers, but

contingent to “presidential calculus”; majority of political insiders with government careers

Structure: significant cross-country variation in

number of portfolios; generalized presence of coordination ministry

Nature and evolution of portfolios

Cabinet structure Ministerial authority

Stability Increasing ministerial stability

Increasing number of para-ministerial consultation

bodies

Cabinet: lower duration than in US; contingent to

legislative status of presidential party, share of

partisan ministers, and coalition makeup

Ministerial: significant cross-country variation contingent to shocks,

presidential popularity, electoral cycle, and

president’s institutional and partisan powers

Participation in Decision-Making

Decreasing ministerial participation

Increasing participation of task forces and special

commissions

Relation to presidents: case studies of president-finance minister relations

Domination in policy design and

implementation, but empirically

unsubstantiated

Forms of staff involvement

Relation to presidential center

Presidential management styles

2.3. Advisory Networks

2.3.1 Overview

Presidential advisory networks are groups of individuals, organizational units and subunits linked

to presidents through the provision of advice for their decisions (Hult, 1993: p. 113). The study

of advisory networks is premised on the idea that interaction among network members may

affect “the nature and timing of the advice a president receives, the president’s views on the

credibility and importance of that advice, and the impact of the advice on presidential decisions

and decision outcomes” (ibid.). Research on presidential advisory networks in the United States

23

has focused on the composition of those networks, their operation, and their effects on

presidential decision-making.

The composition of advisory networks has been studied on two dimensions: the nature of

their members, and the stability of their membership. Approaches to network membership have

been either organizational or interactional. Organizational approaches have focused on the

specific organizational units and subunits involved in particular networks—stressing how their

mandates, information, working routines, and linkages to other actors such as Congress and

interest groups shape the advice they produce and their clout on presidential decisions. Stemming

from Allison’s classic work on the Cuban missile crisis (Allison, 1971), this approach has been

used primarily for the study of foreign policy decision-making, particularly in crisis situations

(Janis, 1972, 1982; Kozak and Keagle, 1988; Burke and Greenstein, 1989; ‘t Hart, 1994; ‘t Hart,

Stern and Sundelius, 1997; Preston, 2001). The main finding of these studies is that the

composition of networks involves crucial tradeoffs for presidents to maintain control of decision-

making. If networks are staffed solely with policy area specialists, presidents would most likely

received biased information designed to protect policy turfs and hide previous bad choices or

least-preferred alternatives of departments and bureaucrats. If networks are staffed with units of

various areas and different mandates, information and advice would be more diverse, but two

opposite dynamics may complicate decision processes: either the pressure to produce decisions

by consensus building may lead to “groupthink” and its pathologies of information filtering,

misrepresentation, and denial of alternatives and potentially bad consequences or outcomes; or

the competition between units for dominance over decision outcomes may force the president to

invest excessive time and energy in the process (Rudalevige, 2005: p. 340). Presidential choices

for advisory network membership are thus critical to networks’ influence on decision-making

and outcomes.

Interactional approaches to network membership have defined individual advisers, rather

than organizations, as their units of analysis, and have categorized them according to their level

of access to the president. Based upon presidential schedules and diaries, scholars (Best, 1988a,

1988b; Thompson, 1992; Link, 2002) have established the volume of interactions between

presidents and advisers and, on this basis, determined the existence of different adviser types

according to the distance between their formal positions in government and their effective

positions in presidential advisory networks. Link’s study of advisory networks in the Nixon and

24

Carter Administrations found three types of network members: inner-core advisers, with

extraordinary—i.e., one standard deviation greater than the mean—access to the president’s

time; outer-core advisers, with above-average but less than standard deviation access levels; and

peripheral advisers, with below-average levels of access (Link, 2002: pp. 251-252). This

categorization of advisers makes it possible to pinpoint the influence of particular individuals

and organizations (as represented by individuals) on presidential decisions by weighing their

frequency of interactions with the president, the length of their paths to the president’s attention,

and the precise timing of their presence before the president for the presentation and discussion

of specific information or alternatives, and the making of concrete decisions.

The stability of network membership has also been studied from the organizational and

the interactional perspective. Organizational studies have concentrated on the survival of

organizational units and on variations in presidents’ use of those units within decision-making

processes (Porter, 1980; Burke and Greenstein, 1989; Ragsdale and Theis, 1997), whereas

interactional analyses have stressed the turnover of each adviser type (Link, 2002). Network

stability has been explained from the organizational perspective as the outcome of presidents’

managerial styles: turnover would be high under competitive styles (Dickinson, 1997) and less so

under collegial styles—though staff shifting to different functions in the policy process may also

yield high turnover in these cases (Ponder, 2000). From the interactional perspective, turnover

rates seem to be determined by overload: since presidents are forced to deal with an increasingly

growing number of problems throughout their term, their engagement in parallel processing of

issues forces them to limit the number of advisers they contact, and to seek only those who can

quickly provide information and solutions that are easy to understand and implement (Link,

2002: p. 253). High turnover rates of network members may therefore be construed as

indications of greater adaptability of presidents to changing decision settings, or as signals of

presidential difficulties in handling complex environments and simultaneous challenges.

The operation of presidential advisory networks has been studied on three dimensions:

decision procedures; conflict among network members; and the effects of both on presidential

decision-making. Decision procedures have been found to change according to context and issue.

Routine decision contexts typically involve deliberation and decision-making by cabinet

members and top-level bureaucrats which presidents subsequently sanction; whereas

extraordinary contexts such as crises or unexpected events typically lead to direct presidential

25

involvement—either through hierarchical arrangements with heavy reliance on the presidential

center, or adjudicative rules by which advisers provide competing advice and presidents decide

(Hult, 1993; Walcott and Hult, 1995). Foreign policy issues are typically settled through

competitive and collegial decision-making in which presidents encourage adversarial

deliberation among agencies with subject matter expertise such as the National Security Council,

State Department, Defense Department, and CIA. In contrast, domestic policy issues, particularly

social policy, are generally discussed by inter-departmental councils and subjected to multiple

advocacy procedures (George, 1972) whereby all concerned agencies and even outside parties

such as interest groups voice their position—typically with some cabinet secretary or top

presidential aide acting as an “honest broker” charged with laying down all the information and

choices. These variations have been explained as outcomes of the diverse incentives of network

members. Presidents must contend with various powerful actors in the course of governing, so

they are chiefly motivated to do so effectively and to bequeath a legacy that secures their place in

history (Moe, 1993). These incentives lead presidents to maximize the chances to push their

agenda through, and since campaigning consumes most of their time and energies they typically

have little in the way of ideas and resources to develop policy agendas upon inauguration. They

must therefore eventually rely on the institutional sources available: cabinet departments,

Congress, interest groups, think tanks (Light, 1999: p. 83). This opens a window of opportunity

for policy entrepreneurship by career bureaucrats and cabinet secretaries, as well as for

influential congressional leaders—all of whom compete for agenda setting and program

jockeying, especially on domestic issues (Light, 1999: p. 158).

Conflict within advisory networks has been studied as a consequence of members’

incentives, problem overload, presidential inattention, and decision cycles. Presidential

incentives to maximize control over decision-making clash with bureaucratic turf protection,

Congressional interest on credit-claiming for politically promising issues, and departmental

policy entrepreneurship (Volden, 2002; Epstein et al., 2008). Problem overload may lead to

inefficient information processing and biased deliberation (Light, 1999), high network turnover

rates (Link, 2002), and ultimately inadequate choices. Presidential inattention, either to specific

issues or to tensions among network members, may lead to domination of decision processes by

powerful actors or agencies, decision gridlock, and “traffic jams” in policy processing due to

“underdirected participants” (Helmer, 1981, quoted in Hult, 1993). Finally, conflicts within

26

advisory networks tends to increase in the course of each term as presidents either become

focused on their reelection campaign or lose power as lame ducks (Light, 1999).

2.3.2 Evidence in LAC There is no comparable literature on presidential advisory networks in Latin America. A handful

of studies have analyzed the role of economists in policymaking process—particularly

particularly during the structural reforms of the 1990s (Markoff and Montecinos, 1993; Centeno

and Silva, 1998; the works recently compiled in Montecinos and Markoff, 2009) but mostly via

case studies, without systematic datasets and unrelated to network analytic perspectives. An even

smaller literature on the diffusion of policy ideas (Madrid 2003, 2005; Weyland, 2007) has

developed comparative analyses of the role of policy networks in the spread of pension reforms

throughout Latin America using network concepts, but these works generally do not deal with

the interaction between presidents and advisory networks.

There is therefore a considerable research agenda still pending. To what extent do

presidents in Latin America employ advisory networks? For what policy issues or areas do they

employ those networks? What is the composition of presidential advisory networks? How stable

is this composition, and if unstable, how does it vary? What explains the emergence, duration,

and demise of advisory networks? How are authority and power distributed among network

members? How does decision-making operate within advisory networks? How do presidents

manage conflict among advisory network members? To answer these questions, legal and

administrative information is needed on the level of institutionalization, formal powers, and

evolution of presidential advisory networks and their members, and quantitative information on

the frequency and nature of interactions and conflicts among network members is also required.

The most adequate research strategy to treat this information would be social network analysis,

focused on describing the structure and evolution of presidential advisory networks, the network

structures and relational contents more conducive to conflict and cooperation, and the managerial

strategies with which presidents deal with those networks.

Table 3 summarizes the findings of the US literature, the evidence available for Latin

America, and the research questions emerging from the knowledge gap.

27

Table 3. State of the Art and Research Agenda on Presidential Advisory Networks

Topic United States Latin America Research Agenda Composition Member types: policy

specialists, political advisers, or mix;

specialized area units or diverse units; inner/outer

core advisers and peripheral advisers

Stability: lower under competitive than collegial

styles; contingent to overload

Case studies of participation of economists

in government

Composition Stability

Emergence, duration, demise

Staff turnover

Operation Decision procedures: contingent to context and

issue area Conflict: presidential incentives to enhance

control clash with bureaucratic turf

protection, congressional credit-claiming, and departmental policy

entrepreneurship

Case studies of participation of economists

in government and comparative studies on

diffusion of policy ideas

Decision procedures Frequency of employment

Issue areas Presidential management

Effects of Presidential Decision-Making

Contingent on network composition and

presidential managerial styles

Comparison of outcomes with work by ministries and presidential center

3. The Resources of the Presidency

The study of the resources of the presidency is another topic to which the literature on the US

presidency has made significant contributions. These contributions are focused on specific

organizational resources: the president’s power to appoint officials to the bureaucracy; the

presidency’s capacity to supervise and clear the production of executive norms and legislative

proposals prepared by cabinet departments and bureaucratic agencies; and the presidency’s

power to command and control the budgetary process. Some of the latter research has been

replicated for Latin America, supplemented by studies on presidential control over

intergovernmental transfers. The literature has accounted for these presidential resources as tools

that facilitate the politicization of the bureaucracy and the centralization of decision-making

processes in the presidency, and has generated important findings about the conditions under

which these resources are typically used. This section reviews the research on each of these

resources and highlights the questions pending for investigation in Latin American countries.

28

3.1. Appointment Power 3.1.1 Overview In presidential systems of government the executive branch is typically endowed by the

constitution or other organic legislation with the power to appoint the staff of cabinet

departments and other executive agencies. Apart from certain positions that typically require

legislative confirmation—such as cabinet secretaries in the United States, or ambassadors,

military commanders, and chief officers of important executive agencies like central banks in

most countries—presidents are free to exercise their appointment power elsewhere in the

bureaucracy. The presidential appointment power has therefore been studied on two dimensions:

its usages; and the determinants of those usages.

Studies on the uses of appointment power concur on the intensity with which presidents

resort to it, but differ on the rationale, the extent, and the effects of its use. On the rationale

underpinning the use of appointment powers, some scholars argue that presidents seek to

increase the neutral competence of the bureaucracy—i.e., the provision of unbiased information

and independent advice on policy choices (Heclo, 1975; Light, 1999), while others contend that

appointment powers are used to generate a responsive bureaucracy—i.e., one politically aligned

with presidents and ready to implement their programs and follow their lead (Moe, 1993; Moe

and Wilson, 1994). According to the latter, in their search for responsiveness presidents use

political appointees to either centralize policymaking in the presidency or politicize the

bureaucracy: centralization would be the consequence of appointees at agency or departmental

head levels deferring to presidential rather than departmental views; politicization would be the

consequence of neutralizing the clout of career bureaucrats by positioning loyalists where

information is produced and policy choices are framed (ibid.; also Dickinson, 2002: p. 251).

