Contracts Outline Fall 2014: Kordana

27
CONTRACTS OUTLINE Page 1 of 27 Contracts Outline Fall 2014: Kordana Don't be a jerk, fetishist and/or freakazoid ELEMENTS OF A CONTRACT 1. Mutual intent 2. Consideration (or promissory estoppel or material benefit) 3. Capacity 4. Sufficient definiteness 5. No fraudulent/against public policy 6. Not unconscionable K=win/win In remedies: talk about property and liability rule protection, Coase, and what are we doing around here, incentives and social waste ROADMAP FOR CONTRACT LAW I. Introduction to Implied in Fact Contracts and the Restitution Interest a. Bailey v. West (R.I, 1969) i. Bailey boarded a horse on his farm when ownership of said horse was in question. West would not pay; he did not own the horse. Bailey sued. Put in volunteer box=loses ii. Timeline: T0=horse is dropped off. T1=ownership clarified although the horse remains. (For some reason the parties testify in a non selfinterested way – West says T0T1 is two to three months and Bailey says one to two months. Kordana thinks the judge screwed up the timeline). iii. TC splits the baby, giving payment for a reasonable period of time. T1 matters to TC. iv. Court here does not care when T1 is and does not split the baby. b. Law of Agency: To what extent should principles be responsible for the actions of their agents? i. Even though the agent screwed up, the legal issue is between the principle and the third party. ii. West acts through agents but he is still liable for when his agent makes a mistake. Most agents would be judgement proof. iii. Need the third parties to trust agents. c. Least Cost Avoider: liability is imposed on the party that could have prevented damages from occurring at the lowest cost. i. KK agrees with Paolino’s outcome but for a different reason: Bailey was the least cost avoider – should have picked up the phone and clarified (‘lift your little pinkie finger dude’). d. Implied in Fact: Not written or oral but still real. i. Intent: Mutual intent is inferred based on the circumstances, which, according to the ordinary course of dealing and the common understanding of men, shows a mutual intent to contract. 1. If the promises of the parties are inferred from their acts or conduct, or from words that are not explicitly words of agreement, the contract is said to be implied in fact. ii. KK thinks Bailey was implied in fact (disagrees with Paolino). It is reasonable to think that you will get paid even when there is an ownership dispute.

Transcript of Contracts Outline Fall 2014: Kordana

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  1  of  27  

Contracts  Outline    Fall  2014:  Kordana  

Don't  be  a  jerk,  fetishist  and/or  freakazoid    

ELEMENTS  OF  A  CONTRACT  1. Mutual  intent  2. Consideration  (or  promissory  estoppel  or  material  benefit)  3. Capacity  4. Sufficient  definiteness    5. No  fraudulent/against  public  policy  6. Not  unconscionable  

 K=win/win    In  remedies:  talk  about  property  and  liability  rule  protection,  Coase,  and  what  are  we  doing  around  here,  incentives  and  social  waste    ROADMAP  FOR  CONTRACT  LAW    I. Introduction  to  Implied  in  Fact  Contracts  and  the  Restitution  Interest    

a. Bailey  v.  West  (R.I,  1969)  i. Bailey  boarded  a  horse  on  his  farm  when  ownership  of  said  horse  was  in  question.  West  

would  not  pay;  he  did  not  own  the  horse.  Bailey  sued.  Put  in  volunteer  box=loses  ii. Timeline:  T0=horse  is  dropped  off.  T1=ownership  clarified  although  the  horse  remains.  

(For  some  reason  the  parties  testify  in  a  non  self-­‐interested  way  –  West  says  T0-­‐T1  is  two  to  three  months  and  Bailey  says  one  to  two  months.  Kordana  thinks  the  judge  screwed  up  the  timeline).    

iii. TC  splits  the  baby,  giving  payment  for  a  reasonable  period  of  time.  T1  matters  to  TC.    iv. Court  here  does  not  care  when  T1  is  and  does  not  split  the  baby.    

b. Law  of  Agency:  To  what  extent  should  principles  be  responsible  for  the  actions  of  their  agents?      i. Even  though  the  agent  screwed  up,  the  legal  issue  is  between  the  principle  and  the  third  

party.    ii. West  acts  through  agents  but  he  is  still  liable  for  when  his  agent  makes  a  mistake.  Most  

agents  would  be  judgement  proof.    iii. Need  the  third  parties  to  trust  agents.    

c. Least  Cost  Avoider:  liability  is  imposed  on  the  party  that  could  have  prevented  damages  from  occurring  at  the  lowest  cost.    

i. KK  agrees  with  Paolino’s  outcome  but  for  a  different  reason:  Bailey  was  the  least  cost  avoider  –  should  have  picked  up  the  phone  and  clarified  (‘lift  your  little  pinkie  finger  dude’).    

d. Implied  in  Fact:  Not  written  or  oral  but  still  real.  i. Intent:  Mutual  intent  is  inferred  based  on  the  circumstances,  which,  according  to  the  

ordinary  course  of  dealing  and  the  common  understanding  of  men,  shows  a  mutual  intent  to  contract.    

1. If  the  promises  of  the  parties  are  inferred  from  their  acts  or  conduct,  or  from  words  that  are  not  explicitly  words  of  agreement,  the  contract  is  said  to  be  implied  in  fact.    

ii. KK  thinks  Bailey  was  implied  in  fact  (disagrees  with  Paolino).  It  is  reasonable  to  think  that  you  will  get  paid  even  when  there  is  an  ownership  dispute.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  2  of  27  

e. Implied  in  Law  (aka  Quasi  Contract):  Law  of  restitution/law  of  unjust  enrichment  –  not  a  real  contract,  and  not  about  mutual  intent  

i. When  one  party  is  required  to  compensate  another  for  a  benefit  conferred  in  order  to  avoid  unjust  enrichment.    

1. The  existence  of  a  benefit  does  not  automatically  mean  that  you  owe  money  -­‐  Officious  intermeddler  (squidgy  man)  

ii. Three  prongs  P  must  show:    1. Benefit  Conferred  2. Benefit  Appreciated  –  knowledge  of  expectation  to  be  paid  3. Benefit  Accepted  –  D  would  be  unjustly  enriched  if  allowed  to  retain  benefit  

without  paying  its  value.    iii. Bailey  has  a  good  case  for  quasi  contract,  but  called  a  volunteer  so  put  in  a  different  box.    

 II. Introduction  to  Contract  Formation  and  the  Objective  Theory  of  Intent    

a. RST  2d:  §  12:  Capacity  to  Contract  i. A  person  lacks  capacity  if  he  is  unable  to  act  in  a  reasonable  manner  and  the  other  

person  has  reason  to  know  his  condition  ii. Voidability:  power  to  void  contract  if  no  capacity  

b. RST  2d:  §  16:  Intoxicated  Persons  i. The  test  is  whether  the  person  who  was  so  intoxicated  as  to  be  unable  to  understand  the  

nature,  purpose  and  effect  of  what  he  was  doing.    c. Lucy  v.  Zehmer  (Va.  1954)  

i. D  writes  a  contract  to  sell  farm  on  a  napkin,  when  P  tries  to  enforce  it,  D  claims  he  was  drunk  and  only  joking.    

ii. Issue:  is  a  party  bound  if  he  acts  like  he  assents  to  an  agreement,  even  if  he  did  not  really  mean  it?  

iii. H/R:  Yes.  If  a  party  to  the  contract  has  reasonable  belief  that  the  other  party  has  the  requisite  intent  to  enter  into  the  agreement  when  he  does  not,  the  contract  is  still  enforceable.    

d. Anti-­‐opportunitism  rules:  prevent  those  who  have  knowledge  of  lack  of  capacity  or  intoxication  from  exploiting  that  knowledge.    

e. Objective  Theory  of  Contracts:  pays  attention  to  the  facts  a  third  party  could  observe.  Important  to  look  at  outward  and  manifest  intention  rather  than  secret  intention.    

i. Mutual  assent.  Mutual  Assent  is  necessary  for  contract  formation  and  is  determined  under  the  objective  theory  of  intent  –  what  a  reasonable  person  to  whom  an  expression  is  made  would  understand  the  expression  to  mean.  Not  about  subjective  intent  or  subjective  interpretations  

ii. Rationale:  protection  of  parties’  reasonable  expectations  for  certainty  in  business  transactions  

iii. Application:  there  is  sufficient  manifestation  of  assent  whenever  a  party  uses  an  expression  that  he  knows  (or  has  reason  to  know)  the  other  party  would  reasonably  interpret  as  an  offer  or  acceptance  and  the  other  party  does  so  interpret  it.    

f. Reliance  i. Enforce  K  that  are  supposed  to  be  win-­‐win  because  of  reliance  

1. Make  investments  2. Change  behaviour    

ii. Lucy  tries  to  manufacture  reliance  by  his  actions  about  town  the  following  day      

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  3  of  27  

III. Introduction  to  Incomplete  Contracts  and  the  Role  of  the  Courts    a. Walker  v.  Keith  

i. Facts:  Walker  was  a  landlord  who  leased  a  piece  of  property  with  an  option  to  renew.  The  option  did  not  contain  a  fixed  price,  but  rather  that  rent  would  be  set  at  the  time  reflected  by  comparative  business  conditions.  Parties  could  not  agree  down  the  line.    

ii. Issue:  was  the  option  to  renew  enforceable?    iii. Holding:  No,  the  renewal  option  was  merely  an  unenforceable  agreement  to  agree.    iv. Kordana  comments:    

1. Strange  that  the  court  mentions  the  meeting  of  the  minds  (subjectivity)    2. Why  is  this  court  unwilling  to  fulfil  its  typical  role  in  contract  law  which  is  to  fill  

in  gaps  in  contracts  (which  are  inevitable)?    b. Stability:  We  want  future  business  transactions  to  be  incentivised  to  have  stability.  

i. It  is  a  foreseeable  possibility  that  if  we  renew  the  lease  we  need  to  talk  about  rent.  This  gap  is  not  a  remote  possibility,  but  is  foreseeable.    

ii. Least  Cost  Avoider:  one  reason  Clay  throws  them  out  of  his  courtroom  is  that  the  parties  have  not  “lifted  their  little  pinkie  fingers”  to  fill  in  the  gap  and  say  what  rent  is.  

1. On  page  5  in  the  judges  words:  “as  a  practical  matter,  courts  will  sometimes  assert  their  right  not  to  be  imposed  upon.”  

2. Either  say  what  rent  is  or  come  up  with  a  formula,  but  if  you  “are  going  to  be  total  lazy  bastards  get  the  hell  out  of  my  courtroom.”    

3. Most  judges  will  fill  most  gaps  most  of  the  time.    4. The  judge  in  this  case  sees  a  gap  that  is  so  big  he  does  not  believe  the  parties  

intended  to  contract.    c. Indefiniteness  Doctrine:  to  be  enforceable  a  contact  must  have  a  certain  minimal  level  of  

definiteness,  need  to  agree  on  certain  crucial  elements.    i. An  apparent  bargain  will  not  be  enforced  if  it  is  found  to  be  too  indefinite:  (1)  its  terms  

are  so  incomplete  or  uncertain  that  they  show  that  the  parties  did  not  regard  themselves  as  having  completed  a  contract.  (2)  Even  if  it  seems  that  the  parties  regarded  themselves  as  having  completed  a  contract,  it  is  so  indefinite  that  a  court  cannot  determine  its  material  terms  with  reasonable  certainty  or  fashion  an  appropriate  remedy  for  breach.    

ii. The  mere  fact  that  an  agreement  leaves  gaps  does  not  render  it  fatally  indefinite;  almost  all  contracts  have  gaps  that  the  court  can  fill  through  the  process  of  implication.    

iii. In  regard  to  Walker:    1. If  the  parties  attempt  to  define  the  price  though  a  standard  that  is  itself  

indefinite,  the  traditional  approach  is  to  refuse  enforcement  on  the  ground  that  in  such  cases  it  cannot  be  inferred  that  the  parties  indented  a  reasonable  price.  

iv. Least  cost  avoider:  listening  to  experts  could  fill  the  gap  but  that  is  costly.  The  parties  could  have  figured  this  out  by  contracting  more  specifically.  The  parties  are  the  least  cost  avoiders  by  covering  the  basics.  Beyond  basics  (e.g.  Canadian  invasion)  the  judge  would  be  the  least  cost  avoider  –  it  is  expensive  to  contract  over  every  possible  future  event.    

d. UCC  §  2-­‐305:  Open  Price  Term    i. On  its  face  liberalises  the  enforcement  of  open  price  terms.  Attentive  to  interests  of  

businessmen  ii. Can  conclude  a  contract  without  price;  default  to  reasonable  price  at  time  of  delivery  iii. As  long  as  the  parties  intend  to  make  a  binding  contract,  their  agreement  to  agree  does  

not  make  contract  too  indefinite.        

