Competition and choice in charter

50
Innovation in Education Markets: Theory and Evidence on the Impact of Competition and Choice in Charter Schools Author(s): Christopher Lubienski Source: American Educational Research Journal, Vol. 40, No. 2 (Summer, 2003), pp. 395-443 Published by: American Educational Research Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3699394 . Accessed: 17/10/2013 11:58 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. . American Educational Research Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Educational Research Journal. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Transcript of Competition and choice in charter

Innovation in Education Markets: Theory and Evidence on the Impact of Competition andChoice in Charter SchoolsAuthor(s): Christopher LubienskiSource: American Educational Research Journal, Vol. 40, No. 2 (Summer, 2003), pp. 395-443Published by: American Educational Research AssociationStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3699394 .

Accessed: 17/10/2013 11:58

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range ofcontent in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new formsof scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

.

American Educational Research Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extendaccess to American Educational Research Journal.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

American Educational Research Journal Summer 2003, Vol. 40, No. 2, pp. 395-443

Innovation in Education Markets: Theory and Evidence on the Impact of

Competition and Choice in Charter Schools

Christopher Lubienski Iowa State University

Charter schools elevate choice and competition to foster educational innova- tions. Indeed, these market-style mechanisms are intended to challenge standardized practices associated with district administration of schools. However, a comprehensive review of practices in charter schools indicates that, although some organizational innovations are evident, classroom strate- gies tend toward the familiar. Drawing on organizational and economic theory, this article considers the forces shaping educational innovation in market-oriented reforms. Although reformers assume that competition and choice necessarily lead to innovations within schools, a more complex exam- ination of competitive institutional environments suggests that mechanisms employed by reformers may actually undercut their intended purposes. The discussion highlights the potential for choice and competition to constrain opportunities for educational innovation and to impose pedagogical and curricular conformity.

KEYWORDs: charter schools, competition, education policy, school choice.

"It's just like Pepsi-Cola!"--Georgian president Eduard Shevardnadze, after sampling Coca-Cola at the opening of a new Coke bottling plant in Tiblisi

Few ideas are more closely associated with charter schools than the notion of innovation. Much of the thinking on school choice proceeds from the

premise that state-administered schools are necessarily bound by bureau-

CHRISTOPHER LUBIENSKI is an Assistant Professor of Historical and Comparative Studies in Education at Iowa State University, E155A Lagomarcino Hall, Ames, IA 50011; e-mail [email protected]. He is also a Fellow at Brown University's Advanced Studies Fellowship Program. His area of specialization is the policy and politics of education, with research interests in equity and organizational behavior in choice-based education reforms.

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

cratic regulations, inhibiting innovation and enforcing uniformity in the way that children are educated. Many reformers argue against such a "one-size- fits-all" model for education and believe that market-style mechanisms of con- sumer choice and competition between autonomous schools will encourage diverse and innovative approaches for increasing achievement (e.g., Anderson, 1997; Bennett et al., 1998; Caudell, 1997; Finn & Gau, 1998; Leonardi, 1998; Nathan, 1996a). Efforts to free schools from burdensome bureaucratic regu- lations are intended to undercut monopolistic political control of public edu- cation, giving educators in charter schools the opportunity and motivation to experiment with new instructional strategies (Allen, 2001; Budde, 1988; Kolderie, 1990). Based largely on reformers' observations of choice and com- petition in markets for consumer goods, these dynamics are expected to induce better achievement, more options for parents, and new ways of edu- cating students-particularly those groups traditionally marginalized in the current public system. Thus charter schools, in particular, are often cast as "laboratories" or "R&D centers" designed to generate curricular and peda- gogical approaches not available in bureaucratically bound district schools (e.g., Kolderie, 1994; Manno, Finn, Bierlein, & Vanourek, 1998b; Nathan & Power, 1996; RPP International, 2001).

Yet, aside from theoretical expectations, little is known about the types of actual changes that have been engendered by these forces in and through charter classrooms (Gill, Timpane, Ross, & Brewer, 2001). Research on the effects of comparable yet more developed reforms in other nations indicates that choice and competition can lead to innovations in organizational behav- iors in many cases, whereas classroom practices are relatively familiar and often revert to traditionalist modes of curriculum and instruction (Gauri, 1998; Lauder et al., 1999; Lubienski, 2001c; Whitty, Power, & Halpin, 1998; Woods, Bagley, & Glatter, 1998). In competing for students, schools in these cases tend to emulate established conceptions of schooling rather than use their autonomy to try substantively different approaches.