These strategic rationales—centralization and politicization—can complement (Moe and Howell,

1999) or substitute for each other contingent on the legacy of centralization and politicization

each president inherits: “if a function is satisfactorily centralized, politicizing its locus in the

wider bureaucracy seems like a waste of resources; likewise, if a bureau is sufficiently

politicized, it should carry out presidential preferences without the additional costs of

centralizing the process” (Rudalevige, 2009: p. 17).

The extent to which appointment powers may politicize or centralize the bureaucracy has

been studied in terms of both the growth of appointees and the specific appointment techniques

29

employed by presidents. Some scholars have substantiated the politicization of the bureaucracy

by pointing to the overall growth of political appointees since the creation of the EOP (Pfiffner,

1987; Maranto 1993; Light, 1995; Durant and Warber, 2001; Dickinson, 2005): while

employment in the federal bureaucracy may have decreased, the tendency towards EOP staff

growth has been consistent since the 1940s—and and as the EOP is the backbone of the

presidential center, then EOP staff growth would signal an increase in political appointees and

therefore an increase in politicization of the bureaucracy. Others scholars have shown that

appointment techniques enable presidents to politicize not merely the managerial level, but also

the policy development, implementation and support levels of agencies (Campbell, 2005; Lewis,

2005, 2008): presidents can replace top managers, create layers of politically appointed managers

with authority over career managers, add appointed ministerial staff with no statutory authority

but political influence over career managers, reorganize agencies to diminish the power of career

bureaucrats, and/or impose reductions on the workforce which eliminate career posts and thus

increase the power of appointees (Lewis 2008: pp. 32-39). The deeper the appointment

techniques carve into the bureaucratic structures, the greater the extent to which presidents may

politicize those structures.

The effects of appointment powers have been studied on two dimensions: the

centralization of decision-making processes in the presidency, and their impact on the

presidency’s ability to adapt to changing situations. Appointments would centralize decision-

making in the presidency not only by increasing the number of presidential loyalists within the

bureaucracy but also by eliciting frequent turnover among appointees—which “brings energy to

the job and rewards more supporters”—and by fostering confrontation between appointees and

careerists—which presidents would deem necessary to “getting things done” (Durant and

Warber, 2001: pp. 227-228). But the very centralization of decision-making would produce a

“loss of political sensitivity” in the presidential center itself: the enlargement and functional

differentiation of the EOP and the occupation of critical information production and policy

development positions by presidential loyalists would displace departmental and bureaucratic

information and advice, and thus incline presidents to rely on the input of a loyal staff that lacks

adequate knowledge to counsel presidents on the consequences of policy decisions (Dickinson,

2005: p. 160). Still, presidents might be able to escape this tradeoff between increased control

and decreased political sensitivity by imposing functional differentiation among their appointees:

30

some political appointments may seek only patronage objectives—i.e., satisfying specific

constituency demands and maintaining linkages with the party and congressional leaders through

which diverse information may flow towards the president—while others may seek only policy

objectives—i.e., guaranteeing that agencies align their operations with the president’s ideological

and policy agendas (Lewis, 2008).

The determinants of the political usage of presidential appointments have been studied

both from the perspectives of the bargaining and the leadership paradigms of presidential

politics. From the bargaining paradigm’s perspective, appointment powers are used to politicize

the bureaucracy when the complexity of the president’s bargaining environment increases: when

Congress passes legislation creating agencies independent from the executive or empowering

pre-existing agencies in such way as to curtail presidential influence (Epstein and O’Halloran,

1999; Epstein et al., 2008); or when societal developments and/or interest group pressures

increase expectations of presidential responsiveness (Dickinson, 2005). From the leadership

paradigm’s perspective, presidents are more likely to use appointments to politicize the

bureaucracy when a) their policy views differ from those typical within a given agency, b)

agency competence is not (likely to be) affected by politicization, and c) their party controls the

majority of Congress (Lewis, 2008: pp. 59-61). Utilizing data on political appointments across

all levels of the bureaucracy, Lewis (2008) found that presidents increase the number of

appointees when party control of the presidency shifts, rather than in second-term presidencies or

within-party transitions; employ less political appointees or decrease their number in agencies

that perform technically complex tasks; and increase politicization when they enjoy unified

government. These patterns yield more or less constant growth in political appointments, as well

as spikes in both policy and patronage appointments in liberal-leaning agencies during

conservative administrations and in conservative-leaning agencies during liberal administrations

(Lewis, 2008: pp. 139-140).

3.1.2 Evidence in LAC There is no equivalent research on presidential appointment powers for Latin America.

Consequently, a wide agenda is open on this topic. The first item in this agenda is the

identification of political appointments: How can they be distinguished from career civil service

appointments? What are the procedures for their appointment and placement within government?

31

The second item is their measurement: What is the ratio of political appointees to civil servants

within the executive branch? In what capacities are political appointees incorporated into

government: managerial, policy development, or support? Where in the executive’s

organizational structure are they located: the presidential center, the cabinet departments, or the

executive agencies? Which policy jurisdictions are more likely to be staffed with high shares of

appointees? How do the shares, positions, and location of political appointees change over time,

both within and between presidencies? What are the backgrounds of appointees? Do

backgrounds change according to the position within government to which they are assigned:

policy or patronage? The third item in this research agenda would be the uses presidents make of

appointees, i.e., in what ways are appointees involved in decision-making processes: as policy

directors, facilitators, or monitors? What types of appointees, policy or patronage, are employed

in what capacities within policymaking processes? To answer these questions, legal and

administrative information such as civil service career rules and government employment data

would be the main input, but qualitative and quantitative information on the forms of

involvement of appointees in decision making would also be required. This information should

be treated using the same strategies combined to study the presidential center and presidential

advisory networks. On the one hand, quantitative statistical analysis is needed to look for

appointment patterns and their determinants—using the size of the president’s party, divided

government, presidential popularity, and the evolution of government functions and structure as

independent variables. On the other hand, social network analysis is necessary to establish the

usages of appointees by determining their role in advisory networks and concrete decision-

making processes.

3.2. Clearance Power

3.2.1 Overview

In presidential as in parliamentary systems of government, the bulk of the executive’s

policymaking activity is not produced by the chief executive but by the cabinet departments or

other executive agencies. In presidential systems, to coordinate the production process of

legislative proposals, decrees, executive orders, and regulatory directives by those departments

and agencies, chief executives typically reserve for themselves the power to review these

32

products and decide which would be sent to Congress or implemented by the executive, and

which would be discarded or reworked within the executive branch. This is clearance power.

Studies of this presidential resource in the United States have focused on its scope, its

rationale, and its effectiveness. Clearance power was first established as budgetary clearance in

the 1920s, but later evolved to encompass legislative clearance in the 1930s (Neustadt, 1954) and

regulatory review in the 1980s (West, 2006). Budgetary and legislative clearance operate both

before and after legislative proposals are dealt with in Congress: before, by evaluating whether

the draft legislation and budget items proposed by cabinet departments and executive agencies

are “consistent with” or “in accordance with” the president’s campaign commitments and stated

legislative goals (Light, 1999: pp. 4-5); after, by assessing whether legislation approved by

Congress is in tune with the president’s program or deserves a presidential veto (Neustadt, 1954:

p. 641). Regulatory review, also known as administrative clearance, performs the same exercise

on drafts for executive orders, regulatory agency directives, and presidential proclamations—

only it adds cost-benefit analysis to the political criteria employed for legislative clearance

(West, 2006: p. 441). Clearance power has always been located in the Executive Office of the

President: in the Bureau of the Budget until 1972, and currently in its successor agency, the

Office for Management and Budget (OMB), where the Office of Legislative Reference takes up

legislative clearance and the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA) deals with

administrative clearance.

The rationale of the clearance power has been to centralize control of decision-making in

the presidency. Clearance criteria and procedures are “managerial rules that constrain agency

behavior” (Moe, 1993: p. 371) by blocking cabinet departments and other agencies from

independently advancing their own agendas in collaboration with congressional committees, and

by imposing a political line upon executive units. Thus clearance power enables presidents to

maintain administrative, policy and political consistency within their own branch: clearance

criteria allow the presidential center to control the policy and political content of executive

output, and clearance procedures centralize the information flow and decision-making processes

in order to secure content control (Moe and Wilson, 1994; Kagan, 2001).

The effects of clearance power have been characterized differently according to the type

of clearance. Legislative clearance has been deemed as effective for mediating and arbitrating

conflict among departments and agencies over policy orientations and responsibilities (Neustadt,

33

1954; Gilmour, 1971), as well as for providing presidents with an institutional memory of

executive policymaking—and hence with ideas and lessons for presidential decision processes

(Light, 1999: p. 231). Its effectiveness for centralizing control over policy content and

maximizing political alignment seems to have been more ambiguous: centralization of legislative

formulation within the executive by the presidential center, measured as the percentage of

legislative proposals led by the EOP or the president’s office, has been more or less constant

since the late 1940s, but by no means dominant in executive policymaking (Rudalevige, 2002:

pp. 82-84). Administrative clearance has also been assessed as effective for resolving conflicts

among agencies and programs (West, 2006: p. 435), as well as for “delaying, stopping,

modifying, or promoting particular regulations” (Durant and Resh, 2009: p. 584). However, its

efficacy for top-down planning or consistency among policy areas and programs has been

labeled as meager (ibid; West, 2006: pp. 448). All in all, then, the centralizing aims of clearance

power appear to have been fulfilled more in their procedural than in their substantial dimension.

3.2.2 Evidence in LAC There is no research available on the clearance power of the presidency in Latin America.

Consequently, the space is open for investigation on all its dimensions. What Latin American

executives have clearance power? Where within the executive branch is this power located: in

the presidential center or in specific cabinet ministries, such as finance or coordination? What is

the scope of clearance power: is it restricted to legislative/administrative clearance, or does it

encompass both? What are the specific capacities involved in legislative clearance power: review

of departmental legislative proposals, decree drafts and enacted legislation to prepare for vetoes,

or interpretation of the meaning and scope of enacted legislation as well? What have been the

conditions for the emergence of clearance power? What are the effects of clearance power upon

decision-making processes? To answer these questions, legal and administrative information on

clearance power is needed: specifically on its scope, location, capacities, and procedures.

Quantitative and qualitative data on the uses of clearance power would also be required:

specifically on the nature and frequency of changes introduced on legislative proposals, decree

drafts, enacted legislation, and regulatory directives; the policy areas and issues on which

clearance power is dominantly exercised; the political conditions under which the exercise of

clearance power varies in frequency, scope, and issues. Statistical treatment of this information

34

would be an appropriate research strategy: using the nature, uses and outcomes of clearance

power as dependent variables, and standard variables utilized in the analysis of budgetary

politics—size of the president’s legislative contingent, divided government, partisan distribution

of cabinet ministries, economic context—as independent variables.

3.3.Budgetary Power 3.3.1 Overview

Presidential budgetary power in the US seems to be the reverse of presidential budgetary power

in most of Latin America. While in the United States the president has no complete control over

any stage of the budgetary process, most Latin American presidents dominate the formulation,

implementation, and control of the budget, and exert significant influence on its approval by

Congress. The budgetary powers of Latin American presidents have been thoroughly described

in both their nature and effects, although the use of specific budgetary procedures remains to be

investigated.