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  4  of  27  

IV. Introduction  to  Contractual  performance  and  the  Role  of  Fault.    a. Jacob  &  Youngs  v.  Kent  (NY  1921)  

i. Facts:  in  contract  to  build  house  D.  requested  Reading  Pipe.  A  pipe  of  the  same  quality  was  installed  instead.  P  would  have  to  tear  down  substantial  parts  of  the  completed  structure  to  replace  pipes,  so  refused  and  sought  final  payment.  Kent  refused.  P  sues.    

ii. The  mistake  was  trivial  and  innocent.  The  remedy  is  this  case  is  liability  rule  protection  and  not  property  rule  protection.  Property  rule  protection  (tear  down  the  wall)  will  result  in  a  lot  of  social  waste,  and  there  is  no  significant  difference  in  the  quality  of  the  pipe.  Liability  rule  protection  just  requires  a  cheque  for  the  difference.    

1. If  you  want  to  be  idiosyncratic  be  more  explicit.  A  Kleenex  could  mean  high  quality  facial  tissue  and  not  Kleenex™  

iii. Punch  back  to  dissent:  plumbing  is  not  a  matter  of  aesthetics  but  one  of  mere  utility.  It  is  not  weird  to  care  about  the  Corinthian  column  because  that  is  aesthetic,  but  it  is  weird  to  care  about  comparable  quality  of  pipes  in  the  walls.  (Whatever  dude,  don’t  be  a  Reading  Pipe  fetishist).    

b. Substantial  Performance  i. Significance:  a  party  can  bring  suit  on  the  contract  as  a  P  for  expectation  damages  even  

though  he  has  breached  the  contract  by  not  rendering  a  perfect  performance.  1. Offset:  D  is  entitled  to  offset  any  remedy  against  him  by  the  amount  of  damages  

he  incurred  as  a  result  of  Ps  breach.  ii. What  constitutes  substantial  performance?  

1. A  question  of  fact  to  be  governed  by  the  circumstances  of  each  case.    2. Does  the  performance  meet  the  essential  purpose  of  the  contract?  Some  factors  

a. The  extent  the  contracted  for  benefits  that  the  innocent  party  has  received.    

b. The  extent  to  which  damages  will  be  an  adequate  compensation  for  breach  

c. The  extent  to  which  forfeiture  will  occur  if  the  doctrine  is  not  applied.    d. The  extent  to  which  the  breach  was  wrongful  or  in  bad  faith.    

iii. Damages:    1. Cost  of  completion:  the  amount  that  it  would  cost  to  repair  the  deficiency.  2. Diminution  in  value:  if  the  repair  would  involve  substantial  economic  waste  or  if  the  

cost-­‐of-­‐completion  damages  would  be  disproportionate  to  the  end  to  be  served,  the  measure  of  damages  will  be  the  amount  by  which  the  deficiency  in  the  performance  diminishes  the  value  of  the  performance.    

 V. Introduction  to  Damages  and  the  Role  of  Substitute  Performance.    

a. Duty  to  mitigate:  Under  UCC  §  2-­‐708,  the  measure  of  damages  for  repudiation  by  the  buyer  is  the  difference  between  the  contract  price  and  the  market  price  at  the  time  and  place  for  tender.  If  the  seller  breaches,  the  buyer  may  either  cover  (make  a  good  faith  purchase  within  a  reasonable  time)  or  recover  damages.  i. An  injured  party  is  not  permitted  to  recover  damages  that  could  have  been  avoided  by  

reasonable  efforts.    1. Contracts  for  the  sale  of  goods:  under  the  U.C.C.  if  the  seller  fails  to  deliver  the  

buyer  has  a  right  to  cover.  If  a  buyer  fails  to  cover,  she  will  be  barred  from  recovering  any  consequential  damages  that  she  could  have  prevented  by  covering.  Similarly,  if  the  buyer  repudiates  the  contract  prior  to  delivery,  the  seller  cannot  run  up  the  damages  by  incurring  freight  charged  for  packing,  delivery  and  so  forth.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  5  of  27  

ii. Expenses  incurred  in  a  reasonable  effort  to  mitigate  damages  are  recoverable  as  incidental  damages,  whether  or  not  the  effort  was  successful.    

b. Globe  Refining  Co.  v.  Landa  Cotton  Oil  Co.  i. P  is  a  victim  of  a  contract  breach  for  the  purchase  of  oil.  For  lack  of  oil  he  wants  

consequential  damages.    1. Holmes:  a  contract  is  a  promise  to  do  something  or  to  pay  damages  

ii. The  measure  of  damages:  (Market  Price  –  Contract  Price)  +  incidentals.    iii. How  to  fill  contract  gaps:  default  rules:    

1. Hypothetical  contracting:  what  would  reasonable  people  have  contracted  for  2. Penalty  Defaults:  incentive  based  (people  need  to  think  about  this  more)  –  see  

Walker  v.  Keith  iv. Incidentals  

1.  Be  reasonable  in  covering.  Don’t  return  from  TX  without  the  oil.    2. You  would  have  had  to  bear  the  cost  of  the  trip  from  KY  to  TX  either  way  so  that  is  

not  covered.    c. The  expectation  damages  rule  operates  to  deprive  the  ‘loser’  of  any  benefit  from  indulging  in  

non-­‐cooperative  conduct  and  reciprocally,  gives  the  winner  his  due.  The  gamble  is  fair  for  both  parties,  and  the  rule  has  a  consistent  and  important  role  in  making  cooperative  relations  feasible  and  in  promoting  efficient  resource  allocation  

d. Expectancy  damages  versus  reliance  damages  i. Start  at  0,  contract  gives  you  1.  If  you  rely  and  it’s  to  your  detriment,  you  are  left  at  -­‐1.    ii. Expectancy  is  2  iii. Reliance  is  1:  it  returns  you  to  the  point  you  would  be  at  had  you  not  made  the  contract.    

e. RST  2d  §344  Purposes  of  Remedies    i. (a)  Expectation  interest  ii. (b)  Reliance  interest  iii. (c)  Restitution  interest  

f. The  Efficient  Breach  i. There  should  be  an  incentive  to  breach  when  it  would  be  efficient.  Restitution  is  punitive  

and  takes  this  incentive  away  ii. Pareto  move  (someone  is  better  off  but  no  one  is  worse  off)  

 VI. Introduction  to  Contract  Defences  and  the  Role  of  Inequality.    

a. Williams  v.  Walker-­‐Thomas  Furniture  Co.    i. Unconscionable:  the  cross  collateralisation  clause.  If  Ms.  Williams  buys  a  series  of  items,  

she  can  never  pay  off  one  of  them  unless  she  pays  off  all  of  them  ii. Risk:  at  T0  the  furniture  company  is  the  one  going  out  on  a  limb  and  bearing  the  risk  and  

the  risk  shifts  over  time:  at  T4  Williams  could  lose  it  all  for  lack  of  $1.    iii. Dissent:  concerned  that  if  you  vindicate  Ms.  Williams  you  restrict  the  poor’s  access  to  

credit.  iv. There  was  an  absence  of  meaningful  choice  and  unfair  terms:    

1. Lack  of  bargaining  power  2. Lack  of  education  3. Fine  Print  

v. A  pushback  at  the  dissent:  any  credit  is  taking  the  floor;  we  do  not  want  people  to  fall  below  the  floor  –  below  the  social  minimum.  Also  credit  is  risky  and  if  they  fall  below  the  floor  we  have  to  pick  them  back  up.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  6  of  27  

b. Black  Letter  Law:  Contract  term  can  be  knocked  out  as  unconscionable  if  it  is  procedurally  unconscionable  (bargaining  power,  lack  of  evidence,  fine  print)  or  substantially  unconscionable  (term  is  unreasonable).  

i. UCC  §  2-­‐302:  unconscionable  Contract  or  Clause:  if  a  court  as  a  matter  of  law  finds  a  contract  or  any  clause  of  the  contract  to  have  been  unconscionable  at  the  time  it  was  made,  the  court  may  refuse  to  enforce  the  contract  or  it  may  enforce  the  remainder  of  the  contract  without  the  unconscionable  clause,  or  it  may  so  limit  the  application  of  any  unconscionable  clause  as  to  avoid  any  unconscionable  result.    

ii. Procedural  unconscionability:    1. Where  a  party  who  drafts  the  contract  includes  a  term  in  the  contract,  having  

reason  to  know  that  the  term  does  not  accord  with  the  other  party’s  fair  expectations  and  that  the  other  party  will  not  notice  the  term  

2. Unfair  bargaining  positions  3. Unfair  surprise:  contrary  to  reasonable  expectations  as  to  what  provisions  a  

contract  of  the  general  type  would  involve  the  term  is  not  pointed  out  and  explained,  or  is  written  in  obscure  language.    

iii. Substantive  unconscionability:    1. Contract  terms  that  are  unconscionable  without  regard  to  the  bargaining  process  

because  they  are  lopsided  iv. RST  2d  §  208:  unconscionable  Contract  or  Term  

1. It  is  possible  for  a  contract  to  be  oppressive  taken  as  a  whole,  despite  the  fact  that  there  is  no  weakness  in  the  bargaining  process,  but  adds  that  unconscionability  ordinarily  involves  other  factors  as  well  as  overall  imbalance.    

   THE  BARGAIN  THEORY  OF  CONTRACT    I. Introduction  to  Consideration:  Gratuitous  Promises    

a. Must  have  to  have  an  enforceable  contract  b. Benefit  Detriment  Test  

i. Either  benefit  to  promisor  or  detriment  to  promisee  c. Bargain  For  Theory:    

i. Both  parties  agree  to  an  exchange  –  giving  something  up  ii. Equivalence  not  required  (consider  circumstances)  iii. Each  giving  up  something  to  get  what  they  want    iv. Mutual  obligation  v. RST  2d  §  71:  Majority  rule  for  bargain  for  case  

1. To  constitute  consideration,  a  performance  or  a  return  promise  must  be  bargained  for  

2. We  have  a  bargain  if  you  view  this  as  an  unfortunate  price  that  someone  has  to  pay  to  get  whatever  result  

3. Different  then  the  benefit/detriment  test:  because  it's  a  little  more  constrictive.    

d. If  the  promise  was  given  as  part  of  a  bargain:  i. Was  it  nominal?  A  bargain  in  form  but  not  in  substance-­‐unenforceable  ii. Was  the  bargain  based  on  a  promise  to  surrender  or  forbear  from  asserting  a  

legal  claim?  –  if  in  good  faith=enforceable  iii. Illusory  promise:  a  statement  that  appeared  to  be  a  promise  but  does  not  

commit  the  promisor  to  any  more  than  what  he  might  later  desire  to  do=unenforceable  

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  7  of  27  

e. If  the  promise  was  not  given  as  a  bargain,  unenforceable  unless  another  possibility  may  make  it  so:    

i. Reliance:  did  the  promisee  rely  to  his  detriment  ii. Past  consideration:  not  consideration  iii. Waiver:  iv. Form:  was  the  promise  in  some  special  legal  form,  such  as  under  seal  in  a  state  

that  still  recognized  the  binding  force  of  the  seal    f. Hamer  v.  Sidway  

i. Consideration  because  the  nephew  suffered  a  detriment.  He  gave  up  his  legal  right  to  drink,  smoke  and  swear.    