In light of these patterns in other nations, this analysis examines the issue of innovation in North American charter schools.' First, by reviewing the goals and expectations of reformers, I consider the theoretical assumptions and innovative potential embedded in these schools. Expectations for innova- tion in charter schools are apparent across the political spectrum and are evi- dent in state legislation, in school mission statements, and in the attraction that charter schools hold for educators as well as for market-oriented school reformers. In the subsequent section, I suggest a framework from which to study the issue of innovation in schools. That framework then serves as a lens through which to examine various forms of change represented in and by charter schools. Despite the multiple conceptions of "innovation" at play in the study of school change, the central purpose here is not to assert the inherent superiority of any one definition but to examine how the practices in charter schools reflect the expectations set out for them by theorists, legislators, and reformers. In view of those expectations, I look at how char- ter schools are developing novel approaches to the practice of schooling. In

396

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

general, the analysis indicates that charter schools are diversifying options for parents but not offering innovations in the manner anticipated by reform- ers. The concluding discussion considers a number of analytical approaches that offer insights into the patterns of change, continuity, and conformity in charter schools. Perhaps most significant, these perspectives problematize optimistic assumptions about the innovative potential of charters and other forms of school choice. Whereas reformers look to choice and competition as a way to unleash entrepreneurial innovation, this analysis suggests that, under some conditions, choice and competition may lead to counterintuitive consequences. It is not simply that the introduction of market forces into school accountability structures somehow failed to increase educational innovation; rather, curricular conformity and instructional standardization may in fact be caused by the very market mechanisms that were unleashed to address those ills.

Innovation as an Expected Outcome: Theory and Policy A viable choice system presupposes a range of options from which parents may choose. Yet, as critics note, public monopolies engender dis-incentives for trying different approaches (Coulson, 1999; Durant, 1997; Forstmann, 1999). Choice and competition encourage experimentation and diverse options in many consumer markets-for transportation, restaurants, clothes, and so on (Ascher, Berne, & Fruchter, 1996; Bennett et al., 1998; du Pont, 2001; Friedman & Friedman, 1980; Gintis in Glass, 1994; Nathan, 1996a; Peterson, 1998). Some suggest similar dynamics would be useful in forcing schools away from rigid, top-heavy administrative models to focus on the needs of students (Brandl, 1998; Hoxby, 1994). Charter advocates encourage choice, autonomy, and com- petition to make schools more flexible and innovative "with the perceived assumption that such innovations will produce identifiable improvements in student achievement" (Wohlstetter & Griffin, 1998, p. 3; see, e.g., Clayton Foundation, 1997, 1998; Lane, 1999; Price, 1998). In that respect themes such as "innovation," "choice," "competition," and "diversity," although they all have some value in and of themselves, often serve as intermediate goals that structure opportunities for institutions to increase achievement (Miron & Nelson, 2002). Even as intermediate goals, however, choice, competition, and innovation are cast as the necessary vehicles for advancing academic outcomes. Therefore, the extent to which school choice reforms succeed in securing these ideals indicates the likelihood of reaching the primary objective in this logic model. Moreover, innovation and diversification are primary goals for those reformers who seek ways of engaging children and communities tra- ditionally marginalized by the "one-size-fits-all" uniformity associated with the status quo (Bosetti, 2001; Flaherty, 1995; Fulford, Raack, & Sunderman, 1997; Lane, 1999; Nathan & Power, 1996). Thus, although it should not be overstated, the significance of encouraging innovative approaches to education also should not be slighted, because it is often central to arguments for, and expectations of, school choice.