The US president’s budgetary power is unequivocally low in both absolute and

comparative terms. In absolute terms, the president is not a dominant actor at any stage of the

budgetary process. Only in the formulation stage does the presidency exert some control over

matters, albeit not dominance: the cabinet departments and executive agencies take the lead in

proposing their own budgets, typically in close contact with the relevant congressional

committees before which they will ultimately defend them, but the president is empowered to

modify those preliminary proposals via the OMB, and thus to shape the budget bill eventually

sent to Congress (Stewart, 1989; Schick, 2007). In the approval stage, the president has no

formal power: presidents may informally bargain with congressional leaders (Beckmann, 2010),

but their leverage in those negotiations is little insofar as Congress may unilaterally reject the

president’s bill and amend its provisions almost at will (Howell, 2003). In the implementation

stage, bureaucrats—i.e., department and agency heads—have the leading role, typically shielded

from presidential influence by direct congressional delegations of power and protected by the

congressional committees with jurisdiction over each agency (Kiewiet and McCubbins, 1991;

Epstein and O’Halloran, 1999), although presidents may impound—i.e., decide not to spend—

funds and have sometimes attempted to reinstate their own budget priorities through executive

orders (Cooper, 2002). In the control stage, presidents may exert some influence through OMB’s

35

regulatory directives, but the main actors are the Government Accountability Office and the

Congressional Budget Office (Schick, 2007).

3.3.2 Evidence in LAC Among Latin American presidents, only the president of Guatemala has as weak a budgetary

power as the US president. In the formulation stage, all presidents except for those of Guatemala

and Peru can limit the expenditures of line ministries; everywhere except Bolivia, Guatemala,

Honduras, Panama, Peru and Venezuela, either the president or the finance minister has ultimate

authority over the executive’s budget proposal; and everywhere except Bolivia, Costa Rica,

Guatemala and Nicaragua the budget’s content is constrained by numerical rules such as

expenditure, deficit, or debt limits (Filc and Scartascini, 2007: pp. 165, 170). In the approval

stage, all congresses except those of Bolivia and Guatemala are restricted in their capacity to

modify the executive’s budget proposal (ibid: p. 169); in all countries except Brazil, Honduras

and Mexico the executive has a fallback outcome in case of congressional deadlock that

increases its budgetary power vis-à-vis Congress—such as execution of an actualized version of

the previous budget in Argentina, Guatemala, Paraguay, the Dominican Republic, El Salvador,

Uruguay and Venezuela; or the tacit approval of the executive’s budget bill in Brazil, Chile,

Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Panama and Peru (Payne et al., 2003). In the implementation

stage, the executive is authorized to withhold the execution of budgetary funds in Brazil, Chile,

Colombia, Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, El Salvador, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua,

Panama, and Uruguay—or to do so when legal obligations to spend have already been contracted

in El Salvador, Paraguay, Uruguay and Venezuela (Filc and Scartascini 2007: p. 171); presidents

can modify the allocation of funds approved by Congress with the sole restriction of not altering

the budgetary outcome in Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay, and Peru—or do so abiding by

constitutional restrictions in Colombia, Ecuador and Venezuela (Abuelafia et al., 2009; Alston et

al., 2009; Cárdenas et al., 2009; Mejía Acosta et al., 2009; Molinas et al., 2009; Carranza et al.,

2009; Moraes et al., 2009; Puente et al., 2009). In the control stage, presidents may dominate

congressional oversight activities contingent to their partisan power over the legislature, which

typically determines their ability to appoint members of oversight agencies, shape the oversight

agenda, and control the imposition of penalties for budgetary deviations (Bonvecchi, 2008,

2009).

36

The effects of presidential budgetary power in the US and Latin America have proven to

be contrasting. While in the United States the budgetary process has been characterized by

recurrent conflict between the president and Congress and recurrent swings between surplus and

deficit outcomes (Schick, 2007), in Latin America the trends seem to be the reverse: more

hierarchical budgetary processes marked by strong presidential power tend to produce budget

surpluses (Filc and Scartascini, 2007: 174). In addition, many works have shown the utility of

budgetary power for coalition building and maintenance throughout the region (Pereira and

Mueller, 2002; Amorim Neto and Borsani, 2004; Hallerberg and Marier, 2004; Amorim Neto,

2006; Rodríguez and Bonvecchi, 2006).

Still, some topics on the nature and use of presidential budgetary powers are still to be

researched. Where within the executive branch are budgetary powers located: in the Finance

Ministry, in the Coordination Ministry, or in the president’s hands? How exactly have budgetary

powers been used in legislative coalition-building: have they been employed to build support for

any and all legislation, or only for specific pieces? What budgetary powers have been more

utilized by presidents—the negative powers of withholding or impounding funds, or the positive

powers of augmenting and allocating funds? Under what conditions have positive and negative

budgetary powers been more used? To answer these questions, administrative information on the

location of budgetary powers and the patterns of use of specific budgetary powers and allocation

of budgetary funds would be required. This information should be treated using the standard

quantitative analyses previously employed to study budgetary politics.

3.4.Intergovernmental Transfers 3.4.1 Overview Intergovernmental transfers are not a presidential resource in the United States but they typically

operate as such in many Latin American countries. The reasons behind this fundamental

difference are rooted in the economic structure, the party system, and the balance of power

among government branches. Unlike Latin American countries, the United States combines three

traits that shape its transfer system into a congress-centered one: an uneven regional distribution

of income that strengthens local governments and socioeconomic groups who press for a

decentralized tax system with automatic intergovernmental transfers (Boix, 2003; Beramendi,

2005; Wibbels, 2005); a decentralized party system that locks in such fiscal arrangements by

37

setting a premium on the control of local over national office and thus discouraging career paths

in the national executive (Díaz-Cayeros, 2006); and a constitutional system of checks and

balances that creates separate institutions sharing powers (Jones, 1994) while simultaneously

granting the legislature exclusive rights over the power of the purse. Under such conditions,

intergovernmental transfers are not controlled by the president but established and governed by

Congress; presidents may propose regional redistribution through their budget bills, but

legislators typically allocate budgetary funds with universalistic criteria in order to maintain

cooperation within the legislature (Shepsle and Weingast, 1981; Weingast and Marshall, 1988);

and the literature on intergovernmental transfers thus focuses on pork-barreling (Weingast and

Shepsle, 1981; Cain et al., 1984; Ferejohn and Krehbiel, 1987; Evans, 1994) or party-based

models of transfer allocation (Cox and McCubbins, 1986; Dixit and Londregan, 1996). In

contrast, Latin American party systems tend to be more centralized than the US system (Jones

and Mainwaring, 2003; Jones, 2010), and the balance of power among government branches

tends to favor the executive (García Montero, 2009)—particularly in the budgetary process.

Under such conditions, given a sometimes even more uneven regional distribution of income,

intergovernmental transfers are typically in the president’s domain, and while legislatures may

be able to constrain the executive’s ability to reallocate funds among regions, presidents have

power to shape that allocation.

3.4.2 Evidence in LAC Presidential power over intergovernmental transfers has been studied along two dimensions:

their use for payment of electoral and/or governing coalitions; and their institutional use-value.

Research on transfers as resources for coalition-building and maintenance has found evidence of

such use in Argentina (Remmer and Wibbels, 2000; Gibson and Calvo, 2001; Jones, 2001;

Tommasi et al., 2001; Remmer and Gelineau, 2003; Bonvecchi and Lodola, 2010), Brazil

(Ames, 2001; Pereira and Mueller, 2002; Arretche and Rodden, 2004), Colombia (Crisp and

Ingall, 2002), Mexico (Flamand, 2006; Magaloni et al., 2007), and Peru (Schady, 2000). The

findings in this literature suggest that transfer allocations vary with the most relevant factors in

each political system: overrepresentation of poor districts and local electoral contests in

Argentina, regional clout and legislative party size in Brazil, territorial distribution of partisan

38

support in Colombia and Peru, and territorial distribution of poverty and partisan support in

Mexico.

Research on the institutional use-value of transfers, although more scarce, has shown that

the political value of intergovernmental transfers for presidents depends on the level of

discretionality they afford them. Bonvecchi and Lodola (2010: p. 8) argue that presidents “prefer

to manage transfers discretionally rather than centralizing tax revenues due to the comparatively

higher coalition-building potential of discretionary funds relative to both formulaic and

equalization transfers,” and propose a taxonomy of intergovernmental transfers based upon their

level of discretionality as measured on five dimensions that presidents may control: amount,

timing, targeting, payment, and earmarking. Using their taxonomy to re-specify previous studies

on transfer allocations in Argentina, these authors show that, unlike in extant analyses (Remmer

and Gelineau, 2003), intergovernmental transfers with high level of presidential discretionality

only boost the electoral chances of presidential co-partisans in provincial legislative elections—

whereas only non-discretionary grants tend to favor co-partisans in national and gubernatorial

elections (Bonvecchi and Lodola, 2010: pp. 20-22). These findings suggest that presidents may

use different transfers for different political purposes.

However, a lot remains to be investigated on intergovernmental transfers as presidential

resources. What are the levels of discretionality of intergovernmental transfers in the rest of

Latin American countries? How do presidents use transfers of different levels of discretionality?

In what ways, if any, does the use of different transfer types varies with electoral or legislative

coalition-building purposes? Where within the executive branch is power over transfer

distribution located? Under what conditions are intergovernmental transfers effective to entice

legislative and/or electoral support for incumbent presidents? To answer these questions, legal

and administrative information on intergovernmental transfers is required: legislation to learn the

level of discretionality of each transfer for both presidents and subnational recipients;

administrative data on the timing and recipients of transfer distribution, as well as on the

institutional format—laws, decrees, administrative decisions—employed to effect transfer

distribution. This information should be treated with the standard statistical techniques used to

study the determinants of transfer distribution: taking allocation patterns as dependent variables,

and transfer types, electoral outcomes, distribution of legislative seats and policy issues as

independent variables.

39

Table 4 summarizes the findings of the US literature on the resources of the presidency,

the evidence available for Latin America, and the research questions emerging from the

knowledge gap.

Table 4. State of the Art and Research Agenda on the Resources of the Presidency

Resource United States Latin America Research Agenda

Appointment Power Use: intense; to increase neutral competence or

responsiveness of bureaucracy; to centralize

decision-making or politicize bureaucracy

Effects: tradeoff between control and political

sensitivity Determinants:

environmental complexity, preference misalignment,

technical feasibility, unified government

Identification of political appointees and

appointment procedures Measurement of

appointees’ presence, location, capacities, and

backgrounds Participation of appointees

in decision-making Cross-country, cross-

presidency and within-presidency variation

Clearance Power Scope: budgetary, legislative, and administrative

Rationale: centralization of decision-making through criteria and procedures

Effects: centralization in procedures but not in

policy substance

Existence, location, scope, capacities, and effects of

clearance power Cross-country, cross-

presidency and within-presidency variation

Budgetary Power Not dominant at any stage Somewhat strong in

formulation, weaker in approval, slightly stronger in implementation, weaker

in control Effects: recurrent conflict with Congress and swings

between deficit and surplus

Stronger than US in all stages throughout the

region, except Guatemala Cross-country variations contingent to legislation

and partisan power Effects: increasingly

hierarchical processes and budget surpluses

Location within executive branch

Uses in legislative and electoral coalition building

Intergovernmental Transfers

Congress-centered transfer system due to uneven

regional income distribution, decentralized party system and strong

checks and balances Transfers distributed by legislators to maintain legislative cooperation

Presidency-centered transfer system with

varying levels of presidential discretionality

over transfers Transfers distributed by presidents for coalition

building

Level of discretionality of transfers across countries

Uses of different discretionary transfers for

legislative or electoral coalition building

40

4. The Impact of Executive Organization and Resources on Policymaking

The study of the effects of the executive branch organization and the resources of the presidency

on policymaking is the least developed topic in both the US and the Latin American literature on

presidential politics. In the United States, research has focused primarily on the effects of

presidential advisory networks on foreign policymaking, and only secondarily on the

consequences of presidential center organization, cabinet structure, and presidency resources on

domestic policymaking, government strategies, and public policy outcomes. In Latin America,

research is particularly scarce, and the little work available is concentrated on the role of

executive organization in government formation and survival, or on the general impact of

executive organization variables on the nature of policymaking processes and policy outcomes.

This section reviews the relevant literature with emphasis on its three most recurrent topics:

governing strategy choices, policymaking processes, and public policy outcomes. 4.1.Governing Strategy Choices 4.1.1 Overview The impact of executive organization and presidency resources on the governing strategy choices

of presidents has been investigated on two dimensions: the choice between unilateral and

legislative governing strategies, and the choice of political moves within each governing

strategy. The treatment of the executive’s organization and resources varies in both topics: they

are sometimes treated as independent variables, and other times as intervening variables.