ii. Because  it  is  a  subjective  test,  it  does  not  matter  that  the  performance  did  not  provide  a  benefit  to  the  promisor  

iii. KK  –  thinks  what  is  really  going  on  here  is  bankruptcy  fraud  g. Kirksey  v.  Kirksey  

i. From  a  house  to  a  hut  to  the  street  was  the  course  of  Ms.  Kirksey’s  retreat.  She  could  not  recover  from  her  in-­‐law  (her  lover?)  Who’d  nakedly  promised  a  suite.    

ii. Gave  up  homesteading  –  D  wants  her  to  give  up  her  land  because  it  is  “unhealthy”  and  society  is  “bad”  

1. D’s  offer:  if  you  come  and  see  me,  I  will  put  you  up.  Expresses  himself  diffidently  to  express  he  is  not  bargaining.  

iii. The  difference  between  a  bargain  and  a  gift:    1. Put  a  condition  on  the  gift  –  you  have  to  make  some  effort  to  receive  it  

versus  a  bargain  in  which  you  are  exchanging  one  thing  for  another.    iv. Promises  to  make  gifts  are  not  enforceable  because  they  lack  consideration.    

h. In  re  Green  i. Contracts  under  seal:  in  the  absence  of  a  statute  a  promise  is  binding  without  

consideration  if  it  is  in  writing  and  sealed  –  RST  2d  §  95  1. If  you  write  down  the  promise  to  pay  for  something  in  writing,  then  it  

means  more  than  saying  it.    2. There  is  a  cautionary  function  of  consideration:  formalism.  It  is  enforced  

when  you  go  through  the  entire  process.  It  is  a  way  of  protecting  the  promisor  from  saying  and  sticking  to  something  that  they  weren’t  even  all  that  formal  about  initiating.  There  has  to  be  a  display  of  commitment.    

3. The  Channelling  Function/Evidentiary  Function:  by  channelling  we  promote  the  evidentiary  function.  It’s  channelling  someone  to  make  that  formalism,  because  we  want  that  person  to  be  able  to  rely.  The  law  channels  you  to  provide  the  evidence  –  this  is  why  we  have  the  seal  

4. If  you  mean  it,  write  it  down  *Lucy  5. What  constitutes  a  seal?  Comment  (b)  ‘written’  

ii. Past  consideration  is  no  consideration  i. Wolford  v.  Powers  

i. Wolford  trying  to  enforce  the  promissory  note  through  the  estate.  Theory-­‐  just  a  promise  to  make  a  gift,  no  consideration.  Lower  court  agreed.  Supreme  Court  Reversed  

ii. If  you  are  a  §71  guy,  it’s  obvious  that  there  was  consideration:  he  had  a  legal  right  to  name  the  kid  and  gave  up  that  right,  it  was  the  unfortunate  price  both  parties  had  to  pay.    

j. Bataskis  v.  Demotsis  

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  8  of  27  

i. Most  states  have  usury  laws  that  prevent  the  lending  of  money  at  an  outrageous  rate.    

ii. Not  unconscionable  because  of  Social  policy:  war-­‐torn  country,  induced  to  bargain.    

iii. Demotsis  knew  that  he  was  only  getting  $25  but  was  lying  to  meet  state  usury  laws  –  the  only  way  that  this  decision  makes  sense.    

iv. If  we  think  you  were  really  bargaining,  we  will  enforce  the  contract.      

II. Promissory  Estoppel  a. RST  2d  §90:  Promise  reasonably  inducing  action  or  Forbearance.    

i. A  promise  that  the  promisor  should  reasonably  expect  to  induce  action  or  forbearance  on  the  part  of  the  promise  or  a  third  person  and  which  does  induce  such  action  or  forbearance  is  binding  if  injustice  can  be  avoided  only  by  enforcement  of  the  promise.  The  remedy  granted  for  breach  may  be  limited  as  justice  requires.  

b. Ricketts  v.  Scothorn  i. Grandfather  gives  granddaughter  money.  Was  it  foreseeable  that  she  would  

retire?    ii. Intra-­‐Familial  Promises    

1. Shame  sanctions  (non-­‐legal  sanctions)  among  families  create  obligations,  unenforceable  

2. Non-­‐legal  sanctions  disappear  when  promisor  dies.  Thanks  to  dead  guy  rule  she  can  sue  the  estate.    

3. Dead  guy  rule:  courts  don’t  enforce  promises  to  make  gifts  among  family  members  when  promisor  is  alive  but  are  willing  to  enforce  against  dead  guy.    

a. The  promise  did  not  revoke  or  withdraw  the  future  gift  promise  during  his  lifetime,  he  meant  to  hold  it.  If  he  did  revoke,  willing  to  suffer  non-­‐legal  sanctions,  therefore  P  should  lose.    

iii. Court  recognises  that  there  was  no  consideration  because  the  note  was  not  conditioned  on  her  quitting  

1. Did  not  view  giving  her  the  promissory  note  as  the  unfortunate  price  he  had  to  pay  for  her  to  quit  

iv. But  even  though  there  is  no  consideration,  there  is  promissory  estoppel,  which  is  a  substitute  for  consideration  because  of  reliance.    

c. Feinberg  v.  Pfeiffer    i. Told  her  she  could  retire  when  she  wanted,  receive  $200  a  month,  cut  pension  ii. Long  term  employee,  BoD  resolution:  strange  language  (hope  and  desire)  more  

consistent  with  giving  a  gift  rather  than  a  firm  obligation.    iii. There  is  no  consideration  because  they  are  not  requiring  anything  of  her.  Past  

consideration  is  no  consideration  and  they  do  not  view  this  as  the  unfortunate  price  they  have  to  pay.  But  they  will  still  lose  because  PE.    

iv. “The  implied  promise  to  complete  being  the  consideration  for  the  original  promise”  –  the  court  fills  the  gap  by  implying  a  promise.  

v. Under  §90,  must  show  definite  and  substantial  reliance.    d. Hoffman  v.  Red  Owl  Stores  

i. PE  as  Tort  –  no  definiteness  (see  Walker  v.  Keith)  but  relied  to  detriment  so  tort.  Not  p.e.  as  consideration  

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  9  of  27  

ii. They  induce  him  to  buy  a  grocery  store  to  get  some  experience  to  be  qualified  to  get  to  the  franchise.  He  must  bear  the  cost  of  his  own  experience  

iii. But  then  “everything  is  ready  to  go,  get  your  money  together  and  we  are  all  set”  –  that  is  the  tort  and  now  they  are  on  the  hook.    

1. Sells  grocery  store  in  reliance  on  that    a. Fire  sale:  may  not  have  gotten  fair  market  price.    

e. Allegheny  College  i. Dead  guy  rule  

1. If  you  die  without  repudiating,  then  legal  sanction    2. Dead  guy  rule  is  wrong  here  

ii. D  made  a  pledge  to  Allegheny  College  –  uses  consideration  but  also  gift  iii. Rst  §90  (2)  charitable  contributions  –  held  up.    iv. Normally,  colleges  will  not  sue  people  who  renege  on  their  promise  to  donate.    

f. Former  Rule  -­‐  Reliance  irrelevant  i. Often  a  donative  promise  is  relied  upon  by  the  promisee.  The  rule  at  one  time  

was  that  reliance  was  irrelevant;  a  donative  promise  was  unenforceable  even  if  it  was  relied  upon.  (Kirksey)  

g. Modern  Rule  i. If  a  donative  promise  induces  reliance  by  the  promisee  in  a  manner  that  the  

promisor  should  reasonable  have  expected,  the  promise  will  be  legally  enforceable,  at  least  to  the  extent  of  the  reliance.  (Feinberg  v.  Pfeiffer  Co.)  

ii. The  principle  of  promissory  estoppel:  if  a  promisee  has  relied  on  a  donative  promise,  for  reasons  of  justice  the  promisor  should  be  estopped  (prevented)  from  pleading  lack  of  consideration.  Under  modern  law  and  practice,  reliance  is  viewed  as  either  a  substitute  for  consideration  (bargain)  or  as  consideration  itself  (a  promise  is  enforceable).    

iii. RST  §  90  1. Remedy  may  be  limited  to  the  extent  of  reliance.  "The  remedy  granted  

for  the  breach  may  be  limited  as  justice  requires"  2. Substantial  reliance  not  required:  enough  that  the  promisor  should  have  

reasonably  expected  that  the  promise  would  induce  reliance  h. Reliance  as  consideration:  a  relied  upon  donative  promise  is  enforceable  despite  the  

absence  of  consideration  i. Actual  reliance  ii. Foreseeability  

 III. Material  Benefit  Rule  

a. Webb  v.  McGowin  (Ala.  1935)  –  Webb  saves  McGowin’s  life,  promises  to  pay  for  life.    i. Webb  saves  the  life  of  McGowin,  but  sustains  serious  injuries  during  the  rescue.  

McGowin  promises  to  pay  Webb  a  bimonthly  stipend  for  the  rest  of  Webb’s  life.  McGowin  pays  Webb  the  stipend  for  more  than  eight  years,  but  on  McGowin’s  death,  his  estate  refuses  to  continue  the  payments  to  Webb.    

1. Aka  green  eyeshade  guy  comes  in  and  says  screw  Webb,  it  looks  like  it  was  just  a  gift  

2. Under  Bargain-­‐For  test:  there  is  no  consideration.  McGowin  did  not  view  promising  the  pension  as  the  unfortunate  price  he  had  to  pay  to  prevent  the  block  from  falling  –  past  consideration  is  not  consideration  

3. BUT  –  TRANSACTION  COSTS:  we  are  not  in  ‘freeze-­‐frame’  world.  There  was  no  time  to  strike  a  bargain.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  10  of  27  

4. Material  Benefit  Rule  turns  the  No  to  a  Yes.  I  want  to  live  in  a  world  were  people  feel  comfortable  to  save  me.    

ii. Past  consideration  (saving  his  life)  coupled  with  promise  to  pay.    1. The  subsequent  promise  to  pay  is  significant    -­‐  it  resolves  the  concern  

that  caused  us  not  to  allow  the  squeegee  man  to  recover  because  we  don’t  know  if  he  really  did  confer  a  benefit.  The  subsequent  promise  to  pay  allows  the  recipient  of  the  benefit  to  put  a  value  on  it.    

2. McGowin  puts  a  value  on  it  that  was  not  indefinite.    iii. McGowin’s  promise  is  binding  because  the  promise  to  pay  was  based  on  a  

material  benefit  to  the  promisor  that  constituted  valid  consideration.    b. In  General:  the  principles  that  govern  past  or  moral  consideration  are  still  in  the  process  

of  development.  The  emerging  modern  rule  is  that  a  promise  based  on  a  moral  obligation  is  enforceable  if  the  promises  is  based  on  a  material  benefit  (usually  meaning  an  economic  benefit)  that  was  previously  conferred  by  the  promisee  upon  the  promisor,  provided  the  benefit  gave  rise  to  an  obligation  –  even  if  only  a  moral  obligation  –  to  make  compensation.    

i. RST  2d.  §  86:    “a  promise  made  in  recognition  of  a  benefit  previously  received  by  the  promisor  from  the  promisee  is  binding  to  the  extent  necessary  to  prevent  injustice”  but  it  is  not  blinding  “to  the  extent  that  its  value  is  disproportionate  to  the  benefit.”  

ii. Statues  of  Modern  Rule:    1. Because  the  modern  rule  adopted  in  the  R.2d  is  still  emerging,  some  

courts  continue  to  follow  the  traditional  rule  and  hold  that  a  promise  based  on  moral  or  past  consideration  is  unenforceable  unless  it  is  a  promise  to  pay  a  debt  barred  by  either  the  statute  of  limitations  or  discharge  in  bankruptcy  or  a  promise  to  perform  a  voidable  obligation.    

c. Exception  to  consideration  i. Past  consideration  along  with  promise  to  pay  =  enforceable  ii. Conjunction  of  quasi  contract  and  promise  to  pay  iii. Implicit  request:  “save  me”  is  implied,  not  gratuitous  iv. Subsequent  Promise  v. RST  2d.  §  90:  Cautionary  Function:  don’t  allow  when  only  promised  in  the  

moment  out  of  guilt,  use  caution,  take  account  of  guilt.      NEGOTIATION  AND  FORMATION  OF  THE  CONTRACT    I. ELEMENT:  Offer  and  Acceptance.  R.2d  §§24,  30,  50,  42,  26-­‐7,  57,  59  

a. Do  not  always  have  to  identify  an  explicit  offer  and  acceptance  to  show  intent  to  contact.    b. RST  2d  §  24:  Offer  Defined:  An  offer  is  the  manifestation  of  willingness  to  enter  into  a  bargain,  

so  made  as  to  justify  another  person  in  understanding  that  his  assent  to  that  bargain  is  invited  and  will  conclude  it.    

c. Adverts  are  usually  not  offers,  unless  facts  and  circumstances  make  it  reasonable  to  assume  that  accepting  is  enough.    i. Lefkowitz  v.  Great  Minneapolis  Surplus  Store  (1957)  –  Lapin  and  house  rules  

1. Exception  to  the  general  rule  that  adverts  are  normally  deemed  to  be  only  invitations  to  deal.    

a. If  the  advert  is  definite  in  its  terms,  and  either  (i)  the  circumstances  clearly  indicate  an  intention  to  make  a  bargain,  (ii)  the  advert  invites  those  whom  it  is  addressed  to  take  a  specific  action  without  further  communication,  or  (iii)  over  acceptance  is  unlikely.  