397

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

The Market Theory Critique of the Uniformity of Public Provision

Indeed, arguments for charter schools implicitly affirm the importance of variety and innovation, particularly when they critique bureaucratically admin- istered education as moribund, inflexible, and inefficient. "Market theory" pre- sumes diverse individual preferences that are neglected in necessarily uniform public provision, because public schools are shielded from market disci- pline and are not accountable to their consumers (Walberg, 2000). The pub- lic choice theory variant, in particular, is quite cogent in its critique of public administration and "provider capture" (Buchanan, 2000; Buchanan & Tullock, 1999; Kalt & Zupan, 1984; Niskanen, 1971; Romer & Rosenthal, 1979). In the case of education, of course, this notion is applied to the "education estab- lishment" of teachers unions, administrators, and the like (Levin, 1997; Levin & Young, 1999). As a consequence of public administration, "every school ... was essentially identical to every other" (Finn & Gau, 1998, p. 79; e.g., Allen, 2001; Coulson, 1999; Dunne, Reed, & Wilbanks, 1997; Fitzgerald, 1995; Gintis, 1995; Little Hoover Commission, 1996; Maranto, 1999; Peterson, 1990; Robson, 2001). The "anti-bureaucracy" sentiment of public choice theory suggests "market-based school reform" as a self-evident remedy to the uniformity associated with state provision of education (Garn, 1998; e.g., Budde, 1988; Kolderie, 1990, 1992, 1993, 1994; Walberg & Bast, 2001). Charter schools are premised on individual (or family) choices where such choices are thought to best reflect the diverse preferences of the choosers rather than the dictates of monolithic bureaucracies. Communities are shaped around common interests and values, and charter schools give form to communities based on educa- tional issues (Brandl, 1998; Clayton Foundation, 1999; Finn & Manno, 1998b; Viteritti, 1999). Public choice theorists would see such communities as homogenous preference clusters that best respond to aggregated preferences while reducing friction and conflict over such issues in the wider context (e.g., Chubb & Moe, 1990). And when this local, decentralized form of pro- vision fails to meet the diverse needs of consumers, they have the right or responsibility to seek satisfaction of education preferences elsewhere- thereby holding publicly funded providers accountable to users through the threat or exercise of an exit option not available in pupil assignment schemes (Manno et al., 1998b; Vanourek, Manno, Finn, & Bierlein, 1997).

Although there are other motivations and justifications that serve as the catalysts for school choice reforms (such as teacher professionalism), char- ter schools bear the unmistakable imprint of market theory in the diagnosis of the pathologies of state provision and advocacy of alternative institutional arrangements. Market theory criticizes state administration on the assump- tion that public bureaucracies cannot innovate, whereas consumer choice and competition between autonomous providers offer the opportunity and incentives for innovation. For instance, Nobel laureate economists such as Milton Friedman and Gary Becker contend that choice and competition "would induce a more rapid rate of innovation into curriculum and teaching" (Becker, 1999, p. 2; Friedman, 1955; see also Chubb & Moe, 1990; Coulson,

398

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

1994, 1996, 1999; Friedman & Friedman, 1980; Gintis, 1995; Henderson, 1997; Lieberman, 2001; Osborne, 1999; Tooley, 1999; West, 1982, 1995, 1996). Similarly, sociologist James Coleman (1990, 1997) argues that the private sector is the organizational model for innovation because businesses are accountable to external (not internal) standards, and are output-driven-not authority-driven like public school systems.

Innovation as a Policy Goal for Charter Schools

These assumptions are also quite evident in state charter school legisla- tion. Thirty-nine states, plus Washington, D.C. (as well as Alberta, Canada), have passed laws authorizing these publicly funded schools to run largely or completely free of district oversight. The specifics vary by state-with greater flexibility, freedom from regulations, and ease of entry defining "strong laws" according to advocates-qualities that then "shape the scope, adequacy, qual- ity, innovativeness, and educational value of charter schools" (Vanourek et al., 1997, on-line; see also Bierlein, 1997; Center for Education Reform, 2001a; Molnar, 1996; Viteritti, 1999). Thus the Illinois statute seeks "the development of innovative and accountable teaching techniques" intended to "create new, innovative, and more flexible ways of educating children" (Illinois, 1996, 27A, et seq.). As the first state to authorize charter schools, Minnesota established them as vehicles to "(1) improve pupil learning; (2) increase learning oppor- tunities for pupils; (3) encourage the use of different and innovative teaching methods" (Minnesota, 1991, 124D.10, Sub. 1). This language is exactly the same in at least 14 states, and nearly verbatim in many others.