The literature on strategy choices differs on the nature of the choices and on the rationale

underpinning choice. The distinction between a unilateral and a legislative governing strategy

appears to be determined by either the type of resources dominantly employed by presidents or

the conditions under which strategy choices must be made. Scholars of the former persuasion

argue that the use of unilateral institutional tools—such as executive orders, proclamations,

regulatory directives, vetoes or decrees—rather than reliance on congressional bills and ordinary

legislative processes (Mayer, 2001; Cooper, 2002; Howell, 2003; Amorim Neto, 2006; Howell

and Kriner, 2008), or the appointment of non-partisan rather than partisan cabinets (Amorim

Neto, 2006), indicate that presidents have chosen a unilateral governing strategy. Scholars of the

latter persuasion contend there is no clear demarcation line between unilateral and legislative

strategies: while it is certainly true that presidents sometimes act on their own against what the

41

majority of Congress wants, it is also oftentimes the case that presidents act alone executing the

will of Congress, effectively making use of shared powers stemming from congressional

delegation of authority (Bailey and Rottinghaus, 2010: pp. 2-3). Moreover, according to these

scholars the use of unilateral tools may involve reliance not only on previous bargains with

Congress, but also on bargains within the executive itself—so much so that the difference

between unilateral and legislative strategies may not actually signify “a shift between a

‘unilateral’ and a ‘multilateral’ process,” but “a change in where, and with whom, bargaining

takes place” (Dickinson, 2008: p. 296). Consequently, strategy choices would depend on the

bargaining conditions: presidents would generally prefer a unilateral strategy that maximizes

their discretion (Moe, 1993; Moe and Wilson, 1994), but the purely unilateral strategy of

discretion maximization would only obtain under unified government and perfect alignment of

preferences among president, legislators, and bureaucrats (Epstein and O’Halloran, 1999: pp.

313-314). Any other situation would require legislative governing strategies—either direct

bargaining with Congress for policies and authority, or indirect bargaining through the

bureaucracy intimately connected to the relevant congressional committees (ibid.).

Research on the rationale for choosing a governing strategy has viewed some presidential

resources as independent variables and others as intervening variables. Unilateral institutional

tools and the organizational capacities of the presidential center are typically conceived of as

independent variables: their availability would induce presidents, ceteris paribus, to adopt a

unilateral strategy (Moe, 1993; Amorim Neto, 2006). In contrast, the composition of cabinets

and the operational structure of advisory networks are typically treated as intervening variables:

non-partisan cabinets and hierarchical advisory networks would be more suitable for

implementing unilateral governing strategies because they enhance presidential control over

decision-making, whereas partisan cabinets and collegial advisory networks would be more

fitting for legislative strategies insofar as they maximize openness and consultation in decision-

making processes (ibid; Walcott and Hult, 1995). However, executive organization and

presidency resources are never conceptualized as the sole determinants of governing strategy

choices. For some scholars, these choices also depend on the distribution of preferences in the

legislature and the courts, which determine the likelihood of repeal of presidential unilateral

actions (Howell, 2003); for others, governing strategies are also chosen with an eye on economic

42

conditions, the time left in the presidential term, the number of parties in the legislature, and the

size of the president’s legislative contingent (Amorim Neto, 2006).

The literature on the political moves within each governing strategy, while consistently

treating executive organization and presidency resources as independent variables, differs on the

nature of their consequences for the implementation of each strategy. Research on unilateral

strategies stresses the fragility of unilateral tools and the collective action problems within the

executive branch that may weaken their efficacy. Decisions made by unilateral fiat may be

overturned by unilateral fiat, which strengthens the power of individual presidents but weakens

the power of the presidency to set a stable status quo (Howell and Kriner, 2008: p. 137)—unless

the status quo itself becomes stable due to the distribution of preferences in Congress and the

courts (Howell and Mayer, 2005). The implementation of unilateral strategies is typically more

complicated the more organizationally complex is the presidential center: high internal

differentiation of the presidential center increases transaction costs by increasing coordination

problems between the president and loyal appointees who, combining political alignment with

informational asymmetries, “accrue power independent of the president” (Krause, 2009: p. 77).

Research on legislative governing strategies underscores a series of tradeoffs between

resources and conditions for their effectiveness which yield cycles of presidential efficacy.

Presidents typically have more resources to design their program, set the legislative agenda, and

influence outcomes at the beginning of their terms—i.e., when they possess more political

capital, with more time and energy to attend to multiple fronts; but at the same time they have

little expertise on how to articulate their program, devise the legislative agenda, and lobby the

right congressional leaders and committees to get it passed (Light, 1999: pp. 18-19, 23, 33).

Presidents generally acquire the required expertise with time, but as midterm and presidential

elections go by they have less political capital to employ that expertise effectively—either

because their party loses seats in the midterms or they become lame ducks after reelection (ibid.).

These tradeoffs generate two cycles that constrain presidential legislative strategies: the cycle of

decreasing influence, marked by the depletion of political capital; and the cycle of increasing

effectiveness, marked by learning about how best to staff the executive organization and use the

presidency’s resources (ibid: pp. 36-39).

43

4.1.2 Evidence in LAC The investigation of governing strategies in Latin America has been circumscribed to the choice

between unilateral and legislative strategies. The works previously cited by Zelaznik (2001) and

Amorim Neto (2006) have shown that the condition for unilateral strategies to be effective is that

unilateral presidential resources be combined with enough partisan resources to withstand

legislative repeals of unilateral decisions. In contrast, Pereira et al.’s (2005) work on the use of

decrees by Brazilian presidents argues that presidential popularity and economic conditions are

the main explanatory variables of the use of unilateral governing strategies. Still, there is little

research available on the political moves within each governing strategy. How does the

organization of the executive branch affect the implementation of unilateral and legislative

strategies? In what ways does staff in the presidential center, cabinet ministers, and advisory

networks intervene in the processes of shaping unilateral and legislative moves? Which types of

presidential resources are most employed in those moves? To what extent do Latin American

presidents experience the cycles of decreasing influence and increasing effectiveness that seem

to characterize US presidential politics? To answer these questions, the paper trail behind by

legislative proposals, decrees, and other presidential directives must be reconstructed, so that the

nature and frequency of each staff type’s involvement can be assessed. The forms and frequency

of staff involvement should be treated as dependent variables, and the staff types, presidency

resources, and standard political and economic environmental factors should be used as

independent variables in statistical analyses.

4.2.Policymaking Processes

4.2.1 Overview

The impact of executive organization and presidency resources on policymaking processes has

been investigated on three dimensions: the type of policy aims and objectives; the source of

policy ideas; and the structure of policymaking processes. The literature on the US presidency

has made substantial contributions on all topics; the literature on Latin American presidencies

has focused on the latter.

The type of policy aims that presidents pursue seem to be determined by the

informational and political resources at their disposal. As for informational resources, presidents

with highly skilled advisors, highly institutionalized bureaucracies and/or highly efficient

44

clearance agencies would typically pursue marginal or incremental policy objectives in technical

or non-controversial areas (Larocca, 2006: p. 17). The rationale for this pattern is that those

informational resources work on the basis of institutional memories and standard operating

procedures, and therefore aim primarily at reproducing or amplifying the power of their own

turf; consequently, presidents predominantly advised by such organizations are discouraged from

pursuing new policies or setting bold aims for themselves. In contrast, presidents would pursue

innovative policies only in policy arenas where some “exogenous shock” has destabilized the

status quo (Miller, 1993: p. 303; Beckmann, 2010: p. 36). In such conditions, the ordinary advice

is rendered unusable because departments and agencies typically lack capacities and incentives

for adaptation, so as disorientation peaks presidents can afford to be selectively unresponsive to

departmental and interest-group pressures (Moe, 1993: p. 364). As for political resources,

presidents with more centralized control over policy formulation and more (cohesive)

congressional support would generally embark in new, large-scale programs, whereas presidents

with less control over policy formulation and less (cohesive) congressional support would most

likely take up marginal improvements in old programs or small new initiatives (Light, 1999: p.

110; Rudalevige 2002).

The sources of policy ideas have been found to vary with the transaction costs of

information and advice. Presidents must decide whether to “make or buy” information and policy

ideas in the presidential center or at the cabinet departments by weighing the relative scope and

quality of the product from each source against the challenges of maintaining control over

policymaking (Rudalevige, 2002). Departments and other expert agencies would typically

contribute “expert substantive knowledge usually unmatched in the White House staff” but little

or no political sensibility, whereas presidential staffers would typically offer “political expertise

and a single-minded devotion to the president’s interest” but no technical advice (ibid: p. 11). So

ideas will be drawn from the presidential center when political dynamics demand quick

responses and novel approaches, issues cut across departmental jurisdictions, and/or the matters

at hand do not require technically sophisticated responses: under these conditions the benefits of

maintaining control over policymaking outweigh the costs of lacking expert information or

advice (ibid: p. 12). In contrast, ideas would be drawn from cabinet departments or independent

agencies when issues are highly complex, presidential and bureaucratic preferences are aligned

either substantively or through control of departments by political appointees, or the president’s

45

party has the legislative majority: in those conditions control over policymaking is of little

concern because it is more likely guaranteed (ibid: p. 39; also Light 1999: pp. 87-89).

The structure of the policy process has been found to change with the level of

institutionalization of the presidency, the nature of presidential staff arrangements, and their

associated informational costs. Some scholars argue that the institutionalization of the presidency

has increased: a) centralization of control over policymaking by the White House staff, b)

centralization of such control in key aids within that staff, and c) the emergence within the

presidential center of behaviors and routines typical of highly institutionalized organizations: turf

wars, information withholding and manipulation, etc. (Burke, 2000: p. 35). Less institutionalized

presidencies, in contrast, would be characterized by more decentralized policy processes led by

cabinet members or agency heads, less political control by the presidential staff, and bureaucratic

routines that place leadership of policy processes in the cabinet departments and line agencies

rather than the presidential center (Durant and Resh, 2009). Other scholars contend that the

institutionalization of the presidency has generated coordination problems within the presidential

staff that hinder both the centralization of policymaking processes and their control by the

president (Krause 2004, 2009). In highly institutionalized presidential centers, presidents face a

tradeoff between staff loyalty and staff discretion: loyalty helps presidents maximize control, but

discretionary power in the hands of staffers may conspire against centralization of policymaking

(Krause, 2009: p. 83). Presidents may escape this tradeoff by maximizing staff loyalty and

minimizing staff discretion, but only to encounter another tradeoff: that between control and

information—in which maximizing control over policymaking may come at the expense of

minimizing the chances for alternative information and advice to flow towards the president’s

desk (Neustadt, 1990).

Hierarchical staff structures typically help presidents centralize policymaking processes,

but simultaneously discourage the consideration of alternative ideas and information, and make

adaptability to changing decision settings more difficult—so they would generally be more

useful when presidential agendas involve “policies that require consistency, standardization, and

reliability” (Durant and Warber, 2001: p. 229). In contrast, collegial staff structures yield

decentralized policy processes in which diverse information and ideas are considered, but

simultaneously prevent top-down control of decision-making, and still make adaptability

difficult (Hult 2000: p. 40; Walcott and Hult, 1995). Competitive staff structures, in turn, seem to

46

combine the best of both worlds: they maximize the flow of information and advice by

encouraging competition and overlapping among aids; they maximize centralization and control

of policymaking by placing presidents as ultimate deciders; and by combining maximum

diversity in information and advice with maximum decision-making authority they also

maximize adaptability to changing settings (Dickinson, 1997: pp. 224, 228). There is, however,

the risk that competitive staff structures might turn into multiple advocacy arrangements—in

which diversity of information and advice are also maximized (George, 1972) but the president’s

authority to settle disputes is weakened by legitimizing the voice of all advocates. Staff shift may

counter this risk by combining hierarchy, which preserves presidential authority, with flexible

assignments and collegial consultation, which preserve diversity of information and advice

(Ponder, 2000: p. 193). The problem is presidents are typically not free to choose their staff

structures but forced to shape them under the constraints inherent to agenda-setting in a system

of separated institutions sharing powers: the cycle of decreasing influence encourages the

adoption of hierarchical structures in order to maximize control and centralization of

policymaking at the zenith of the president’s agenda-setting power—i.e., the first year in

office—but the cycle of increasing effectiveness encourages the adoption of collegial staff

structures to compensate for the lack of expertise and ideas with which presidents generally enter

office (Light, 1999: p. 60). The countervailing incentives of these cycles would suggest that

competitive or staff shift arrangements are more suitable, but no comparative research is

available to settle the argument.