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  11  of  27  

2. Law:  An  advert  may  be  converted  to  an  offer  when  it  promises  something  in  exchange  for  clear,  definite  action,  and  leaves  nothing  open  for  negotiation.    

3. Otherwise,  an  advert  is  an  invitation  for  an  offer.    4. What  is  really  going  on  here:  Lefkowitz  owns  the  other  fur  stores  in  the  area.    

a. K  –  why  does  he  win  on  the  second  Sat?  He  knows  what  the  house  rule  is  by  then.      

d. RST  2d.  §  30:  Form  of  Acceptance  Invited  (1)  An  offer  may  invite  or  require  acceptance  to  be  made  by  an  affirmative  answer  in  words,  or  by  performing  or  refraining  from  performing  a  specified  act,  or  may  empower  the  offeree  to  make  a  selection  of  terms  in  his  acceptance.  (2)  Unless  otherwise  indicated  by  the  language  or  the  circumstances,  an  offer  invites  acceptance  in  any  manner  and  by  any  medium  reasonable  in  the  circumstances.  

 e. RST  2d  §  50:  Acceptance  of  Offer  Defined;  Acceptance  by  Performance;  Acceptance  by  

Promise  (1)  Acceptance  of  an  offer  is  a  manifestation  of  assent  to  the  terms  thereof  made  by  the  offeree  in  a  manner  invited  or  required  by  the  offer.  (2)  Acceptance  by  performance  requires  that  at  least  part  of  what  the  offer  requests  be  performed  or  tendered  and  includes  acceptance  by  a  performance  which  operates  as  a  return  promise.  (3)  Acceptance  by  a  promise  requires  that  the  offeree  complete  every  act  essential  to  the  making  of  the  promise.  

 f. Assent/Acceptance  can  be  manifested  by  the  execution  of  a  written  document,  or  by  an  oral  

expression  of  agreement,  or  perhaps  simply  by  commencement  of  the  performance  that  the  offer  calls  for.    

 g. Mirror  Image  rule  

a. At  c/l,  an  acceptance  had  to  be  a  “mirror  image”  of  the  offer.  If  the  purported  acceptance  deviated  from  the  offer  in  any  way,  even  in  an  immaterial  way,  it  was  deemed  a  qualified  or  conditional  acceptance  and  did  not  form  a  contract;  instead  it  is  a  counteroffer.    

b. Davis  v.  Satrom  (1986)    -­‐  talks  to  buy  a  mobile  home  park  fall  through  i. Classic  example  of  c/l  doctrine.  Davis  is  nuts  to  think  he  has  a  contract.    ii. Letter  of  intent  =  offer  iii. Counteroffer  kills  the  offer.  Only  one  offer  in  place  at  any  time  iv. RST  2d  §42:  revocation  by  communication  v. UCC  §  2-­‐207:  attempts  to  try  give  a  more  reasonable  answer  than  the  practice  

of  shooting  documents  at  each  other.  c. Ardente  v.  Horan  (1976)  –  accepts  purchase  agreement,  wants  dining  set  included  –  

trying  to  claim  can  accept  the  house  plus  the  furniture?  No  contract  dude  i. RST  2d.  §§  26-­‐27  ii. “Difficult  to  replace”  –  veiled  threat  to  walk  away.  Jerky.  Quibbling  acceptance.  

Not  mirror  image.    iii. RST  2d.  §  22:  not  adding  another  link  to  the  chain  of  necessary  requirements.  

Offer  and  acceptance  is  the  typical  means  we  use  to  show  manifestation  of  mutual  assent.    

iv. RST  2d.  §  57:  Effect  of  Equivocal  Acceptance:  

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  12  of  27  

Where  notification  is  essential  to  acceptance  by  promise,  the  offeror  is  not  bound  by  an  acceptance  in  equivocal  terms  unless  he  reasonably  understands  it  as  an  acceptance.  

v. RST  2d.  §  59:  Purported  Acceptance  Which  Adds  Qualifications  A  reply  to  an  offer  which  purports  to  accept  it  but  is  conditional  on  the  offeror's  assent  to  terms  additional  to  or  different  from  those  offered  is  not  an  acceptance  but  is  a  counter-­‐offer.  

vi. RST  2d.  §  22  Mode  of  Assent:  Offer  and  Acceptance (1)  The  manifestation  of  mutual  assent  to  an  exchange  ordinarily  takes  the  form  of  an  offer  or  proposal  by  one  party  followed  by  an  acceptance  by  the  other  party  or  parties.  (2)  A  manifestation  of  mutual  assent  may  be  made  even  though  neither  offer  nor  acceptance  can  be  identified  and  even  though  the  moment  of  formation  cannot  be  determined.    

h. Raffles  v.  Wichelhaus  (Court  of  Exchequer  1864)  –The  Peerless  Rule  –  for  want  of  an  October  peerless,  my  kingdom  was  lost.    a. Where  an  expression  of  two  equally  reasonable  meanings,  and  each  party  understands  

the  expression  differently.    b. Both  parties  used  the  term  ‘ex  ship  Peerless,”  each  thinking  there  was  only  one  ship  

Peerless  when  there  were  two  and  each  intended  a  different  one.    c. The  rule  in  such  cases  is  that  if  both  parties  subjectively  attach  different,  equally  

reasonable,  interpretations  to  their  expression,  no  contract  is  formed.    i. Note:  limited  to  cases  where  two  or  more  meaning  are  equally  reasonable.  If  an  

expression  is  susceptible  of  two  or  more  meanings,  but  only  one  meaning  is  reasonable  or  one  is  more  reasonable  than  the  other,  the  objective  theory  of  contracts  prevailed  and  interpretation  is  based  on  the  reasonable  meaning.    

d. BUT,  K’s  interpretation  i. This  was  a  fairly  casual  contract.  Did  not  even  contract  about  delivery  date,  

peerless  was  mentioned  incase  ship  got  lost.    ii. D  wants  to  walk  away  because  he  regrets  entering  into  it  (price  spike  due  to  war  

in  US  at  time,  cotton  from  South  was  not  exported).  South  losing,  prices  falling,  Lawyer  finds  way  out  of  contract.    

 e. R.2d.  §  20  -­‐  Effect  of  Misunderstanding  (K  hates  this)  

(1)  There  is  no  manifestation  of  mutual  assent  to  an  exchange  if  the  parties  attach  materially  different  meanings  to  their  manifestations  and  

(a)  Neither  party  knows  or  has  reason  to  know  the  meaning  attached  by  the  other;  or  (b)  Each  party  knows  or  each  party  has  reason  to  know  the  meaning  attached  by  the  other.  

If  both  no,  contract  is  void  –  get  out  of  my  courtroom  (2)  The  manifestations  of  the  parties  are  operative  in  accordance  with  the  meaning  attached  to  them  by  one  of  the  parties  if  

(a)  That  party  does  not  know  of  any  different  meaning  attached  by  the  other,  and  the  other  knows  the  meaning  attached  by  the  first  party;  or  (b)  That  party  has  no  reason  to  know  of  any  different  meaning  attached  by  the  other,  and  the  other  has  reason  to  know  the  meaning  attached  by  the  first  party  

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  13  of  27  

 i. Evert-­‐tite  Roofing  Corp  v.  Green  (1955)  –  does  roofing  commence  when  trucks  leave  or  work  

starts?    a. Both  are  jerks  –  both  should  have  picked  up  the  phone.    b. But,  the  Green’s  are  the  true  LCA.  We  need  the  law  to  go  anti-­‐Green  even  though  

roofing  co  were  jerks.  There  is  no  ability  for  Roofing  co  to  just  cover.    i. Therefore,  must  protect  expectancy  interest  –  RST  2d.  §  344(a)    ii. Have  to  give  both  lost  profits  and  costs  iii. Should  you  split  the  baby?  Give  reliance  but  not  expectancy  to  give  incentives  to  

roofing  co  to  contact  consumer  first.      

II. Subcontractor  formation  Problem    a. RST  2d.  §87  (2):  Option  Contract  

(2)  An  offer  which  the  offeror  should  reasonably  expect  to  induce  action  or  forbearance  of  a  substantial  character  on  the  part  of  the  offeree  before  acceptance  and  which  does  induce  such  action  or  forbearance  is  binding  as  an  option  contract  to  the  extent  necessary  to  avoid  injustice.  

b. Baird  v.  Gimbel  (2d  Cir  1933)    i. Gen  Contractor  relied  on  Gen  Sub  Contractor  Bid  to  Penn  Government  and  then  

received  contract.    ii. Gen  Contractor  is  not  in  position  to  accept  sub  contractors  bid  until  after  it  was  

awarded  the  contract.  Gen  has  to  rely  before  they  can  accept.    iii. Tech  D  sub  contractor  withdraws  before  bed  it  accepted,  but  K  thinks  should  not  

be  allowed  to  withdraw.    iv. Gen  is  being  reasonable  in  its  reliance,  and  according  to  §  82,  if  it  is  reasonable  

for  you  to  rely;  you  have  the  option  without  the  payment  of  consideration.    1. Reasonable:  if  obviously  a  type  it  would  not  be  unreasonable.  If  all  bids  

are  in  69K-­‐72K  and  one  for  7,000,  obviously  not  reasonable  to  rely  on  that  one.    

c. Drennan  v.  Star  Paving  (Ca.  1958)  i. Builder,  a  gen  contractor,  wants  to  make  a  bid  on  a  school  construction  job,  

requests  plumbing  subcontractors  to  give  bids.  This  request  is  not  an  offer  to  the  subcontractors.    

ii. But  bids  by  the  subcontractors  are  offers  to  Builder.    iii. Reliance:  a  firm  offer  is  irrevocable  if  the  offeror  should  have  reasonably  

foreseen  that  the  offer  would  induce  reliance  by  the  offeree  prior  to  acceptance,  and  such  reliance  occurs.    