In fact, the policy goals for charter schools in most states are rather sim- ilar. In surveying legislative language, "innovation" was specified as a policy goal in approximately three-quarters of the laws, with virtually all of them explicitly seeking innovations in instructional practice such as "teaching methods." No other goal-including academic achievement and the diversi- fication of programmatic options-was mentioned more frequently.2 Hence, not only is the promise of classroom innovation evident in law as a widely cited policy goal, but policymakers appear to assume a causal connection between structural reforms and innovations in classroom practice. That assumption is significant: Reformers, consistent with assumptions of market theory, expected that changes in school administrative structures would lead to "different and innovative" classroom practices.

Similar assumptions are evident in the expectations of charter autho- rizers, as well as in the charter schools themselves. For instance, Central Michigan University-which at one point had established upwards of two- thirds of the charter schools in its state-expects of the schools it charters that they "be pillars of innovation in instruction" (Khouri, Kleine, White, & Cummings, 1999, pp. 7, 25). At their inception, more than 42% of Colorado charter schools identified innovations in teaching and learning as a goal in their mission statements (see Clayton Foundation, 1997). Teachers interested in establishing or working at a charter school anticipate more freedom to

399

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

employ "innovative methods" in pursuing their educational philosophy through classroom practices (Arizona Education Association, 1998; Clayton Foundation, 1998, 1999; Fuller, 2000a; Miron & Nelson, 2000; New Jersey Department of Education, 2001; Vanourek, Manno, Finn, & Bierlein, 1998). Some reports show similar expectations from parents and charter school founders (Clayton Foundation, 1998, 1999; New Jersey Department of Edu- cation, 2001; RPP International, 1998, 1999; SRI International, 1997; Vanourek et al., 1997). For instance, in a survey of more than 100 charter operators, "innovation" was one of the top three reasons for founding a school (see Education Commission of the States, 1995; Medler, 1996).

The frequency with which reform advocates, policymakers, and analysts endorse the expectation of educational innovations has been notably consis- tent over time, and is-as a whole-overwhelming (e.g., Allen, 2001; Anthes & Ziebarth, 2001; Bierlein & Mulholland, 1994; Brandl, 1998; Education Com- mission of the States & National Conference of State Legislatures, 1998; Finn & Manno, 1998a; Flake, 1999; Halpern & Culbertson, 1994; Hassel, 1999b; Hill, 1996; Kolderie, 1993, 1994, 1995; Lane, 1999; Little Hoover Commission, 1996; Manno, Finn, Bierlein, & Vanourek, 1998a; Manno et al., 1998b; Nathan, 1996a, 1996b; Nathan & Power, 1996; National Governors' Association, 1986, 1998; Rofes, 1996; Vanourek et al., 1997). Corporate figures such as Edison Schools chairman Benno Schmidt simply point to the business world to note, "Choice and competition breed innovation and better performance" (quoted in Symonds, Palmer, & Hylton, 2001). Likewise, policymakers from across the political spectrum embrace charters largely because, as Bill Clinton declared, the "right to choose will foster competition and innovation" (Clinton, 1997b; see also Buechler, 1997; Bush, 2001; Clinton, 1997a, 1999). Certainly, there are other goals associated with charter schools, including increased achieve- ment, professional opportunities for teachers, and more options for parents. Indeed, some early advocates of charter schools now downplay optimistic expectations for educational innovations (e.g., Hassel, 1999b; Maranto, 1999). On the other hand, most prominent charter supporters and leading policymakers continue actively to embrace the promise that choice and competition will lead to innovations in charter school classrooms (Center for Education Reform, 2000a; Nathan, 2002). Consequently, every one of the last 11 laws passed since 1998 specifies "innovation" (almost always in teaching or learning, or both) as an expected outcome-representing a notable increase in the frequency of this goal in the legislation. For instance, in one of the most recent laws, enacted in Iowa, the potential for classroom inno- vation was one of two primary reasons cited by lawmakers for passing the measure-the other being access to federal funds for charter schools (Iowa State Rep. Greimann, personal communication, June 16, 2002; see also Drost, 2002). The association between charter schools and innovative educational programming is a prominent theme in the No Child Left Behind Act (2002). Indeed, insofar as the current popularity of school reforms based on choice and competition represents the future direction of school reform through vouchers and tuition tax-credits, it is important to understand the record of

400

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

these dynamics in encouraging innovations in charter schools, where they were specifically intended to do so.