The informational costs associated with reliance on centralized or decentralized staff

structures lead presidents to make centralization a contingent rather than a permanent

policymaking arrangement. The rationale for contingent centralization stems from the aggregate

nature of presidential agendas: since the president’s program is “an aggregation of individual

proposals” (Rudalevige, 2002: p. 29) intended to deal with the country’s problems as each

president perceives them and as they come to demand presidential responses, then presidents

should assign the locus and leadership of policy formulation to either cabinet departments, the

presidential center or both, according to the type of advice required by each policy issue and

decision situation (ibid: p. 26). Thus, a centralized policy process would be preferable when

conditions require political rather than technical information and advice, such as crises that

demand urgent responses, cross-cutting issues or technically simple matters; whereas a

47

decentralized policy process would be preferable when conditions require technical rather than

political information and advice, such as technically complex issues or a decision setting marked

by preference alignment among presidents, legislators, and bureaucrats (ibid: p. 39).

4.2.2 Evidence in LAC Research on the effects of executive organization and presidency resources on policymaking

processes in Latin America has focused on the structure of those processes. Both IDB (2006:

149) and Martínez-Gallardo (2010a: pp. 138-142) have found that cabinet stability is correlated

to policy processes with high coordination, coherence, adaptability to changing environments,

and stability of structural arrangements. In addition, Martínez-Gallardo (2010b: p. 27) has shown

that the composition of cabinets is generally designed to boost presidential control of decision-

making by adapting it to shocks—such as elections, crises, etc.—that alter the relative costs of

unilateral or legislative governing strategies. However, no research exists either on the types of

policy aims or the sources of policy ideas or on the factors underpinning variations in

policymaking structures. What are the policy aims that Latin American presidents typically set

themselves? Where do policy ideas come from? How do different staff arrangements, cabinet

compositions, and advisory network memberships impact the policy aims and ideas that

presidential administrations set? What accounts for variations in the ways policymaking

processes are structured: issue areas, organizational structures, or political and economic

environmental conditions? To answer these questions, certain administrative information apart

from that on presidential centers, cabinets and advisory networks would have to be collected:

presidential messages to Congress and the general public to identify policy aims; paper trail on

the production of legislative proposals, decrees and other presidential directives to identify the

sources of policy ideas, the types of staff involved, forms of staff involvement in decision-

making and their frequency. A combination of statistical analyses and case studies should be

devised in which executive branch organizational arrangements should be treated as independent

variables, and types of ideas, sources of ideas, and forms of staff involvement in decision-

making should be treated as dependent variables.

48

4.3.Public Policy Outcomes

4.3.1 Overview The impact of executive organization and presidency resources on public policy outcomes is the

least studied topic in the presidency literature. There at least two reasons for this shortcoming.

On the one hand, conceptual problems: lack of clarity about the nature of the dependent

variable—i.e., the notion of “good” or “bad” public policy outcomes; and insufficient

conceptualization of causation between independent and dependent variables. On the other hand,

measurement problems: how to pinpoint empirically the linkage between executive organization

or presidency resources and policy outcomes. The literature on the US presidency has attempted

to overcome these problems by specifying policy types as dependent variables, and measuring

the president’s success in eliciting each type of policy. The literature on policymaking in Latin

America has specified features of the policy process as dependent variables, and explored

correlations between those features and some executive organization factors. Still, both

literatures seem far from having exhausted the topic because none appears to have developed

consistently comparative measures of the connections between executive organization variables

and public policy outcomes.

The evaluation of presidents’ public policy outcomes in the United States has revolved

around three empirical referents: foreign policy processes; presidential success in Congress; and

the effects of presidential politicization of the bureaucracy. The research on foreign policy

processes, already cited in Section 1.3, dwells mostly on case studies and small-N comparisons

crafted on such different theoretical frameworks that comparison of processes and outcomes

becomes extremely difficult and the specific assessment of executive organization variables are

typically subject to controversies of a normative, rather than empirical, nature.

The research on presidential success in Congress, in contrast, has developed comparable

concepts and measures of both dependent and independent variables. On the dependent variable,

policies have been categorized using various typologies: by objectives, as in Lowi’s (1972)

famous typology of distributive, regulatory, redistributive, and constituent policies; by salience

and complexity, as in Gormley’s (1986) typology of regulatory policies; by size and novelty, as

in Peterson’s (1990) and Light’s (1999) typologies of new/old and large/small policies; by scope,

and in Eshbaugh-Soha’s (2005, 2010) typology of major and minor policies. As independent

variables, this literature has utilized not only institutional and partisan variables—such as

49

unilateral institutional powers, divided government, size of presidential legislative party, timing

within the presidential term, and presidential popularity (Edwards, 1985; Bond and Fleischer

1990, 2008; Peterson 1990; Canes-Wrone and De Marchi, 2002; Barrett and Eshbaugh-Soha,

2007; Eshbaugh-Soha, 2010); but also organizational variables—such as the source of policy

formulation, the locus of leadership during policymaking processes, and the resources employed

to influence legislative outcomes (Light, 1999; Rudalevige, 2002: Larocca, 2006). The relevant

findings of this literature for the present discussion show a) that policies, particularly domestic

policies, tend to be smaller and less novel because presidents lack organizational and

informational resources to develop and promote other types of policies (Light,1999; Krause,

2009) except in crisis situations (Dickinson, 1997), and b) that presidents are more successful in

getting legislative approval for policies developed in a decentralized, rather than centralized,

manner—as the former implies collaboration between the presidential center, cabinet

departments and congressional committees both in policy design (Rudalevige, 2002: pp. 114,

149-150) and in shaping and pushing the agenda (Beckmann, 2010: 21, 126) more than the latter.

The problem with this literature is that the linkage between executive organization variables and

public policy outcomes is mediated by presidential success in Congress: only successful

presidential initiatives enter the assessment. This begs at least two questions: on the one hand,

what exactly would count as presidential policy success; on the other hand, how are executive

organization variables related to unsuccessful presidential initiatives. The US literature has

proposed several answers to the former question, but not to the latter: presidential success may

be measured either as support for presidential initiatives in Congress (Edwards, 1985; Peterson,

1990; Bond and Fleischer, 1990, 2008) or as presidential ability to protect the substance of

presidential legislative proposals (Rudalevige, 2002; Barrett and Eshbaugh-Soha, 2007;

Beckmann, 2010), but little is known about why or how executive organization variables

influence unsuccessful initiatives beyond the fact that decentralized policy formulation processes

fare better with legislators.

The research on presidential politicization of the bureaucracy has found that politicization

yields worse outcomes than reliance on career bureaucrats or appointees with previous

government experience. Based upon wide-coverage internal polls conducted within the federal

bureaucracy during the G.W. Bush presidencies, Lewis (2008: p. 196) has shown that programs

run by careerists or in-and-out appointees (i.e., appointees with previous government experience)

50

receive better assessments in terms of program effectiveness and managerial efficacy than

programs run by short-term, high-turnover appointees. These findings, however, are not

conceptually related to the usually employed typologies of public policies, and have not yet been

investigated beyond the Bush presidencies.

4.3.2 Evidence in LAC The research on the impact of executive organization variables on policy outcomes in Latin

America is scant and beset by similar problems. On the one hand, the dependent variable is

conceptualized not as the type of policies using any extant typology, or as the policy issue areas,

but as the features of the policymaking process (stability, adaptability, coherence, coordination)

and only marginally considering traits of policies themselves, such as public-regardedness and

efficiency (IDB, 2006). On the other hand, the only comparative data available on executive

organization variables concern cabinet composition and ministerial backgrounds. The main

findings in this literature hold that ministers with career backgrounds in the civil service produce

more stable policies (ibid: p. 149), but beyond that there are no comparatively established

patterns on the connection between executive organization, presidency resources, and policy

outcomes.

Consequently, a wide research agenda is open on this topic. Firstly, it is necessary to

establish what the policy processes for specific policy areas are and in what ways they differ.

Secondly, information about the legislative process of bills and decrees must be collected in

order to assess presidential success in advancing policy agendas, protecting their proposals from

legislative amendments, and securing consistent implementation within the executive branch.

Finally, information of the staff types involved in the drafting, bargaining, legislative steering,

and implementation of policies should be gathered in order to evaluate whether different staff

types and/or staff arrangements impact presidential legislative success and the outcomes of

public policies.

Table 5 summarizes the findings of the US literature on the effects of presidency

resources, the evidence available for Latin America, and the research questions emerging from

the knowledge gap.

51

Table 5. State of the Art and Research Agenda on the Effects of Presidency Resources

Effect on… United States Latin America Research Agenda Governing Strategy

Choices Availability of unilateral resources, non-partisan

cabinets and hierarchical networks matter for choice, but do not

determine it Unilateral strategies yield more unstable outcomes than legislative strategies Legislative strategies are

subject to cycles of decreasing influence and increasing effectiveness

Unilateral strategies require combination of unilateral resources and

enough partisan powers to withstand legislative

repeals Unilateral strategies only

effective when presidential popularity and economic

conditions are good

Effects of executive branch organization on

governing strategies Participation of

presidential center, cabinet and advisory networks in

each strategy Types of resources

employed per strategy Cycles of influence and effectiveness in Latin

American presidencies

Policymaking Processes Policy aims: marginal/incremental

when good informational resources are available or political control is low;

innovative in response to shocks or under

centralized political control

Policy sources and management: presidential

center when situations require quick responses,

cross-area issues and little technical expertise; cabinet

or agencies otherwise Structure:

centralized/decentralized when institutionalization

of presidency is high/low; centralization contingent

to informational costs Dynamics: leadership

styles and forms of staff involvement generate

tradeoffs among political control, information and

adaptability

Cabinet stability correlated

to policy processes with high coordination,

coherence and adaptability Cabinet composition

designed to boost presidential control over

processes

Types of policy aims

Sources of policy ideas Forms of staff

involvement in policy processes

Variations per issue areas, organizational structure, political and economic

conditions

Public Policy Outcomes

Policies are only novel and large-scale in response to

crises Presidential success on the substance of legislation is

higher when policy processes are decentralized

to cabinet or agencies Political appointees yield worse policy outcomes than career bureaucrats

Ministers with career backgrounds in the civil

service produce more stable policies

Nature of policy process

per issue area Forms of staff

involvement in the production of specific

types of policy outcomes Presidential success on the

substance of legislation across countries and

presidencies

52

5. Concluding Thoughts

This paper has reviewed the literature on the organization of the executive branch and the

presidential resources in the United States and Latin America. The review has shown that

research on Latin American presidencies has produced strong, region-wide findings in some

areas only, such as the composition of cabinets, the nature of budgetary powers, the choice of

governing strategies, and the features of policymaking processes. In contrast, research is

significantly lagging behind the benchmark set by the literature on the US presidency in regard

to the presidential center, the presidential advisory networks, the appointment, clearance, and

intergovernmental transfer powers of the presidency, and the effects of executive branch

organization and presidential resources on policymaking processes and public policy outcomes.

The research strategy to pursue in order to fill in the research gap varies from topic to

topic. Research on the presidential center, the powers of cabinet departments, and the

presidential advisory networks should combine statistical analysis with social network analytic

strategies: this combination would be most adequate to establish not only the determinants of

different types of staff structures and arrangements but also the nature of staff involvement in

policymaking and the frequency with which each form of involvement is mobilized by the

president. Research on presidential resources should be chiefly addressed using statistical

techniques to establish the nature, conditions of emergence, and frequency of use of each type of

resource. Finally, research on the effects of executive organization and presidency resources on

policymaking should combine statistical analysis with case studies in order to pinpoint the

determinants of governing strategies, policy aims and ideas, policymaking structures, and policy

outcomes, and trace the mechanisms by which the former variables affect the latter.

It might have been important to rank the topics that need to be addressed in order of

importance as an additional tool for guiding researchers. Still, that would be a fruitless task for

the region as a whole. Existing evidence and studies differ from country to country. The

relevance of each topic for understanding the policymaking also differs from country to country.