 III. Negotiation  and  Closure  

a. RST  2d  27:  Existence  of  Contract  Where  Written  Memorial  is  Contemplated  Manifestations  of  assent  that  are  in  themselves  sufficient  to  conclude  a  contract  will  not  be  prevented  from  so  operating  by  the  fact  that  the  parties  also  manifest  an  intention  to  prepare  and  adopt  a  written  memorial  thereof,  but  the  circumstances  may  show  that  the  agreements  are  preliminary  negotiations  

 b. Arnold  Palmer  v.  Fuqua  (6th  Cir.  1976)  –  sign  memo  of  intent,  but  leave  many  terms  open  

i. P  golf  co  filed  for  breach  against  D  golf  equipment  manufacturer.  Their  agreement  was  culminated  in  a  doc  named  “memorandum  of  intent.”  DC  ruled  for  D.  COA  Rev&Rem.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  14  of  27  

ii. To  determine  intent  to  be  bound,  look  at  entirety  of  circumstance,  full  document,  relevant  circumstances,  extrinsic  evidence.  

c. Empro  (7th  Cir  1989)  –  letter  from  Empro  about  agreement  to  work  together,  want  to  work  with  others  

i. No  liability  –  not  even  a  signature,  looks  at  language  of  document  only  ii. Easterbrook  is  satisfied  to  determine  intent  solely  from  the  language  of  the  document  

(remain  in  all  four  corners  of  the  document).    iii. Arnold  is  willing  to  override  explicit  language  in  the  document  by  looking  at  all  facts  

and  circumstances.    d. Reliance:  if  it  is  the  kind  of  thing  that  is  normally  associated  with  pre-­‐contractual  

negotiations,  you  lose.      

IV. Battle  of  the  Forms    If  the  contract  is  for  a  sale  of  goods,  the  UCC  is  the  governing  law.    

a. Attack:  i. Was  the  contract  definite?  2-­‐204:  a  contract  will  not  fail  for  indefiniteness  if  clear  

parties  intended  to  make  a  contract  ii. Was  the  form  a  counter-­‐offer?  For  it  to  be,  the  offeree  must  demonstrate  an  

unwillingness  to  proceed  with  the  transaction  unless  the  additional  or  different  terms  are  included  in  the  contract.  If  not,  you  are  in  (2),  but  Zemke  puts  us  in  three.    

b. Introduction:    i. Definitions:    

1. Merchant:  UCC  2-­‐104:  someone  with  knowledge  or  skill  in  something  2. Goods:  UCC  2-­‐105:  all  things  that  are  movable  at  the  time  of  identification  to  

the  sale  other  than  money.  ii. Common  law  rule:  LAST  SHOT  DOCTRINE:  terms  that  govern  are  the  ones  that  were  

sent  last  iii. Before  you  enter  UCC  2-­‐207  world,  you  have  to  be  in  the  ‘conditional  acceptance’  box  

and  not  the  ‘counter-­‐offer’  box.  (if  counter  offer  –  c/l)  iv. Also,  look  to  UCC  2-­‐204  about  contract  formation  v. Addresses  the  battle  of  the  forms,  but  in  2-­‐207,  there  is  no  requirement  that  you  need  

two  forms.      

c. Statue:  §  2-­‐207.  Additional  Terms  in  Acceptance  or  Confirmation.  (WILL  BE  ON  FINAL)  (1)  A  definite  and  seasonable  expression  of  acceptance  or  a  written  confirmation  which  is  sent  within  a  reasonable  time  operates  as  an  acceptance  even  though  it  states  terms  additional  to  or  different  from  those  offered  or  agreed  upon,  unless  acceptance  is  expressly  made  conditional  on  assent  to  the  additional  or  different  terms.  (2)  The  additional  terms  (modern  rule  diff  terms  get  in)  are  to  be  construed  as  proposals  for  addition  to  the  contract.  Between  merchants  such  terms  become  part  of  the  contract  unless:  

(a)  the  offer  expressly  limits  acceptance  to  the  terms  of  the  offer;    (b)  they  materially  alter  it;  or  (this  will  almost  never  be  true  if  we  are  litigating  about  it).  (c)  notification  of  objection  to  them  has  already  been  given  or  is  given  within  a  reasonable  time  after  notice  of  them  is  received.  

(3)  Conduct  by  both  parties  which  recognizes  the  existence  of  a  contract  (such  as  the  fact  that  they  have  started  to  perform)  is  sufficient  to  establish  a  contract  for  sale  although  the  writings  of  the  parties  do  not  otherwise  establish  a  contract.  (no  acceptance,  but  performance).  In  such  case  the  terms  of  the  particular  contract  consist  of  those  terms  on  

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  15  of  27  

which  the  writings  of  the  parties  agree,  together  with  any  supplementary  terms  incorporated  under  any  other  provisions  of  this  Act.  A  clever  lawyer  will  say  their  contracts  where  expressly  conditional,  thereby  getting  them  to  3.      

d. Official  Comments:    i. OC  3.  Whether  or  not  additional  or  different  terms  will  become  part  of  the  agreement  

depends  upon  the  provisions  of  subsection  (2).  If  they  are  such  as  materially  to  alter  the  original  bargain,  they  will  not  be  included  unless  expressly  agreed  to  by  the  other  party.  If,  however,  they  are  terms  which  would  not  so  change  the  bargain  they  will  be  incorporated  unless  notice  of  objection  to  them  has  already  been  given  or  is  given  within  a  reasonable  time  

ii. OC  6.  If  no  answer  is  received  within  a  reasonable  time  after  additional  terms  are  proposed,  it  is  both  fair  and  commercially  sound  to  assume  that  their  inclusion  has  been  assented  to.  Where  clauses  on  confirming  forms  sent  by  both  parties  conflict  each  party  must  be  assumed  to  object  to  a  clause  of  the  other  conflicting  with  one  on  the  confirmation  sent  by  himself.  As  a  result  the  requirement  that  there  be  notice  of  objection  which  is  found  in  subsection  (2)  is  satisfied  and  the  conflicting  terms  do  not  become  a  part  of  the  contract.  The  contract  then  consists  of  the  terms  originally  expressly  agreed  to,  terms  on  which  the  confirmations  agree,  and  terms  supplied  by  this  Act,  including  subsection  (2).    

iii. OC  7  (KNOCK  OUT  RULE):  In  such  cases,  where  the  writings  of  the  parties  do  not  establish  a  contract,  it  is  not  necessary  to  determine  which  act  or  document  constituted  the  offer  and  which  the  acceptance.  See  Section  2-­‐204.  The  only  question  is  what  terms  are  included  in  the  contract,  and  subsection  (3)  furnishes  the  governing  rule.  

 e. What  about  language  of  additional  terms  in  (2)  -­‐  Three  ways  to  interpret  2-­‐207:    

i. (1)  Official  comment  3  determined  that,  in  spite  of  the  omission,  different  terms  are  to  be  analyzed  under  2-­‐207(2).    

ii. (2)  The  omission  was  identical,  however  once  an  offeror  addresses  the  subject,  it  implicitly  objects  to  variance  of  that  subject,  thereby  obviating  the  need  to  refer  to  “different”  terms.  These  two  produce  the  same  result  (i.e.  first  shot).    

iii. (3)  From  comment  6:  different  terms  cancel  each  other  out  and  the  existing  applicable  code  provision  stand  in  their  place.  2-­‐207  was  designed  to  avoid  the  common  law  result  that  gave  the  advantage  to  the  party  sending  the  last  form,  we  cannot  conclude  that  the  statute  was  intended  to  shift  that  advantage  to  the  party  sending  the  first  form.  

 f. Gardner  Zemke    -­‐  Issue  of  warranty  air  con  chillers,  conflicting  terms  

i. Contract  conditions  on  acceptance  of  warranty,  but  court  says  no  because  form  is  pre-­‐printed,  so  not  expressly  conditional.    

ii. At  c/l,  the  mirror  image  rule  applied  to  the  formation  of  contracts  and  the  terms  of  the  acceptance  had  to  exactly  imitate  or  mirror  the  terms  of  the  offer.  If  the  accepting  terms  were  different  from  or  additional  to  those  in  the  offer,  the  result  was  a  counteroffer,  not  an  acceptance.    

iii. However,  the  drafters  of  the  code  intended  to  change  the  common  law  in  an  attempt  to  conform  contract  law  to  modern  day  business  transactions.  Where  preprinted  forms  are  used  to  structure  deals,  they  rarely  mirror  each  other,  and  yet  the  parties  usually  assume  they  have  a  binding  contract  and  act  accordingly.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  16  of  27  

iv. Where  merchants  exchange  preprinted  forms  and  the  essential  contract  terms  agree,  a  contract  is  formed  under  section  2-­‐207(1).  A  responding  document  will  fall  outside  the  provisions  of  section  2-­‐207(1)  and  be  a  counteroffer  only  when  its  terms  radically  differ  from  the  offer,  or  when  “acceptance  is  expressly  made  conditional  on  assent  to  the  additional  or  different  terms.”  1. The  court  concluded  that  the  “expressly  conditional”  provision  of  2-­‐207(1)  was  

intended  to  apply  only  to  an  acceptance,  which  clearly  reveals  that  the  offeree  is  unwilling  to  proceed  with  the  transaction  unless  he  is  assured  of  the  offeror’s  assent  to  the  additional  or  different  terms  therein.    

a. Q:  Did  he  clearly  and  unequivocally  communicate  to  the  offeror  that  its  willingness  to  enter  into  a  bargain  was  conditioned  on  the  offeror’s  assent  to  the  additional  or  different  terms.    

b. Boilerplate  contracts  will  not  be  expressly  conditional,  therefore  not  counteroffers.    

g. K’s  summary    i. §2-­‐207(1)  –  before  the  comma,  repudiates  mirror  image  rule.  After  comma,  last  shot  

doctrine.    ii. §2-­‐207(2)  –  turns  the  last  shot  doctrine  into  the  first  shot  doctrine  iii. §2-­‐207(3)  –  knock  out  rule.    iv. Default  rules:  course  of  dealings  and  course  of  trade  

 V. The  Software  Problem  and  Rolling  Contracts    

a. UCC  §  2-­‐204.  Formation  in  General.  (1)  A  contract  for  sale  of  goods  may  be  made  in  any  manner  sufficient  to  show  agreement,  including  conduct  by  both  parties  which  recognizes  the  existence  of  such  a  contract.  (2)  An  agreement  sufficient  to  constitute  a  contract  for  sale  may  be  found  even  though  the  moment  of  its  making  is  undetermined.  (3)  Even  though  one  or  more  terms  are  left  open  a  contract  for  sale  does  not  fail  for  indefiniteness  if  the  parties  have  intended  to  make  a  contract  and  there  is  a  reasonably  certain  basis  for  giving  an  appropriate  remedy.  

 b. Form  contract  problem  

i. In  general  form  contracts  are  enforceable,  unless  they  have  an  unconscionable  term.    ii. Reason:  (1)  backstops  of  unconscionability  and  (2)  competition  

1. Competition  is  not  perfect  protection  for  consumers,  but  in  general  imperfect  competition  will  beat  imperfect  judges.    