Thus there is a substantial, broad, and voluminous consensus on the potential of choice and competition to induce innovation in education. People from a wide variety of viewpoints cutting across institutional and ideological boundaries concur in the premise that organizational propen- sities for innovation and uniformity are consequences of institutional design. Consequently, reformers cast charter schools as "R&D centers" or "laboratories" to pursue "break-the-mold" innovations in classroom prac- tice (e.g., Bosetti, 1998; Halpern & Culbertson, 1994; Wohlstetter & Griffin, 1997). " This R&D potential is an important part of any policy-oriented appraisal of the charterphenomenon" (Manno et al., 1998b, p. 490, italics mine).

Analytical Framework

Lacking a developed model of K-12 school choice in the United States, choice advocates point instead to the logic of market dynamics in other areas where goods and services are produced for consumers-restaurants, cars, higher education, and so on (e.g., Bennett et al., 1998; Friedman, 1955, 1994; Friedman & Friedman, 1980; Nathan, 1996a; Walberg, 2000). However, as noted above, comparative research on these dynamics in education systems in other nations problematizes the theoretical assumption that market dynamics will necessarily transfer into state-funded education, fostering innovation in classroom practice (Lubienski, 2001c). There being no con- sensus on the nature of innovation in U.S. charter schools, in this section I consider a variety of perspectives in developing an approach to analyze changes represented in charter schools. Then I apply this approach to evi- dence on practices in charter schools.3

Considering Innovation

Various observers advance competing conceptions of innovation intended in and through charter schools. Some predict the invention of new approaches that will "break the mold" of school practices; others focus on increasing options for local consumers (e.g., Bosetti, 1998; Halpern & Culbertson, 1994; Hassel, 1999b; Mintrom, 2000b). For example, evaluators in Pennsylvania judged charter schools to be innovative insofar as the prac- tices in a charter school are different from the practices currently offered by the other schools in the host district (Miron & Nelson, 2000). While some argue that innovation can mean providing parents with a range of options (even familiar ones), others assess innovation in charter schools "as conventionally understood (e.g., something new)" (Good & Braden, 2000, p. 145; Stout & Garn, 1999). As this discussion of innovation has become more contentious, it is useful to distinguish between four common approaches to the question of innovation in charter schools and to identify

401

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

their limitations for understanding the nature of change represented by charter schools:

1. A popular perspective contends that practices are innovative if they appear so in a local context (Clayton Foundation, 1997, 1998, 1999; Fitzgerald, 1995, 2000; Manno, 2001; Manno et al., 1998a, 1998b; Maranto, 1999). This subjective approach highlights the diversifica- tion goal for charter schools-deemphasizing the expected R&D "laboratory" function. It also avoids two important questions: First, under what conditions is it "innovative" to import practices from one context to another? (See Meyer, 1992.) Second, although "many charter-school founders are simply more satisfied when they do it for themselves" (Vanourek et al., 1997), is reinventing the wheel in various isolated contexts necessarily innovative?

2. Others observe that innovation does not have to emerge in the form of a singular or distinctly new inventedpractice but may involve the combination or continuation ofpreexisting practices in support ofa coherent philosophy (Fitzgerald, 2000; Flaherty, 1995; Rosenblum Brigham Associates, 1998; Triant, 2001). This perspective notes that nothing is new in and of itself but that all newness is a matter of recombining attributes from preexisting models. Thus applying old practices to new purposes is innovative. This approach is less help- ful, however, in considering the nature of change: the degree to which new purposes are different from the old, and the extent to which innovations represent substantive or symbolic combinations of preexisting ideas. If innovation is simply a matter of recombining ideas or applying established practices in a new context, then virtu- ally all change is innovative.