Consequently, those interested in broad regional studies may want to concentrate first on those

areas of research that would have broad application. For example, studying cabinets may have to

come before studying advisory networks. This may be particularly true for those studies that

want to be quantitatively focused, as data on advisory networks may prove harder to come by.

However, researchers that concentrate on a specific country may want to tackle head on the role

53

of advisory networks, particularly if they are shown to matter more. For example, recent US

evidence tends to indicate that presidents have relied more upon their inner circle than the formal

cabinet members. Similarly, may be happening in LAC countries. Without understanding who

the president chooses for conducting the most serious discussions and on whom he relies at key

junctures may otherwise provide a distorted picture.

The questions posed and the research strategies proposed on the basis of this literature

review may of course be corrected and improved upon. But the fact will remain that advancing

this research may greatly help to improve the understanding of the workings of the presidency

and the causes of its weaknesses in some of the countries in the region. It may also contribute to

understanding the ways the presidency affects policymaking and its outcomes. More importantly,

it may help reformers to identify bottlenecks and weakest links where support may be more

effective, as well as the types of reforms and strengthening programs that may be sustainable

over time. Academically, the payoff of this research agenda can also be large. While the US-

based literature has advanced at a faster pace, it is still in its infancy, particularly regarding the

use of strong quantitative and comparative analysis. Researchers taking on Latin American

executives may then be able to make a contribution that resonates beyond the Latin American-

based research network of scholars.

54

Bibliography Abuelafia, E. et al. 2009. “Who Decides on Public Expenditures? The Importance of the

Informal Budget Process in Argentina.” In: M. Hallerberg et al., editors. Who Decides the

Budget? A Political Economy Analysis of the Budget Process in Latin America.

Washington, DC, United States: Inter-American Development Bank/David Rockefeller

Center for Latin American Studies.

Alesina, A., N. Roubini and G. Cohen. 1997. Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy.

Cambridge, United States: MIT Press.

Allison, G. 1971. 1971. Essence of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis. Boston,

United States: Little, Brown.

Alston, L. et al. 2008. “On the Road to Good Governance: Recovering from Economic and

Political Shocks in Brazil.” In: E. Stein et al., editors. Policymaking in Latin America:

How Politics Shapes Policies. Washington, DC, Inter-American Development

Bank/David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies.

Alston, L. et al. 2009. “Presidential Power, Fiscal Responsibility Laws, and the Allocation of

Spending: The Case of Brazil.” In: M. Hallerberg et al., editors. Who Decides the

Budget? A Political Economy Analysis of the Budget Process in Latin America.

Washington, DC, United States: Inter-American Development Bank/David Rockefeller

Center for Latin American Studies.

Altman, D. 2000. “The Politics of Coalition Formation and Survival in Multiparty Presidential

Democracies: The Case of Uruguay 1989-1999.” Party Politics 6(3): 259-283.

Ames, B. 2001. The Deadlock of Democracy in Brazil. Ann Arbor, United States: University of

Michigan Press.

Amorim Neto, O. 2006. Presidencialismo e Governabilidade nas Américas. Rio de Janeiro,

Brazil: Konrad Adenauer Stiftung/Fundação Getúlio Vargas.

Amorim Neto, O., and H. Borsani. 2004. “Presidents and Cabinets: The Political Determinants

of Fiscal Behavior in Latin America.” Studies in Comparative International Development

39(1): 3-27.

Aninat, C., and E. Rivera. 2009. “Coordinación Estratégica en el Estado de Chile: El Centro de

Gobierno bajo la Concertación y Propuestas a Futuro.” In: V. Tomicic and C. García. Un

55

Mejor Estado para Chile: Propuestas de Modernización y Reforma. Santiago, Chile:

Consorcio para la Reforma del Estado.

Arnold, P.E. 1998. Making the Managerial Presidency: Comprehensive Reorganization

Planning, 1905-1996. Lawrence, Kansas, United States: University Press of Kansas.

Arretche, M., and J. Rodden. 2004. “Política Distributiva na Federação: Estratégias Eleitorais,

Barganhas Legislativas e Coalizões de Governo.” Dados 47(3): 549-576.

Bailey, J., and B. Rottinghaus. 2010. “Reexamining the Unilateral Politics Model: Source of

Authority and the Power to Act Alone.” Paper prepared for American Political Science

Association Annual Meeting, Washington DC, United States, September 2-5.

Barrett, A.W., and M. Eshbaugh-Soha. 2007. “Presidential Success on the Substance of

Legislation.” Political Research Quarterly 60(1): 100-112.

Baumgartner, J.C., and R. Evans. 2009. “Constitutional Design of the Executive: Vice

Presidencies in Comparative Perspective.” Congress and the Presidency 36: 148-163.

Beckmann, M.N. 2010. Pushing the Agenda. Presidential Leadership in U.S. Lawmaking, 1953-

2004. Cambridge, United States: Cambridge University Press.

Beramendi, P. 2005. “Inequality, Economic Specialization and Fiscal Decentralization.”

Syracuse, United States: Syracuse University, Department of Political Science.

Unpublished manuscript.

Best, J. 1988a. “Who Talked to the President When? A Study of Lyndon B. Johnson.” Political

Science Quarterly 103(3): 531-545.

Best, J. 1988b. “Presidential Learning: A Comparative Study of the Interactions of Carter and

Reagan.” Congress and the Presidency 15: 25-48.

Boix, C. 2003. Democracy and Redistribution. Cambridge, United States: Cambridge University

Press.

Bond, J.R., and R. Fleisher. 1990. The President in the Legislative Arena. Chicago, United

States: University of Chicago Press.

Bond, J.R., and R. Fleisher. 2008. “Which Presidents Are Uncommonly Successful in

Congress?” In: B.A. Rockman and R.W. Waterman, editors. Presidential Leadership:

The Vortex of Power. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Bonvecchi, A. 2008. “Political Determinants of Legislative Budgetary Oversight: Party System

Competitiveness and Party Cohesion in Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico.” In:

56

G. O’Donnell, J. Tulchin and A. Varas, editors. New Voices in the Study of Democracy in

Latin America. Washington, DC, United States: Woodrow Wilson International Center

for Scholars.

Bonvecchi, A. 2009. “Tipos de Presidencialismo y Efectividad del Control Legislativo sobre el

Presupuesto: Control Político y Control Técnico en Argentina, Brasil y México.” Paper

presented at VII Annual Meeting of RedGob, Salamanca, Spain, December 10-11.

Bonvecchi, A., and G. Lodola. 2010. “The Dual Logic of Intergovernmental Transfers:

Presidents, Governors, and the Politics of Coalition-Building in Argentina.” Publius

41(2): 179-206.

Bonvecchi, A., and V. Palermo. 2000. “En Torno a los Entornos: Presidentes Débiles y Partidos

Parsimoniosos.” Revista Argentina de Ciencia Política 6: 103-111.

Bonvecchi, A., and J. Zelaznik. 2010. “Recursos de Gobierno y Funcionamiento del

Presidencialismo en Argentina.” Paper delivered at the seminar “El Parlamentarismo

Europeo y el Presidencialismo Latinoamericano Cara a Cara,” Manuel Giménez Abad

Foundation of Parliamentary Studies, Cortes de Aragón, Zaragoza, Spain, March 17-18.

Burke, J.P. 2000. The Institutional Presidency: Organizing and Managing the White House from

FDR to Clinton. Second edition. Baltimore, United States: Johns Hopkins University

Press.

Burke, J.P. 2009. “Organizational Structure and Presidential Decision Making.” In: G.C.

Edwards and W.G. Howell, editors. The Oxford Handbook of the American Presidency.

Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Burke, J.P., and F. Greenstein. 1989. How Presidents Test Reality: Decisions on Vietnam 1954

and 1965. New York, United States: Russell Sage Foundation.

Cain, B.E. et al. 1984. “The Constituency Service Basis of the Personal Vote for U.S.

Representatives and British Members of Parliament.” American Political Science Review

78(1): 110-125.

Campbell, C. 2005. “The Complex Organization of the Executive Branch: The Legacies of

Competing Approaches to Administration.” In: J.D. Aberbach and M.A. Peterson. The

Executive Branch. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Canes-Wrone, B., and S. De Marchi. 2002. “Presidential Approval and Legislative Success.”

Journal of Politics 64(2): 491-509.

57

Cárdenas, M. et al. 2009. “Changes in Fiscal Outcomes in Colombia: The Role of the Budget

Process.” In: M. Hallerberg et al., editors. Who Decides the Budget? A Political Economy

Analysis of the Budget Process in Latin America. Washington, DC, United States: Inter-

American Development Bank/David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies.

Carey, J., and M. Shugart. 1998. Executive Decree Authority. Cambridge, United States:

Cambridge University Press.

Carranza, L. et al. 2009. “Success in Sustainability? The Case of Peru.” In: M. Hallerberg et al.,

editors. Who Decides the Budget? A Political Economy Analysis of the Budget Process in

Latin America. Washington, DC, United States: Inter-American Development

Bank/David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies.

Centeno, M.A., and P. Silva, editors. 1998. The Politics of Expertise in Latin America. London,

United Kingdom: Macmillan.

Chasquetti, D. 2008. Democracia, Presidencialismo y Partidos Políticos en América Latina:

Evaluando la “Difícil Combinación.” Montevideo, Uruguay: Universidad de la

República, Instituto de Ciencia Política.

Cheibub, J.A. 2002. “Minority Governments, Deadlock Situations, and the Survival of

Presidential Democracies.” Comparative Political Studies 35(3): 284-312.

Cheibub, J.A. 2007. Presidentialism, Parliamentarism and Democracy. Cambridge, United

Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

Cohen, J. E. 1988. Politics of the U.S. Cabinet: Representation in the Executive Branch, 1789-

1984. Pittsburgh, United States: University of Pittsburgh Press.

Cooper, P.J. 2002. By Order of the President: The Use and Abuse of Executive Direct Action.

Lawrence, Kansas, United States: University Press of Kansas.

Corrales, J. 2000. “Presidents, Ruling Parties, and Party Rules: A Theory on the Politics of

Economic Reform in Latin America.” Comparative Politics 32(2): 127-149.

Corrales, J. 2002. Presidents without Parties: The Politics of Economic Reform in Argentina and

Venezuela in the 1990s. University Park, Pennsylvania, United States: Penn State

University Press.

Cox, G., and M. McCubbins. 1986. “Electoral Politics as a Redistributive Game.”Journal of

Politics 48(2): 370-389.

58

Cox, G., and S. Morgenstern. 2002. “Epilogue: Latin America’s Reactive Assemblies and

Proactive Presidents.” In: S. Morgenstern and B. Nacif, editors. Legislative Politics in

Latin America. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

Crisp, B.F., and R.E. Ingall. 2002. “Institutional Engineering and the Nature of Representation:

Mapping the Effects of Electoral Reform in Colombia.” American Journal of Political

Science 46(4): 733-748.

Cronin, T.E. 1975. The State of the Presidency. Boston, United States: Little, Brown.

Deheza, G.I. 1997. Gobiernos de Coalición en el Sistema Presidencial: América del Sur,

Florence: European University Institute. Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation,

Díaz-Cayeros, A. 2006. Federalism, Fiscal Authority, and Centralization in Latin America.

Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

Dickinson, M. 2002. “Staffing the White House, 1937-1996: The Institutional Implications of

Neustadt’s Bargaining Paradigm.” In: R. Shapiro et al., editors. Presidential Power:

Forging the Presidency for the Twenty-First Century. New York, United States:

Columbia University Press.

Dickinson, M.J. 1997. Bitter Harvest: FDR, Presidential Power and the Growth of the

Presidential Branch. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

Dickinson, M.J. 2005. “The Executive Office of the President: The Paradox of Politicization.”

In: J.D. Aberbach and M.A. Peterson, editors. The Executive Branch. Oxford, United

Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Dickinson, M.J. 2008. “The Politics of Persuasion: A Bargaining Model of Presidential Power.”

In: B.A. Rockman and R.W. Waterman, editors. Presidential Leadership: The Vortex of

Power. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Dickinson, M.J., and K.D. Tenpas. 2002. “Explaining Increasing Turnover Rates among

Presidential Advisers, 1929-1997.” Journal of Politics 64(2): 434-448.