2. Ultimately,  there  will  be  higher  transaction  costs  born  by  consumers  if  (2)  is  rejected.      

iii. RST  2d  §  211(3)  and  Comment  F:  standard  form  contracts  (3)  Where  the  other  party  has  reason  to  believe  that  the  party  manifesting  such  assent  would  not  do  so  if  he  knew  that  the  writing  contained  a  particular  term,  the  term  is  not  part  of  the  agreement.  1. Official  comment  F:  terms  excluded:  not  bound  to  terms  that  are  beyond  

reasonable  expectation.  This  is  a  standard,  not  a  rule,  but  it  makes  sense.  K:  Lets  not  revert  to  cave  man  society;  we  need  some  standard  form  contracts  around  here!  

c. Rolling  Contracts  problem:    i. E.G.  Geico  

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  17  of  27  

ii. Consumer  or  purchaser  enters  into  the  contract  with  things  such  as  price,  quantity  and  delivery  date  settled.  Later,  the  contract  is  delivered.    

iii. K  doesn’t  think  the  difference  here  matters  –  no  one  in  fact  reads  contracts  1. Form  contracts  (Best  Buy)  are  about  adhesion  (take  it  or  leave  it)  2. Rolling  contracts  are  about  timing  

d. Box  top  license  scenario:  three  options:    i. Offer  and  acceptance  already  occurred  over  the  phone  ii. License  is  an  acceptance  with  additional  terms  iii. Phone  is  preliminary  negotiation  and  box  top  is  offer.  Opening  the  box  and  keeping  is  

an  acceptance.    e. Step-­‐Saver:    

i. Agreement  to  transact  over  the  phone,  follow  up  with  written  purchase  order,  only  warranty  is  on  box  top  when  delivered.  (Does  UCC  govern?  Software  a  good  or  service?)  

ii. Court  says  contract  made  on  the  phone,  box  top  just  proposed  additions  1. 2-­‐204(3):  even  though  one  or  more  terms  is  left  open  the  contract  can  be  

accepted  if  there  is  reasonable  basis  for  providing  the  remedy.    2. Not  crucial  to  the  fact  that  there  is  a  contract  to  determine  when  exactly  one  was  

formed.    3. Was  the  box  top  licence  a  counter  offer?    

a. If  price,  quantity  and  delivery  date  are  different  =  counter  offer.  Warranty  is  a  conditional  acceptance.  Tests:    i. Counter  Offer:  Is  the  response  a  conditional  acceptance  to  the  extent  

it  states  a  term  that  materially  alters  the  contractual  obligations  solely  to  the  disadvantage  of  the  offeror?    

ii. Conditional  Acceptance:  uses  key  words  for  phrases,  e.g.  these  terms  are  the  only  ones  upon  which  we  will  accept  orders.  (K  thinks  this  is  illogical  –  how  seriously  do  you  want  to  take  pre-­‐printed  forms)  

4. Back  up  test:  Wisdom  is  not  persuaded  the  TSL  would  not  have  gone  through  with  the  deal  if  the  warranty  term  had  been  rejected.    

iii. Conclusion:  TSL’s  warranties  are  just  proposals  for  addition  to  contract.    1. TSL’s  C’  does  not  get  in,  step  saver  is  entitled  to  C”  2. C”  is  default,  which  can  come  from  c/l  or  UCC.    3. UCC  remedies  will  replace  the  c/l  remedies.    4. If  step  saver  had  term  C,  UCC  2-­‐207(1)  would  apply.  Since  no,  (2)  and  (3)  give  us  

the  same  answer  –  knock  out  C’  and  make  it  C”.    f. Hill  v.  Gateway  –  term  requiring  arbitration,  inconvenient  for  consumer.    

i. Easterbrook  being  a  weirdo  by  not  using  2-­‐207  because  only  one  form  (not  called  battle  of  the  forms  dude)  and  by  allowing  the  terms  to  get  in.    

ii. Reasoning  –  high  transaction  costs  without  the  enforcement.    iii. K  thinks  there  should  be  a  higher  standard  of  reasonableness  about  the  arbitration  

clause.      

VI. Reasonable  Expectations      a. Reasonable  expectations  is  really  only  relevant  or  robust  in  insurance  law.    b. C&J  Fertilizer  –  insurance  policy  weird  definition  of  burglary  

i. Burglary  definition:  risk  allocation:  the  insurance  company  does  not  want  to  assign  risks  to  itself  when  the  LCA  is  the  company  insured.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  18  of  27  

ii. It  is  reasonable  for  the  insurance  company  to  have  the  rule,  but  the  rule  misfired  –  it  was  not  an  inside  job.    

iii. Forcing  the  insurance  company  to  call  attention  to  its  idiosyncratic  terms  reduces  transaction  costs.    

 THE  NECESSITY  AND  EFFECT  OF  A  WRITING    

I. Statute  of  Frauds    U.C.C.  §  2-­‐201:  Formal  Requirements,  Statute  of  Frauds  

1) Except  as  otherwise  provided,  a  contract  for  sale  of  goods  for  $500  or  more,  is  not  enforceable  by  way  of  action  or  defense  unless  there  is  some  writing  sufficient  to  indicate  that  a  contract  for  sale  has  been  made  between  the  parties  and  signed  by  the  party  against  whom  enforcement  is  sought  or  by  his  authorized  agent  or  broker.    

2) Between  merchants,  if  within  reasonable  time,  a  writing  in  confirmation  of  the  contract  and  sufficient  against  the  sender  is  received  and  the  party  receiving  it  has  reason  to  know  its  contents,  it  satisfies  the  requirements  of  (1)  against  such  party  unless  written  notice  of  objection  to  its  contents  is  given  within  10  days  after  it  is  received  

3) A  contract  which  does  not  satisfy  requirements  of  (1)  but  which  is  valid  in  other  respects,  is  enforceable:  

a. If  the  goods  are  to  be  specially  manufactured  for  the  buyer…  b. If  the  party  against  whom  enforcement  is  sought  admits  in  his  pleading  that  a  

contract  for  sale  was  made…  c. With  respect  to  goods  for  which  payment  has  been  made  and  accepted  or  which  

have  been  received  and  accepted  a. In  general:  absent  a  statute  that  provides  otherwise,  oral  contracts  are  enforceable.  

However,  the  Statute  of  Frauds  requires  certain  types  of  contracts  to  be  memorialised  in  a  writing  signed  by  “the  party  to  be  charged”  (i.e.  by  the  party  against  whom  enforcement  of  the  contract  is  sought).    i. Terminology  

1. “Within  the  statute”  -­‐  If  an  oral  contract  falls  within  one  of  the  categories  of  contracts  that  must  be  memorialised  in  a  writing  under  the  SOF  

a. i.e.  the  SOF  is  a  defence  to  enforcement  of  the  contract,  unless  some  expectation  applies.    

b. Unenforceable  against  a  party  who  has  not  signed  a  written  memo  containing  the  contracts  material  terms  

2. “Taken  out  of  the  Statute”  –  if  an  exception  does  apply,  i.e.  the  statute  is  not  a  defence.    

ii. Purpose:  prevent  fraud  and  perjury  by  persons  who  might  falsely  claim  that  a  contract  was  made.    

iii. Types  of  contracts  that  must  be  memorialised  in  writing:  (1)  Contracts  for  the  sale  of  an  interest  in  land;  (2)  contracts  for  the  sale  of  goods  (now  covered  by  the  UCC);  (3)  contracts  in  consideration  of  marriage;  (4)  contracts  not  to  be  performed  within  one  year  from  the  making  thereof,  and  (5)  contracts  of  suretyship  

b. Contracts  for  the  sale  of  goods  –  UCC  §  2-­‐201  i. A  contract  for  the  sale  of  any  goods  for  the  price  of  $500  or  more  must  be  supported  

by  a  writing.    ii. “Goods”  Defined:  includes  all  tangible  movable  property.  It  does  not  include  intangible  

securities  or  service.    iii. Exceptions:  when  an  oral  contract  for  the  sale  of  goods  for  $500  or  more  will  be  

enforced:    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  19  of  27  

1. Receipt  and  acceptance  of  goods:  the  buyer  received  and  accepts  all  or  part  of  the  goods  

2. Part  Payment  3. Special  Manufacture:  the  contract  calls  for  the  manufacture  of  special  goods  for  

the  buyer  not  suitable  for  sale  to  others  in  the  ordinary  course  of  the  seller’s  business,  and  the  seller  makes  either  a  “substantial  beginning”  in  the  manufacture  of  the  goods  or  “commitments”  for  their  procurement.    

4. No  objection  to  confirmation:  the  contract  is  between  merchants;  within  a  reasonable  time  a  written  confirmation,  which  satisfies  the  SOF  as  to  the  sender,  is  sent;  and  the  party  receiving  the  confirmation  does  not  dispatch  a  written  objection  thereto  within  10  days.  [U.C.C.  §  2-­‐201(2)]  

5. Admission:  the  contract  is  admitted  by  the  party  against  whom  enforcement  is  sought  “in  his  pleadings  or  testimony  in  court.”  [UCC  §  2-­‐201(3)(b)]  

iv. Modifications  1. A  modification  of  a  contract  for  the  sale  of  goods  is  within  the  SOF  if  the  new  

agreement  that  results  from  putting  together  the  original  contract  and  the  modification  is  within  the  statute.    

c. Contracts  that  cannot  be  performed  within  one  year  of  making    i. The  one-­‐year  period  begins  at  the  date  the  contract  is  made,  not  when  performance  is  

promised.      

d. Klewin  –  shook  hands  and  agreed  at  dinner  meeting  that  Klewin  would  serve  as  construction  manager  for  the  project  i. Flagship  was  dissatisfied  after  the  first  part  –  wanted  a  new  manager  ii. Whether  agreement  is  under  SOF  –  whether  it  could  possibly  be  completed  within  one  

year  –  does  not  need  to  be  written  down  iii. K  hates  this  –  there  should  be  some  incentives  here,  and  there  seems  to  be  a  difference  

between  the  phase  one  and  the  phase  two  contract.  Also,  it  is  obvious  that  this  could  not  be  completed  within  one  year  –  but  since  indefinite,  through  a  tortured  interpretation,  enforces.  It  is  weird;  some  judges  seem  to  be  on  a  crusade  against  SOF.      

e. Migerobe  –  loss  leader  watch  sale  turns  bitter  i. Court  allows  them  to  sting  together  documents  from  their  filing  cabinets,  one  of  which  

is  signed,  to  have  an  enforceable  contract  ii. Again,  SOF  doesn’t  work  the  way  it  should.    iii. K  is  not  nearly  as  outraged  by  this  case  as  by  Klewin,  but  “I  thought  that  the  purpose  of  

SOF  was  to  get  people  to  write  down  their  contracts,  not  stitch  together  stuff  from  their  filing  cabinets.”      

f. Conagra    -­‐  oral  agreement  for  sale  of  wheat  –  not  followed  through,  Conagra  covers  i. We  are  clearly  between  merchants.  Big  farmer.    

1. Normally  do  not  want  silence  to  an  assent  -­‐  it  makes  the  offeror  less  of  a  master  of  the  offer.    

2. But  we  change  that  c/l  rule  between  merchants  -­‐  trying  to  promote  communication  (bailey)  

3. If  ConAgra  is  nice  and  send  a  confirmation,  the  Nierenberg’s  are  supposed  to  play  ball  -­‐  lift  their  little  pinkie  finger  and  talk!  K  likes  this  -­‐  as  long  as  it  is  just  between  merchants!    

4. (Note  an  email  can  constitute  a  signature  –  modern  world).    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  20  of  27  

ii. Official  comment  1  The  required  writing  need  not  contain  all  the  material  terms  of  the  contract  and  such  material  terms  as  are  stated  need  not  be  precisely  stated.  All  that  is  required  is  that  the  writing  afford  a  basis  for  believing  that  the  offered  oral  evidence  rests  on  a  real  transaction.  It  may  be  written  in  lead  pencil  on  a  scratch  pad.  It  need  not  indicate  which  party  is  the  buyer  and  which  the  seller.    

g. Lige  Dickson  i. For  roughly  a  decade,  paving  contractor  purchases  asphalt  from  union.  ii. Course  of  dealing:  Lige  gets  a  contract,  telephones  Union  and  place  an  order.  The  

practice/course  of  dealing  is  that  after  telephonic  order,  Lige  received  a  written  invoice  from  union.  Although  there  is  writing  in  place,  they  do  not  otherwise  have  a  contract.    1. When  price  of  oil  drifts  up,  union  gives  Lige  price  protection.    2. At  t0,  Lige  contracts  with  homeowner,  at  t1  Lige  contracts  with  union,  t2  Lige  

does  the  paving.    3. Union  will  offer  asphalt  at  t0  price,  because  Lige  contracted  with  homeowner  

when  the  price  of  oil  was  at  t0  and  so  union  covers  the  loss.  Given  the  spike  in  oil  in  ‘73,  union  finds  internalising  the  loss  of  the  t0-­‐t1  price  difference  (which  is  a  practice,  not  something  written  down)  as  too  costly.    