3. Some note that diversification is itself an innovation (Center for Education Reform, 2000d; Hassel, 1999b; Manno et al., 1998a, 1998b; Vanourek et al., 1997). Based on the premise of public school uni- formity, this argument emphasizes the goal of providing various options for parents. While diversifying options is an obvious objec- tive for reformers, it should not preclude consideration of the other goal in the different and innovative mandate in the authorizing legislation. Although providing more choices may be laudable, choice as an end in itself does not necessarily advance-and may in fact preempt-the other goals of charter schools, such as innovation, increased academic achievement, and inclusion of marginalized groups (Howe, 1997). By conflating diversification with innovation, such arguments disavow expectations for an "R&D center" or "lab- oratory" for innovative classroom practice for the whole public school system and favor the more attainable aim of providing more options for specific parents and communities.

4. Several commentators emphasize that charter schools themselves are an innovation in governance (Center for Education Reform, 2000a,

402

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

2000c, 2000d; Hassel, 1999b; Hess, 1998; Manno, 2001; Manno et al., 1998a; Mintrom, 1997, 2000c; Mintrom & Vergari, 1997; Rofes, 1998a). Although this claim is true, it problematizes the diagnosis of patholo- gies in the public sector. As a policy innovation in school gover- nance and administrative structures, charter schools are the result of public policymaking--not market forces-wielded as an input at the governance level to effect and structure change at another level. Thus consideration of charters as being simply a policy innovation falls outside of the scope of this article, which is concerned instead with the policy objective of encouraging "different and innovative" approaches to education. As Richard Shavelson notes, "the real issue is whether what goes on in the classroom has substantially changed" (quoted in Jacobson, 1997, p. 12).

Thus the concept of innovation itself is contested, particularly in a politi- cized area such as school reform. Organizational theory and economic mod- els of industrial organization offer some insights into the dynamics of change in institutions and processes. For example, in thinking about the dissemina- tion of ideas, Rogers (1995) emphasizes the perception of newness for indi- viduals in specific contexts. However, in regard to the present question, that does not help us to account for efforts by education management organi- zations (EMOs) to import or apply practices from one context to another through processes such as franchising, for example. Although such changes may appear innovative to some, they are not new to the franchising agency or to other practitioners in the broader context. Moreover, although a practice may emerge organically in localities isolated from knowledge of its previous use elsewhere, such notions of "innovation" encounter the "reinventing-the- wheel" problem of redundancy and inefficient use of resources (e.g., Manno, 2001). Furthermore, change alone is not innovation. As Daft and Becker (1978, p. 4) note: "Innovation is the adoption of something new; change is the adoption of something different." The question is, "New" in what con- text? Rather than label all change or adoption of practices imported from other systems as innovations, Meyer (1992, p. 242) suggests a standard of "at least partly exogenous support or legitimization" (see also Wakeley, 1997). Because the charter laws largely specify "different and innovative teaching methods" as the most frequently cited policy goal, we may infer an intent on behalf of policymakers that diversification of options alone is not sufficient (Good & Braden, 2000; Little Hoover Commission, 1996). Instead, it appears that many laws seek to encourage new or substantially altered practices that can benefit the education system as a whole by making teaching and learn- ing more effective overall-simple diversification (as in bringing an estab- lished practice from one locality to another) is insufficient in terms of the stated goals of many policymakers.

Management theory equates product innovation with the act of inven- tion because firms invest in R&D to secure advantages over competitors (Hill & Jones, 1989). The economic literature on industrial organization is a

403

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

bit different, placing technological innovation as the central component in a process through which an invention is adapted for commercial application (innovation) before diffusion through the marketplace largely by imitation (Davies, 1988; Greer, 1984; Jacquemin, 1987; Shepherd, 1997). Insofar as such a conception of change can be applied to charter schools as R&D centers, there must be both the means of diffusion (often presumed to be competition-inspired emulation),4 and the potential for replicability of those innovations in district schools. These assumptions are not givens. Because charter schools can draw from diverse practices to support a coherent mission (Rosenblum Brigham Associates, 1998), some practices that they generate may not be appropriate or effective in district schools that, by their public function, must necessarily be "all things to all people" (Hassel, 1999a, p. 132). That is, inasmuch as charters are public-private hybrids (Finn, Manno, & Vanourek, 2000; Lubienski, 2001b), they occupy an area between the differ- ent institutional roles (and consequent structural characteristics) typically played by public and private schools (Lubienski, in press; Scott & Meyer, 1994). Indeed, research suggests that coherence of mission is a positive attribute for school effectiveness and that the act of choosing schools facilitates such coherence through the clustered and aligned preferences of parents- which are not necessarily available to neighborhood schools (Chubb & Moe, 1990; Hill, Pierce, & Guthrie, 1997; Smrekar, 1996). On this point, the issue of innovation in charter schools moves into problematic questions about the pub- lic nature of schools and the value of the common school ideals or the com- prehensive model relative to other goals such as effectiveness and innovation.5