Dixit, A., and J. Londregan. 1996. “The Determinants of Success of Special Interests in

Redistributive Politics.” Journal of Politics 58(4): 1132-1155.

Durant, R.F., and W.G. Resh. 2009. “Presidential Agendas, Administrative Strategies, and the

Bureaucracy.” In: G.C. Edwards and W.G. Howell, editors. The Oxford Handbook of the

American Presidency. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

59

Durant, R.F., and A. Warber. 2001. “Networking in the Shadow of Hierarchy: Public Policy, the

Administrative Presidency, and the Neoadministrative State.” Presidential Studies

Quarterly 31(2): 221-244.

Echegaray, F. 2005. Economic Crises and Electoral Responses in Latin America. New York,

United States: University Press of America.

Edwards, G.C. 1985. “Measuring Presidential Success in Congress: Alternative Approaches.”

Journal of Politics 47: 667-85.

Epstein, D. et al. 2008. “Conditional Presidential Leadership: Pivotal Players, Gridlock, and

Delegation.” In: B.A. Rockman and R.W. Waterman, editors. Presidential Leadership:

The Vortex of Power. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Epstein, D., and S. O’Halloran. 1999. Delegating Powers: A Transaction Cost Politics Approach

to Policy Making under Separate Powers. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge

University Press.

Escobar-Lemmon, M., and M. Taylor-Robinson. 2009. “Do Cabinet Ministers in Presidential

Systems have Experience in their Portfolio or is On-the-Job Training the Norm?” Paper

prepared for delivery at the International Political Science Association Meeting, Santiago,

Chile, July 11-16.

Escobar-Lemmon, M., and M. Taylor-Robinson. 2010. “Coming or Going: How Background

Affects Duration in 5 Presidential Systems.” Paper prepared for American Political

Science Association Annual Meeting, Washington DC, September 2-5.

Eshbaugh-Soha, M. 2005. “The Politics of Presidential Agendas.” Political Research Quarterly

58: 257-68.

Eshbaugh-Soha, M. 2010. “The Importance of Policy Scope to Presidential Success in

Congress.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 40(4): 708-724.

Etchemendy, S. 2001. “Constructing Reform Coalitions: The Politics of Compensations in

Argentina’s Economic Liberalization.” Latin American Politics and Society 43(3): 1-35.

Evans, D. 1994. Greasing the Wheels: Using Pork Barrel Projects To Build Majority Coalitions

in Congress. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

Ferejohn, J., and K. Krehbiel. 1987. “The Budget Process and the Size of the Budget.” American

Journal of Political Science 31(2): 296-320.

60

Filc, G., and C. Scartascini. 2007. “Budgetary Institutions.” In: E. Lora, editor. The State of

State Reform in Latin America. Washington, DC, United States: Inter-American

Development Bank/Stanford University Press.

Flamand, L. 2006. “El Juego de la Distribución de Recursos en un Sistema Federal: La

Influencia del Gobierno Dividido Verticalmente en la Asignación de Fondos Federales a

los Estados Mexicanos.” Política y Gobierno 13(2): 315-359.

Fleisher, R. et al. 2008. “Which Presidents Are Uncommonly Successful in Congress?” In: B.A.

Rockman and R.W. Waterman, editors. Presidential Leadership: The Vortex of Power.

Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Foley, J.P., editor. 1900. The Jeffersonian Cyclopedia: a Comprehensive Collection of the Views

of Thomas Jefferson. New York, United States: Funk & Wagnalls Company.

García Montero, M. 2009. Presidentes y Parlamentos: ¿Quién Controla la Actividad Legislativa

en América Latina? Madrid, Spain: Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas.

George, A. 1972. “The Case for Multiple Advocacy in Making Foreign Policy.” American

Political Science Review 66: 751-785.

Gibson, E., and E. Calvo. 2001. “Federalism and Low-Maintenance Constituencies: Territorial

Dimensions of Economic Reform in Argentina.” Studies in Comparative International

Development 35(3): 32-55.

Gilmour, R.S. 1971. “Central Legislative Clearance: A Revised Perspective.” Public

Administration Review 31(2): 150-158.

Gormley, W. 1986. “Regulatory Issue Networks in a Federal System.” Polity 18: 595-620.

Haggard, S., and R. Kaufman. 1995. The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions.

Princeton, United States: Princeton University Press.

Haggard, S., and R. Kaufman, editors. 1992. The Politics of Economic Adjustment. Princeton,

United States: Princeton University Press.

Hallerberg, M., and P. Marier. 2004. “Executive Authority, the Personal Vote, and Budget

Discipline in Latin American and Caribbean Countries.” American Journal of Political

Science 48(3): 571-87.

Heclo, H. 1975. “OMB and the Presidency: The Problem of ‘Neutral Competence.’” Public

Interest 38: 80-98.

61

Helmer, J. 1981. “The Presidential Office: Velvet Fist in an Iron Glove?” In: H. Heclo and L.

Salamon, editors. The Illusion of Presidential Government. Boulder, United States:

Westview.

Howell, W.G. 2003. Power without Persuasion: The Politics of Direct Presidential Action.

Princeton, United States: Princeton University Press.

Howell, W.G. 2006. “Executives: The American Presidency.” In: R.A. Rhodes, S. Binder and B.

Rockman, editors. The Oxford Handbook of Political Institutions. Oxford, United

Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Howell, W.G., and D. Kriner. 2008. “Power without Persuasion: Identifying Executive

Influence.” In: B.A. Rockman and R.W. Waterman, editors. Presidential Leadership:

The Vortex of Power.Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Howell, W., and K. Mayer. 2005. “The Last 100 Days.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 35(3):

533-553.

Hult, K.M. 1993. “Advising the President.” In: G.C. Edwards et al., editors. Researching the

Presidency: Vital Questions, New Approaches. Pittsburgh, United States: University of

Pittsburgh Press: 111-160.

Hult, K.M. 2000. “Strengthening Presidential Decision Making Capacity.” Presidential Studies

Quarterly 30: 27-46.

Hult, K.M., and C.E. Walcott. 2009. “Influences on Presidential Decision Making.” In: G.C.

Edwards and W.G. Howell, editors. The Oxford Handbook of the American Presidency.

Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Inacio, M. 2006. Entre Presidir e Coordenar: Presidência e Gabinetes Multipartidários no

Brasil. Paper presented to the III Congresso Latino Americano de Ciência Política,

Campinas, Brazil, September 4-6.

Inter-American Development Bank (IDB). 2006. The Politics of Policies. Washington, DC,

United States: Inter-American Development Bank/ David Rockefeller Center for Latin

American Studies, Harvard University.

Janis, I.L. 1972. Victims of Groupthink: A Psychological Study of Foreign-policy Decisions and

Fiascoes. Boston, United States: Houghton Mifflin.

Janis, I.L. 1982. Groupthink: Psychological Studies of Policy Decisions and Fiascoes. Boston,

United States: Houghton Mifflin.

62

Johnson, R.T. 1974. Managing the White House. New York, United States: Harper and Row.

Jones, C. O.1994. The Presidency in a Separated System. Washington, DC, United States:

Brookings Institution.

Jones, M. 2001. “Political Institutions and Public Policy in Argentina: An Overview of the

Formation and Execution of the National Budget.” In: S. Haggard and M.D. McCubbins,

editors. Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy. Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge

University Press.

Jones, M. 2010. “Beyond the Electoral Connection: The Effect of Political Parties on the

Policymaking Process.” In: C. Scartascini et al., editors. How Democracy Works:

Political Institutions, Actors, and Arenas in Latin American Policymaking. Washington

DC, United States: Inter-American Development Bank.

Jones, M., and S. Mainwaring. 2003. “The Nationalization of Parties and Party Systems: An

Empirical Measure and an Application to the Americas.” Party Politics 9(2): 139-166.

Kagan, E. 2001. “Presidential Administration.” Harvard Law Review 114(8): 2245-2385.

Kiewiet, D.R., and M.D. McCubbins. 1991. The Logic of Delegation: Congressional Parties and

the Appropriations Process. Chicago, United States: University of Chicago Press.

Kozak, D.C., and J.M. Keagle. 1988. Bureaucratic Politics and National Security: Theory and

Practice. Boulder, United States: Lynne Rienner.

Krause, G.A. 2004. “The Secular Decline in Presidential Domestic Policy Making: An

Organizational Perspective.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 34: 79-92.

Krause, G.A. 2009. “Organizational Complexity and Coordination Dilemmas in U.S. Executive

Politics.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 39: 74-88.

Lanzaro, J. 2001. “Uruguay: Las Alternativas de un Presidencialismo Pluralista.” In: J. Lanzaro,

editor. Tipos de Presidencialismo y Coaliciones Políticas en América Latina. Buenos

Aires, Argentina: CLACSO.

Larocca, R.T. 2006. The Presidential Agenda: Sources of Executive Influence in Congress.

Columbus, United States: Ohio University Press.

Levitsky, S. 2003. Transforming Labor-Based Parties in Latin America: Argentine Peronism in

Comparative Perspective. Cambridge, United States: Cambridge University Press.

Levitsky, S., and K.M. Roberts. 2007. “Latin America’s ‘Left Turn’: A Conceptual and

Theoretical Overview.” In: S. Levitsky and K.M. Roberts, editors. Latin America’s Left

63

Turn: Causes and Implications. Cambridge, United States: Harvard University.

Manuscript.

Lewis D.E. 2008. The Politics of Presidential Appointments. Political Control and Bureaucratic

Performance. Princeton, United States: Princeton University Press.

Lewis, D.E. 2005. “Staffing Alone: Unilateral Action and the Politicization of the Executive

Office of the President, 1988-2004.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 35(3): 496-514.

Light, P.C. 1995. Thickening Government: Federal Hierarchy and the Diffusion of

Accountability. Washington, DC, United States: Brookings Institution.

Light, P.C. 1999. The President’s Agenda: Domestic Policy Choice from Kennedy to Clinton.

Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press.

Link, M.W. 2002. “The Presidential Kaleidoscope: Advisory Networks in Action.” In: R.

Shapiro et al., editors. Presidential Power: Forging the Presidency for the Twenty-First

Century. New York, United States: Columbia University Press.

Linz, J., and A. Valenzuela, editors. 1994. The Failure of Presidential Democracy. Baltimore,

United States: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Lowi, T.J. 1972. “Four Systems of Policy, Politics and Choice.” Public Administration Review

32: 298-310.

Madrid, R. 2003. Retiring the State: The Politics of Pension Privatization in Latin America and

Beyond. Stanford, United States: Stanford University Press.

Madrid, R. 2005. “Ideas, Economic Pressures, and Pension Privatization.” Latin American

Politics and Society 47(2): 23-50.

Magaloni, B. et al. 2007. “Clientelism and Portfolio Diversification: A Model of Electoral

Investment with Applications to Mexico.” In: H. Kitschelt and S. Wilkinson, editors.

Patrons, Clients and Policies. Cambridge, United States: Cambridge University Press.

Maranto, R. 1993. Politics and Bureaucracy in the Modern Presidency: Appointees and

Careerists in the Reagan Administration. Westport, United States: Greenwood Press.

Markoff, J., and V. Montecinos. 1994. “The Ubiquitous Rise of Economists.” Journal of Public

Policy 13(1): 37-38.

Martínez-Gallardo, C. 2005. “Designing Cabinets: Presidents, Politics, and Policymaking in

Latin America.” New York, United States: Columbia University. Ph.D. Dissertation.

64

Martínez-Gallardo, C. 2010a. “Inside the Cabinet: The Influence of Ministers in the

Policymaking Process.” In: C. Scartascini et al., editors. How Democracy Works:

Political Institutions, Actors, and Arenas in Latin American Policymaking. Washington,

DC, United States: Inter-American Development Bank.

Martínez-Gallardo, C. 2010b. Designing Cabinets: Presidential Politics and Cabinet Instability in

Latin America. Unpublished Manuscript. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina.

Martínez-Gallardo, C. 2010c. “Out of the Cabinet: What Drives Defections from the

Government in Presidential Systems?” Paper prepared for the American Political Science

Association Annual Meeting, Washington DC, September 2-5.