4. As  a  result  Lige  will  lose  money  on  a  bunch  of  contracts  they  entered  into  at  t0.  Lige  is  upset  over  their  loss  and  they  sue  seeking  the  enforcement  in  price  protection  that  they  have  been  receiving  for  the  past  several  years  (course  of  dealing).  It  would  be  an  enforceable  oral  contract,  except  that  it  is  within  the  SOF  –  over  $500  –  there  has  to  be  a  writing  signed  by  union  and  there  is  not.  

iii. Therefore,  SOF  says  that  not  enforceable.  1. Finally,  the  SOF  works  the  way,  from  my  armchair,  I  thought  it  was  supposed  to  

work.  2. Who  better  bore  the  risk?  LCA  analysis:  difficult  to  say  -­‐  need  to  know  more  

about  the  industry.  Who  should  the  lose  fall  on?  It  is  best  to  allow  the  smaller  business  to  take  the  loss,  rather  than  Union  who  would  have  to  cover  everyone  and  go  out  of  business.  

h. K  Commentary:  Likes  SOF.  Without  it,  there  will  be  opportunity  for  a  buyer  or  seller  to  opportunistically  exit.  Therefore,  no  one  would  contract  and  we  would  be  at  (0,  0).  World  with  SOF  gets  us  to  (1,  1).    

 II. Parol  Evidence  Rule    

a. The  Rule:  parol  evidence  will  not  be  admitted  to  vary,  add  to,  or  contradict  a  written  contract  that  constitutes  an  integration.    

b. Governs  the  effect  of  a  written  agreement  on  any  prior  oral  or  written  agreements  between  the  parties.    i. A  full  and  final  expression  of  the  parties  agreement  may  not  be  supplemented  or  

contradicted  by  any  oral  or  written  agreements  made  prior  1. Does  not  bar  evidence  of  oral  agreement  after  the  writing  2. Does  not  bar  evidence  about  the  meaning  the  parties  intended  to  give  to  

contract  terms    c. General  notes:    

i. Parol  evidence  rule  divides  into  three  kinds:  unintegrated  agreements,  partially  integrated  and  fully  integrated  agreements.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  21  of  27  

1. Unintegrated  writing  -­‐  no  privileging  of  the  written  document.  It  is  relevant  but  so  is  all  your  oral  testimony.  For  example,  the  cocktail  napkin  scrawl  setting  out  business  negotiation  is  an  unintegrated  agreement.  

2. A  partially  integrated  agreement  is  more  formal,  and  because  more  formal,  parol  evidence  will  privilege  it  over  oral  testimony  that  contradicts  it.  BUT  oral  testimony  that  supplements  it  is  admissible.    

a. For  example,  A  and  B  are  the  final  word  on  A  and  B.  We  could  still  have  oral  evidence  of  C  and  D,  but  not  evidence  that  says  not  A  and  B.  A  clever  lawyer  can  always  cast  a    ‘not  B’  into  a  C.    

b. Normally,  a  partially  integrated  agreement  is  something  that  looks  like  it  is  more  formal,  i.e.  typed  up.    

c. You  privilege  the  written  A  and  B,  exclude  not  A  and  not  B,  but  can  supplement  C  and  D.    

3. A  fully  integrated  document:    a  conclusion  that  it  is  the  final  and  complete  agreement  between  the  parties.  Never  allow  testimony  of  C  and  D.  Consists  of  whatever  terms  the  parties  have  written  down  and  then  sub  in  default  rules  when  necessary  

a. A  fully  integrated  agreement  will  have  a  merger  clause  –  ‘this  is  the  final  and  complete  agreement  between  the  parties.’  Just  like  there  was  the  question  in  Zemke,  but  will  contracts  won’t  normally  show  full  integration?  Better  have  it  specific  and  upfront  rather  than  buried.  

ii. The  default  is  partially  integrated.  Only  if  they  seem  to  really  mean  it  is  it  fully  integrated,  and  only  super  informal  (contract  napkin)  agreements  are  unintegrated.    

iii. C/l  has  an  additional  test  on  whether  C  can  get  in  on  a  partially  integrated  agreement  -­‐natural  omission  test.  R2d  §216(2).  

d. Natural  omission  test:    i. Parol  evidence  is  admissible  of  it  concerns  a  term  that  would  naturally  be  omitted  from  

the  agreement.    ii. Under  the  R.2d.  §216,  a  term  will  be  treated  as  naturally  omitted  if  

1. The  term  does  not  conflict  with  the  written  integration    2. The  term  concerns  a  subject  that  similarly  situated  parties  would  not  ordinarily  

be  expected  to  include  in  the  written  agreement.    e. UCC  says  it  gets  in  as  a  default  unless  it  is  the  sort  of  thing  that  naturally  would  have  been  

excluded.  If  you  cannot  say  whether  it  would  have  been  omitted,  it  gets  in.    f. UCC  §  2-­‐202:  Final  Written  Expression  (movable)-­‐  try  to  tweak  the  parol  evidence  rule  for  

partially  integrated  agreements.  Terms  with  respect  to  which  the  confirmatory  memoranda  of  the  parties  agree  or  which  are  otherwise  set  forth  in  writing  intended  by  the  parties  as  a  final  expression  of  their  agreement  with  respect  to  such  terms  as  are  included  therein  may  not  be  contradicted  by  evidence  of  any  prior  agreement  or  of  a  contemporaneous  oral  agreement  but  may  be  explained  or  supplemented  

• By  course  of  dealing  or  usage  of  trade  or  by  course  of  performance  • By  evidence  of  consistent  additional  terms  unless  the  court  finds  the  writing  

to  have  been  intended  also  as  a  complete  and  exclusive  statement  of  terms  of  the  agreement  

i. Not  contracted  (not  A  or  B)  but  can  be  explained  or  supplemented  (C  or  D).    g. Mitchill:  icehouse  case  

i. Buys  the  property,  just  a  standard  form  contract  for  sales  of  real  property.  The  standard  form  does  not  contemplate  agreements  about  adjacent  properties.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  22  of  27  

1. Perhaps  that  is  why  it  is  natural  to  omit  it,  because  it  is  not  standard  to  discuss  adjacent  properties  

2. Received  oral  contract  for  the  tearing  down  of  icehouse.  She  sues  seeking  to  enforce  the  oral  promise.  Have  a  contract  for  sale  of  farm  between  Lath  and  Mitchill,  which  has  terms  such  as  price,  quantity  and  delivery  date,  and  she  wants  to  bring  in  term  Z.  there  is  no  reason  to  think  this  is  complete  (no  merger  clause)  but  it  is  more  formal.  

3. Therefore,  partially  integrated  agreement  and  the  natural  omission  test  will  be  applied.    

ii. ANDREWS:  I  understand  it  will  be  over  and  under  conclusive  but  on  the  whole  it  works  for  the  good.  As  a  pragmatic  matter,  generally  follow  tradition,  but  when  need  be  pay  attention  to  social  concerns.  Always  trying  to  do  good.  Utilitarian.    

iii. Three  conditions  must  exist  before  an  oral  agreement  can  vary  the  written  contract:    1. The  agreement  in  form  be  a  collateral  one  (side  agreement)  -­‐  met  here  2. Must  not  contradict  written  contract  -­‐  seems  met  here  -­‐  Z  term  and  not  A  or  B  3. Not  ordinarily  expect  to  be  embodied  -­‐  that  is  to  say  natural  omission  test.    

a. Comes  down  to  this.  Would  it  be  natural  to  omit  icehouse.  Who  knows?  Seems  like  a  cultural  thing.  It  was  standard  form  contract  (for)  but  seems  kind  of  unusual  and  therefore  not  the  sort  of  thing  you  would  naturally  omit  (against).    

b. K  doesn't  know  so  he  hates  natural  omission  test.      MISTAKE  AND  EXCUSE  

I. In  general:  Mistake  in  contract  law  falls  into  five  categories:  (1)  mutual  mistake;  (2)  unilateral  mistake;  (3)  mistake  in  transcription;  (4)  misunderstanding;  (5)  mistake  in  transmission    

II. Mutual  Mistake  –  a  mistaken  assumption  shared  by  both  parties  as  to  the  conditions  of  the  outside  world.    a. Modern  rule:  where  parties  enter  into  a  contract  under  a  mutual  mistake  concerning  a  basic  

assumption  of  fact  on  which  the  contract  was  made,  the  contract  is  voidable  by  the  adversely  affected  party  if  the  mistake  has  a  material  effect  on  the  agreed  exchange  and  the  adversely  affected  party  did  not  bear  the  risk  that  the  assumption  was  mistaken.  [R.2d.  §  152]  

III. Sherwood  v.  Walker  a. Facts:  not-­‐so-­‐barren  cow  sold  at  lower  cost  than  worth.    b. Held:  Judgement  for  D.  court  found  parties  misapprehension  regarding  the  barren  

nature  of  the  cow  went  to  the  substance  of  the  agreement.  Agreement  was  therefore  void.    

c. Dissent:  no  evidence  that  the  P  did  not  understand  what  he  was  buying.  As  such,  he  may  not  have  been  mistaken  in  what  he  was  buying  and  should  have  been  able  to  recover.    

d. Class  Notes:    i. K  doesn’t  like  mutual  mistake  doctrine.  Best  justification  he  can  find:    

1. T0  –  T1:  cow  sold  but  marshans  invade  (new  unexpected  world,  contract  should  not  hold).    

ii. D’s  violating  Meta  rule  1,  they  regret  having  sold  cow  at  lower  cost.    iii. The  trial  court  gets  it  right.    iv. EFFICENT  BREACH:    

1. Although  99%  chance  that  the  cow  is  barren,  1%  chance  that  it  could  be  a  barren  producing  cow.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  23  of  27  

a. Therefore,  if  Sherwood  brought  the  cow  as  a  lottery  ticket,  no  reason  to  take  it  away  just  because  it  paid  off.    

2. Reward  the  smarter  person  –  makes  for  better  economics,  stronger  society.  Doing  the  opposite  is  wasteful:    

a. Greek  Vase  example:  Expertise  of  the  guy  buying  the  vase  wins  over  the  seller  who  casually  acquired  it  and  is  using  it  as  an  umbrella  holder.  The  expert  does  not  have  to  disclose  his  carefully  acquired  expertise,  even  though  seller  may  have  to  disclose  casually  acquired  info.  Want  to  protect  expertise  and  not  raise  transaction  costs.    

3. Create  incentives!  We  don’t  want  the  seller  to  opportunistically  breach  for  his  own  mistake  

IV. Krell  v.  Henry  a. Facts:  D  rented  a  flat  to  watch  coronation  of  the  King,  paid  deposit  but  coronation  got  

cancelled,  D  not  liable  for  remaining  balance.    b. Held:  when  the  subject  of  the  contract  is  frustrated  non-­‐performance  of  one  of  the  

parties  is  excused.  c. Class  notes:  K  likes  this  case!  

i. LCA:  cheaper  risk  bearer  is  the  guy  renting  out  the  apartment,  not  the  guy  renting  it  (who  bears  very  little  risk).    

1. P  only  bears  the  transaction  cost  of  having  to  reschedule  the  renting  out  of  the  apartment.    

2. LOWEST-­‐COST  RISK  BEARER:  Assign  the  risk  to  the  party  who  bears  the  lowest  risk  cost.    

ii. Should  he  get  the  deposit  back?  It  depends  on  the  role  the  deposit  is  playing.    1. Hostage  taker:  if  passport  given  to  preserve  option,  give  back  passport.  

But  monetary  deposit’s  could  be  doing  different  things  2. To  ensure  against  backing  out:  D  didn’t  technically  back  out.    3. Split  the  baby:  let  P  keep  deposit.  Allow  D  not  to  pay  remainder.    

V. Foreseeablity  and  Excuse    a. If  it  was  a  foreseeable  risk,  mistake/excuse  does  not  apply    

i. Why  would  you  magically  assign  the  unforeseeable  risk  to  someone  who  does  not  bear  the  foreseeable  risk?  This  is  why  K  hates  this.  

b. When  asking  to  be  excused,  it  is  normally  due  to  unforeseen  circumstances.  Therefore,  it  is  up  to  the  Rhetorical  skills  of  the  parties  to  convince  the  court  as  to  what  was  foreseeable.    

c. General  v.  Specific    i. General:  the  more  general  terms  you  use  to  describe  the  unforeseen  

circumstance,  the  more  foreseeable  it  will  seem  1. Columbian  coffee  to  Seattle  shipping  example:  You  contracted  at  a  fixed  

shipping  cost;  it  is  foreseeable  that  your  shipping  costs  would  increase  for  various  reasons  (labour,  petrol,  geographic,  etc.)  You  would  not  be  seeking  excuse  if  your  fixed  shipping  costs  went  down.  You  should  have  gone  with  variable.    

ii. Specific:  the  more  specific,  the  more  unforeseeable  1. Was  it  foreseeable  that  right  wing  monarchs  in  Panama  would  seize  

power  and  close  down  the  canal?        