In view of this range of approaches to the notion of change, this article employs three considerations for analyzing and understanding the changes represented in and by charter school practices. These considerations are hardly neat, and are mutually dependent and overlapping. Still, they are use- ful in examining charter school practices. As applied to the evidence from the research on charter schools reviewed below, the three considerations were posed as follows:

* At what level within the institution does the practice represent change? * To what extent is the practice established and familiar, or original

and unique? * To what extent are views on the second question informed by con-

textual perspectives across educational institutions? (That is, what is the scope of analysis?)

Thus I considered the level at which the practice occurs within institutions. This factor emerges from the analytical distinction suggested by the reform experiences in other countries, where research indicates that similar reforms succeed in inducing certain types of innovation and diversification at particular levels (for a review of this literature, see Lubienski, 2001c; see, e.g., Woods et al., 1998). Thus, I distinguished between educational changes (practices regarding curricular content and instructional strategies with immediate impact at the classroom-level) and administrative changes

404

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

(organization-level practices and structural designs that do not directly affect classroom techniques or content), following Daft and Becker (1978; see also Meyer, 1992, on juxtaposing innovations in form and content).

Moreover, I examined changes in terms of both innovation and diversi- fication, so as to better assess the potential of choice and competition to gen- erate original practices in local contexts or to transfer practices within school systems. Because charters are accountable to consumers for outcomes (not processes), I use innovation in the "product development" sense-whereby providers develop new or substantively altered products for consumers (Davies & Lyons, 1988; Hill & Jones, 1989; Shepherd, 1997). This sense is con- sistent with the "different and innovative" aspect of the "charter law intent of encouraging new methods" (Little Hoover Commission, 1996). In that respect, I examined evidence on charter school practices in terms of their original characteristics as they would be evident to a local consumer-essentially, the quality of newness (Daft & Becker, 1978). In addition, because the "R&D potential is an important part of any policy-oriented appraisal" (Manno et al., 1998b, p. 490), I examined the unique and distinctive characteristics of char- ter schools within the broader context of education.

Furthermore, I attended to the policy goal of diversification of options within a given context. Because theorists locate innovation within a process of development and implementation (and implementation is assumed here, as this analysis focuses on practices reported to be in use), innovation nec- essarily leads to diversification. However, not all diversification is an imme- diate consequence of innovation, because diversification could be a result of emulating, importing, or renewing practices. Consequently, a lack of diversi- fication implicitly indicates a lack of innovation. Yet, regardless of the means of diversification, policymakers hope to increase the variety of options for families, so I examined the record of charter schools in that respect.

Evidence on Charter School Practices

If, as market theorists have argued, the problems with public schools are symptomatic of an anti-competitive bureaucratic culture in a monopolistic education establishment, and if those problems appear in the classroom as stagnant and uncreative teaching and learning, then modifying that institu- tional structure is expected to spark creativity in the classroom. This pre- scriptive logic can be outlined as follows:

1 State policy changes-+ 2 Substantive institutional autonomy for schools and

choice for consumers--+ 3 Incentives for innovation in educational practice not possible in

district classrooms.

If this logic holds true, then a sector designed to be responsive to choice and competition would develop innovations that had been previously unavail-

405

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

able in a sector defined by state-monopoly provision and assigned student placements. To test this assumption, one can examine innovations produced by charter schools in comparison with practices currently in use in tradition- ally governed district schools. Thus, within the scope of the publicly funded school system, the unit of analysis for such a comparison would be the orga- nizational sector, as characterized by governance-that is, district-run (non- charter public) schools on the one hand and charter schools on the other- because market theorists juxtapose schools administered by districts with those driven by consumer preferences (e.g., Chubb & Moe, 1990; Coulson, 1999; Tooley, 1999; Walberg & Bast, 2001).