Mayer, K. 2001. With the Stroke of a Pen: Executive Orders and Presidential Power. Princeton,

United States: Princeton University Press.

Mayorga, R.A. 2001. “Presidencialismo Parlamentarizado y Gobiernos de Coalición en Bolivia.”

In: J. Lanzaro, editor. Tipos de Presidencialismo y Coaliciones Politicas en America

Latina. Buenos Aires, Argentina: CLACSO: 101-135.

Mejía Acosta, A. et al. 2009. “Institutional Reforms, Budget Politics, and Fiscal Outcomes in

Ecuador.” In: M. Hallerberg, et al., editors. Who Decides the Budget? A Political

Economy Analysis of the Budget Process in Latin America. Washington, DC, United

States: Inter-American Development Bank/David Rockefeller Center for Latin American

Studies.

Mesa-Lago, C., and K. Muller. 2002. “The Politics of Pension Reform in Latin America.”

Journal of Latin American Studies 34: 687-71.

Miller, G.J. 1993. “Formal Theory and the Presidency.” In: G.C. Edwards et al., editors.

Researching the Presidency: Vital Questions, New Approaches. Pittsburgh, United States:

University of Pittsburgh Press.

Moe, T.M. 1993. “Presidents, Institutions, and Theory.” In: G.C. Edwards et al., editors.

Researching the Presidency: Vital Questions, New Approaches. Pittsburgh, United States:

University of Pittsburgh Press.

Moe, T.M., and W. Howell. 1999. “Unilateral Action and Presidential Power: A Theory.”

Presidential Studies Quarterly 29(4): 850-872.

Moe, T.M., and S.A. Wilson. 1994. “Presidents and the Politics of Structure.” Law and

Contemporary Problems 57: 1-44.

65

Molinas, J.R. et al. 2009. “Weakened Policymaking Process, Deteriorating Fiscal Outcomes: The

Case of Paraguay.” In: M. Hallerberg, et al., editors. Who Decides the Budget? A

Political Economy Analysis of the Budget Process in Latin America. Washington, DC,

United States: Inter-American Development Bank/David Rockefeller Center for Latin

American Studies.

Molinelli, N.G. et al. 1998. Congreso, Presidencia y Justicia en Argentina. Buenos Aires,

Argentina: Temas.

Montecinos, V., and J. Markoff, editors. 2009. Economists in the Americas. Cheltenham, United

Kingdom: Edward Elgar.

Moraes, J.A. et al. 2009. “Fiscal Rules that Fit Political Cycles: The Case of Uruguay Who

Decides the Budget? A Political Economy Analysis of the Budget Process in Latin

America. Washington, DC, United States: Inter-American Development Bank/David

Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies.

Murillo, M.V. 2001. Labor Unions, Partisan Coalitions, and Market Reforms in Latin America.

Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

Negretto, G. 2006. “Minority Presidents and Democratic Performance in Latin America.” Latin

American Politics and Society 48(3): 63-92.

Neustadt, R.E. 1954. “Presidency and Legislation: The Growth of Central Clearance.” American

Political Science Review Vol. 48(3): 641-671.

Neustadt, R.E. 1990. Presidential Power and the Modern Presidents. New York, United States:

Free Press.

Nicholls, K. 1991. “The Dynamics of National Executive Service: Ambition Theory and the

Careers of Presidential Cabinet Members.” Western Political Quarterly 44(1): 149-172.

Novaro, M. 2001. “Presidentes, Equilibrios Institucionales y Coaliciones de Gobierno en

Argentina (1989-2000).” In: J. Lanzaro, editor. Tipos de Presidencialismo y Coaliciones

Políticas en América Latina. Buenos Aires, Argentina: CLACSO.

Palermo, V., and M. Novaro. 1996. Política y Poder en el Gobierno de Menem. Buenos Aires,

Argentina: Norma.

Payne, J. Mark et al. 2003. La Política Importa: Democracia y Desarrollo en América Latina.

Washington, DC, United States: Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo.

66

Pereira, C. and B. Mueller. 2002. “Comportamento Estratégico em Presidencialismo de

Coalizão: As Relações entre Executivo e Legislativo na Elaboração do Orçamento

Brasileiro.” Dados 45(2): 265-301.

Pereira, C. et al. 2005. “Under What Conditions Do Presidents Resort to Decree Power? Theory

and Evidence from the Brazilian Case.” Journal of Politics 67(1): 178-200.

Pérez Liñán, A. 2007. Presidential Impeachment and the New Political Instability in Latin

America. Cambridge Studies in Comparative Politics. Cambridge, United Kingdom:

Cambridge University Press.

Perón, J.D. 1988. Conducción Política. Buenos Aires, Argentina: Megafón.

Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 2000. Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy.

Cambridge, United States: MIT Press

Persson, T., and G. Tabellini. 2000. The Economic Effect of Constitutions. Cambridge, United

States: MIT Press

Peterson, M.A. 1990. Legislating Together: The White House and Capitol Hill from Eisenhower

to Reagan. Cambridge, United States: Harvard University Press.

Pfiffner, J. 1987. “Political Appointees and Career Executives: The Democracy-Bureaucracy

Nexus in the Third Century.” Public Administration Review 47(1): 57-65.

Ponder, D.E. 2000. Good Advice: Information and Policy Making in the White House. College

Station, Texas, United States: Texas A&M University Press.

Porter, R.B. 1980. Presidential Decision Making: The Economic Policy Board. Cambridge,

United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

Preston, T. 2001. The President and His Inner Circle: Leadership Style and the Advisory Process

in Foreign Affairs. New York, United States: Columbia University Press.

Puente, J.M. et al. 2009. “Oil Wealth, the Changing Political Structure, and the Budget Process:

The Case of Venezuela.” Who Decides the Budget? A Political Economy Analysis of the

Budget Process in Latin America. Washington, DC, United States: Inter-American

Development Bank/David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies.

Ragsdale, L., and J. Theis. 1997. “The Institutionalization of the American Presidency, 1924-

92.”American Journal of Political Science 41(4): 1280-1318.

Remmer, K.L., and F. Gelineau. 2003. “Subnational Electoral Choice: Economic and

Referendum Voting in Argentina.” Comparative Political Studies 36(7): 801–821.

67

Remmer, K.L., and E. Wibbels. 2000. “The Subnational Politics of Economic Adjustment.”

Comparative Political Studies 33(4): 419-451.

Riddlesperger, J.W., and J.D. King. 1986. “Presidential Appointments to the Cabinet, Executive

Office, and White House Staff.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 16: 691-699.

Rockman, B.A. 2002. “Staffing and Organizing the Presidency.” In: R. Shapiro et al., editors.

Presidential Power: Forging the Presidency for the Twenty-First Century. New York,

Columbia University Press.

Rodden, J. 2006. Hamilton’s Paradox: The Promise and Peril of Fiscal Federalism. Cambridge,

United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

Rodríguez, J., and A. Bonvecchi. 2006. “El Papel del Poder Legislativo en el Proceso

Presupuestario Argentino (1984-2004).” Desarrollo Económico 180: 487-521.

Rose, R. 2005. “Giving Direction to Government in Comparative Perspective.” In: J.D.

Aberbach and M.A. Peterson, editors. The Executive Branch. Oxford, United Kingdom:

Oxford University Press.

Rudalevige, A. 2002. Managing the President’s Program: Presidential Leadership and

Legislative Policy Formulation. Princeton, United States: Princeton University Press.

Rudalevige, A. 2005. “The Structure of Leadership: Presidents, Hierarchies, and Information

Flow.”Presidential Studies Quarterly 35(2): 333-360.

Rudalevige, A. 2009. “The Administrative Presidency and Bureaucratic Control: Implementing a

Research Agenda.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 39: 10-24.

Samuels, D. 2003. Ambition, Federalism, and Legislative Politics in Brazil. Cambridge, United

Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

Schady, N.R. 2000. Picking the Poor: Indicators for Geographic Targeting in Peru. Policy

Research Working Paper 2477. Washington, DC, United States: World Bank.

Schamis, H. 1999. “Distributional Coalitions and the Politics of Economic Reform in Latin

America.” World Politics 51(2): 236-268.

Schamis, H. 2002. Re-forming the State: The Politics of Privatization in Latin America and

Europe. Ann Arbor, United States: University of Michigan Press.

Schick, A. 2007. The Federal Budget: Politics, Policy, Process. Third edition. Washington, DC,

United States: Brookings Institution.

68

Shepsle, K., and B. Weingast. 1981. “Political Preferences for the Pork Barrel: A

Generalization.” American Journal of Political Science 25(1): 96-111.

Shugart, M., and J. Carey. 1992. Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral

Dynamics. Cambridge, United States: Cambridge University Press.

Siavelis, P. 2010. “Formal and Informal Organization of the Executive Branch in Chile.” Paper

presented at the V Congreso Latinoamericano de Ciencia Política, Buenos Aires,

Argentina, July 28-30.

Stewart, C. 1989. Budget Reform Politics: The Design of the Appropriations Process in the

House of Representatives, 1865-1921. Cambridge, United States: Cambridge University

Press.

Stokes, S.C., editor. 2001. Public Support for Economic Reforms in New Democracies.

Cambridge, United States: Cambridge University Press.

Sullivan, T., editor. 2004. The Nerve Center: Lessons in Governing from the White House Chiefs

of Staff. College Station, Texas, United States: Texas A&M University Press.

‘T Hart, P. 1994. Groupthink in Government: A Study of Small Groups and Policy Failure.

Baltimore, United States: Johns Hopkins University Press.

‘T Hart, J. Stein and B. Sundelius, editors. Beyond Groupthink: Political Group Dynamics and

Foreign Policy-making. Ann Arbor, United States: University of Michigan Press.

‘T Hart, P. et al. 1997. “Foreign Policy-Making at the Top: Political Group Dynamics.” In: P. 't

Hart, J. Stein and B. Sundelius, editors. Beyond Groupthink: Political Group Dynamics

and Foreign Policy-making. Ann Arbor, United States: University of Michigan Press.

Thompson, Robert J. 1992. “Contrasting Models of White House Staff Organization: The

Eisenhower, Ford, and Carter Experiences.” Congress and the Presidency 19: 101-124.

Tommasi, M. et al. 2001. “Fiscal Federalism in Argentina: Policies, Politics, and Institutional

Reform.” Economia 1: 147–201.

Torre, J.C. 1998. El Proceso Político de las Reformas Económicas en América Latina. Buenos

Aires, Argentina: Paidos.

Volden, C. 2002. “A Formal Model of the Politics of Delegation in a Separation of Powers

System.” American Journal of Political Science 46(1): 111-133.

Walcott, C.E., and K.M. Hult. 1995. Governing the White House from Hoover to LBJ. Lawrence,

Kansas: University Press of Kansas.

69

Weingast, B. 2005. “Caught in the Middle: The President, Congress, and the Political-

Bureaucratic System.” In: J.D. Aberbach and M.A. Peterson, editors. The Executive

Branch. Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

Weingast, B., and W.J. Marshall. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why

Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets.” Journal of Political Economy,

96(1): 132-163.

Weingast, B. et al. 1981. “The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical

Approach to Distributive Politics.” Journal of Political Economy 89(4): 642-664.

West, W. 2006. “Presidential Leadership and Administrative Coordination: Examining the

Theory of a Unified Executive.” Presidential Studies Quarterly 36(3): 433-456.

Weyland, K. 2005. “Theories of Policy Diffusion: Lessons from Latin American Pension

Reform.” World Politics 57(2): 262-95.

Weyland, K. 2007. Bounded Rationality and Policy Diffusion: Social Sector Reform in Latin

America. Princeton, United States: Princeton University Press.

Weyland, K. et al., editors. 2010. Leftist Governments in Latin America: Successes and

Shortcomings. Cambridge, United States: Cambridge University Press.

Whitehead, L. 2010. “Fernando Henrique Cardoso: The Astuzia Fortunata of Brazil’s

Sociologist-President.” Journal of Politics in Latin America 1(3): 111-129.

Wibbels, E. 2005. “Decentralized Governance, Constitution Formation, and Redistribution.”

Constitutional Political Economy 16(2): 161-88.

Zelaznik, J. 2001. The Building of Coalitions in the Presidential Systems of Latin America.

Colchester: University of Essex. Ph.D. dissertation.