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  24  of  27  

REMEDIES  I. Attack:    

a. The  measure  of  damages:  (Market  Price  –  Contract  Price)  +  incidentals.    b. What  are  they  asking  for?    c. Is  it  reasonable?    d. Should  it  be  expectation,  reliance  or  restitution  e. What  about  liability  rule/property  rule  protection?  Sheeping  and  Dogging  f. Does  it  even  matter  –  Coase  

 II. RST  2d  §344  Purposes  of  Remedies    

(a)  His  “expectation  interest,”  which  is  his  interest  in  having  the  benefit  of  his  bargain  by  being  put  in  as  good  a  position  as  he  would  have  been  in  had  the  contract  been  performed,  (b)  His  “reliance  interest,”  which  is  his  interest  in  being  reimbursed  for  loss  caused  by  reliance  on  the  contract  by  being  put  in  as  good  a  position  as  he  would  have  been  in  had  the  contract  not  been  made,  or  (c)  His  “restitution  interest,”  which  is  his  interest  in  having  restored  to  him  any  benefit  that  he  has  conferred  on  the  other  party.  

 III. RST  §  359  Effect  of  Adequacy  of  Damages  

(1)  Specific  performance  or  an  injunction  will  not  be  ordered  if  damages  would  be  adequate  to  protect  the  expectation  interest  of  the  injured  party.  (2)  The  adequacy  of  the  damage  remedy  for  failure  to  render  one  part  of  the  performance  due  does  not  preclude  specific  performance  or  injunction  as  to  the  contract  as  a  whole.  (3)  Specific  performance  or  an  injunction  will  not  be  refused  merely  because  there  is  a  remedy  for  breach  other  than  damages,  but  such  a  remedy  may  be  considered  in  exercising  discretion  under  the  rule  stated  in  §  357.    

IV. RST  §  360  Factors  Affecting  Adequacy  of  Damages  In  determining  whether  the  remedy  in  damages  would  be  adequate,  the  following  circumstances  are  significant:  

(a)  The  difficulty  of  proving  damages  with  reasonable  certainty,  (b)  The  difficulty  of  procuring  a  suitable  substitute  performance  by  means  of  money  awarded  as  damages,  and  (c)  The  likelihood  that  an  award  of  damages  could  not  be  collected.  

 V. Default  in  contract  law  is  expectancy  damages.    

a. From  an  ex-­‐anti  perspective,  you  want  the  promise  to  be  reliable,  but  not  more  reliable  than  it  is  worth.  Punitive  damages  would  raise  transaction  costs.    

i. Prefer  $100  rule  with  expectancy  damages,  but  not  $120  with  punitive.  I  want  the  promise  to  be  sufficiently  reliable  but  don’t  want  to  overpay  for  reliable  because  I  don't  need  super  duper  reliability  and  am  not  willing  to  pay  for  it.  

VI. Freund  a. Facts:  D  contracted  to  publish  a  book  written  by  P.  P  delivered  manuscript  and  received  

advance,  but  D  merged  and  refused  to  publish  book.    b. Option  for  damages:  (1)  loss  of  promotion,  (2)  royalties,  (3)  cost  of  publication.    

i. Problem  with  (3):  if  you  have  a  contract  with  oxford  university  press  that  they  will  publish  your  book,  they  breach,  and  give  you  cost  of  publication.  That  doesn’t  fulfill  you.  There  is  prestige  in  the  publishing  that  is  not  reflected  in  the  cost  of  publication.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  25  of  27  

1. It’s  like  giving  your  heirloom  watch  to  a  watch  repair  man  and  then  he  wants  to  give  you  an  objective  value  -­‐  no  give  me  my  watch  back!  

ii. Better  remedy:  specific  performance    (getting  a  book  published  is  more  personal  than  other  types  of  coverage).      

iii. K  also  likes  remedy  (2)  -­‐  this  is  not  his  first  book,  look  at  history.  If  his  previous  sales  were  $70K,  80K  and  90K,  it’s  not  unrealistic  to  say  80  as  opposed  to  0.    

1. Also,  interlibrary  purchasing:  Look  and  see  who  buys  Washington  square  documents  in  respect  to  interlibrary  purchasing.    

2. Also,  civil  discovery  -­‐  if  there  was  email  within  co  about  what  his  percentage  should  be  with  respect  to  royalties  calculating  his  past  sales.  

 II. Peevyhouse  -­‐  do  they  deserve  property  or  liability  rule  protection?  

About  sheeping  v.  dogging;  Coase  and  liability  rule  protection.  Some  cynicism  that  your  choice  will  even  matter.    

a. Facts:  Ps  leased  their  farmland  to  D  for  strip-­‐mining  on  the  condition  that  D  fill  in  the  holes  D  made  after  the  completion  of  the  mining.  D  did  not  fill  the  holes.    

b. Law:  Damages  for  breach  of  contract  cannot  be  so  excessive  that  they  cause  economic  waste.    

i. Case  law,  statute  and  Restatement  limit  damages  to  those  that  do  not  cause  economic  waste  or  to  those  damages  where  the  costs  involved  are  not  disproportional  to  the  end  obtained.  Ps  may  not  gain  more  in  damages  for  a  breach  of  contract  that  actual  performance  is  worth.    

ii. It  is  unlikely  that  a  reasonable  landowner  would  spend  $29,000  to  increase  the  value  of  a  piece  of  land  by  $300.    

c. Choose  liability  rule  protection:  not  perform,  pay  objective  value  of  damage  -­‐  $300.    d. Comes  down  to  what  are  we  doing  around  here?  If  we  are  strip  mining  we  don't  destroy  

50  acres  of  land.  On  the  other  hand,  if  we  are  in  a  war  with  Canada  and  we  are  losing,  liability  rule  protection.    

e. Endowment  effect:  mug  and  candy  bar  example:  if  give  half  the  room  a  mug  and  half  the  room  a  candy  bar:  very  few  people  will  transact  even  given  the  chance,  people  attach  a  sentimental  value  to  what  they  were  given  in  30  sec.    

f. Coase:  The  society  might  value  strip  mining  versus  property,  so  all  that  will  change  is  allocation  of  wealth.  In  property  rule  protection,  the  Peevyhouses  are  richer.  In  liability  rule  protection,  the  mining  company  is  richer.  It  doesn't  matter  which  you  choose,  just  affects  distribution.    

     III. Hadley  v.  Baxendale:    

a. Facts:  Involves  a  mill  that  lost  profits  due  to  the  delay  in  delivery  of  a  new  crank  shaft.    b. Law:  unless  special  circumstances  are  clearly  communicated,  damages  resulting  from  a  

breach  of  contract  should  be  only  those  that  may  be  fairly  and  reasonably  considered  at  the  time  the  contract  was  made.    

c. Takeaway:  you  are  treated  as  normal  guy.  If  you  are  idiosyncratic,  and  didn’t  have  a  spare  shaft,  reveal  yourself  and  I  will  charge  you  more.    

d. ALREADY  EMMESHED  IN  LAW:  you  are  not  a  jerk  if  the  rule  is  property  rule  protection  so  respecting  rights  when  put  a  check  in  the  mail.  

       

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  26  of  27  

*Calabresi  Article:  Property    1. Three  types  of  protection:    

1. Property  Rule  Protection  –  your  right  in  the  property  is  alienable  a. You  can  sell  it,  but  it  allows  you  to  place  a  high  price  on  the  item;  do  not  have  to  

sell  for  an  objective  value.    b. Can  gift  it  c. Robust  State  protection  and  illegitimate  boarder  crossings:  if  you  come  into  my  

garage  and  steal  my  car  I  call  the  cops  (robust  –  criminal  law;  illegitimate  –  non-­‐consensual).    

2. Liability  Rule  Protection  a. Weaker  state  protection:  the  violator  only  needs  to  drop  a  cheque  in  the  mail  

based  on  the  objective  value  of  my  property.    i. If  the  car  is  in  your  garage,  property  rule  protection.  If  on  the  street  liability  

rule  protection.    b. The  transaction  costs  are  to  high  to  have  property  rule  protection  on  the  car  you  

drive  on  the  road  amongst  society.  (E.g.  someone  might  fabricate  the  sentimental  value  of  their  car).    

3. Inalienability  a. Robust  Protection  b. Can  gift,  but  cannot  sell  c. E.G.  body  parts,  sexual  services  

2. The  choice  between  liability  rule  protection  (damages)  and  property  rule  protection  (specific  performance)  is  at  dispute  in  many  cases.    

3. Calabresi  creates  a  fourth  rule  for  dealing  with  polluters:    a. Three  traditional  ways:    

i. Don’t  pollute:  property  rule  protection  to  enjoyers  1. This  does  not  mean  no  pollution  -­‐  property  rule  protection  is  alienable.  2. The  enjoyers  can  sell  their  rights  to  the  polluters  (i.e.  the  polluters  pay  

the  enjoyers  to  not  call  the  EPA)  ii. Pollution  is  ok:  property  rule  protection  for  polluters  

1. Some  polluters  may  sell  their  rights  to  the  enjoyers.    iii. Tax  pollution:  liability  rule  protection  for  enjoyers  

1. Force  the  polluter  to  internalise  the  cost  of  pollution  and  hopefully  the  polluter  will  take  cost  justified  steps  because  at  some  point  that  will  be  cheaper  then  paying  the  tax  

2. Cannot  pollute  unless  you  pay  the  tax.    b. Calabresi’s  fourth  way:    

i. Liability  rule  protection  for  polluters  1. Realise  that  stopping  the  pollution  will  be  a  social  benefit  –  here  is  a  

cheque  to  stop  2. Came  to  the  nuisance:  pig  farm  example:  pig  farm  was  already  there  

and  the  city  came  to  him.  Give  him  a  cheque  to  bring  about  the  social  outcome  to  avoid  holdouts.    

ii. KK  –  what  are  we  doing  around  here:  are  we  dogging  or  are  we  sheeping?      

Coase  Theorem:    In  theory:  if  trade  in  an  externality  is  possible  and  there  are  sufficiently  low  transaction  costs,  bargaining  will  lead  to  an  efficient  outcome  regardless  of  the  initial  allocation  of  property.  In  practice  transaction  costs  or  poorly  defined  property  rights  can  prevent  Coasian  bargaining.    

CONTRACTS  OUTLINE     Page  27  of  27  

1. Coase  Theorem  1:  the  law  does  not  matter  to  substantive  outcomes  –  what  matters  is  the  bargaining  between  people.    

a. Assumptions  to  Coase  Theorem  1:    i. Legal  entitlements  alienable    ii. No  wealth  effects  

1. Of  course  there  will  be  wealth  effects,  whoever  has  the  initial  entitlement  by  the  allocation  will  be  wealthier  than  the  person  who  has  to  buy  it.    

iii. No  bargaining  or  transaction  costs  1. Freeloaders  2. Information  costs  

2. Coase  Theorem  2:  what  does  the  law  say?  What  rights  are  alienable?  Coase  Theorem  1  does  not  need  law  because  it  makes  those  assumptions.    

a. RST  344  (a)  over  344  (c)  is  Coase  Theorem  2=minimisation  of  transaction  costs.    DOES  IT  MATTER:  The  society  might  value  strip  mining  versus  property,  so  all  that  will  change  is  allocation  of  wealth.  In  property  rule  protection,  the  Peevyhouses  are  richer.  In  liability  rule  protection,  the  mining  company  is  richer.  It  doesn't  matter  which  you  choose,  just  affects  distribution.