Data and Analysis

To examine the assumption that charter schools would generate innova- tive practices, I reviewed all known research and scholarly studies available that reported evidence of innovations in charter schools. Specifically, to under- stand the nature of innovative practices in charter schools as compared with district schools, I focused on charter school practices cited as innovations in these reports as the data for my analysis. Following Light and Pillemer (1984), this exploratory review of research attempted to "cast as wide a net as possi- ble" in accessing every study available on the topic, to consider a broad range of practices. This approach would control for any potential selection bias in gathering studies and assembling lists of practices reported as innovative.

In all, approximately 190 published works were collected that deal with the issue of innovation in charter schools in some significant way. (Published works on this topic were compiled through regular and exhaustive Web searches, ERIC searches, and comprehensive literature reviews of publications focusing on charter schools.) Of those, a substantial number of the publica- tions made no pretensions of scholarly inquiry. Many were not based on sys- tematic observations of charter schools but instead made unsubstantiated assertions in attacking or advocating for charter schools; as such, they were not useful in understanding charter school practices and were thus set aside.6 Of those offering evidence on innovative practices in charter schools collected in any systematic manner, none were excluded. Consequently, this article analyzes practices reported in 56 studies-including state-level evaluations and other research reports that provide evidence regarding innovative prac- tices in charter schools.7 Taken together, this broad collection of studies rep- resents the most comprehensive research available on the topic of charter school innovation-providing a rich set of data on charter school practices.

Of these reports, most have been published recently (86% since 1997), and several focus only on charter schools that have been in operation for some time. Although the reports provide primary data on innovations in charter schools, the numerous studies used various methods of inquiry to gather data: classroom observations, examinations of curriculum materials, interviews with employees and parents, and innovations self-reported by charter school operators. The studies were undertaken by a number of orga-

406

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

nizations, groups, and individuals with a range of interests in charter schools. Their stated conclusions often diverge from each other on the issue of charter school innovations because of conflicting conceptions of the issue. However, as is demonstrated below, the weight of the evidence from multiple reports suggests an overall (albeit unacknowledged) consensus on the nature of changes represented in and by charter schools.

In light of the multiple definitions of "innovation" used by the authors of charter school reports, the practices analyzed here are necessarily derived from sources with uneven standards for identifying innovative practices. Yet, to explore the research and development potential of charter schools, it is essential that the use of this data drawn from such reports be as inclusive as possible, with no prior restrictions imposed on what the various reports may, in a sense, "nominate" as an innovative practice to be considered in this analysis. This approach allows for analyses of perspectives and definitions relative to variations in findings. Consequently, no studies were excluded on the basis of a particular standard or definition of "innovation." The result was a richer set of examples of innovation to consider as potentially new or sig- nificant departures from existing practices.8

Thus practices reported as charter school innovations in these reports were compared with practices already in use in district schools, in order to test the assumption of "market-based reform" that location in a sector defined by choice and competition would lead to the development of innovations not possible in a state-administered system (Walberg & Bast, 2001). As noted above, I reviewed each individual study-without regard to how the authors defined "innovation"-and compiled the practices cited into lists, by study. Then, on the basis of the analytical framework outlined in the preceding sec- tion, I considered each of three dimensions in characterizing the innovative nature of each practice:

1. The level within the institution: administrative and/or classroom level. As suggested by literature on organizational theory, innovation could be expected in organization-level structures and practices (in governance, structure, and relationships external to the classroom) or in practices that would be primarily evident in the classroom- what Daft and Becker (1978) characterize as "administrative" and "educational" innovations, respectively (see also Meyer, 1992). As noted above, these categories are consistent with findings from research on comparable school choice reforms in other nations and are also evident in state legislation that seeks innovations not only in governance but also in "learning" and "teaching methods."

2. The distinctive nature of the practice: replications offamiliarprac- tices, adoption of practices used elsewhere, or development of new practices. These three categories emerge from the conflicting per- spectives on what constitutes "innovation," in relation to "diversifi- cation" of options (discussed above). The dimensions are intended to account for contrasting interpretations and theoretical perspectives

407

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

regarding innovation, while examining the record of charter schools in meeting the "different and innovative" legislative expectation.

3. The appearance of innovation in a given context: local, state, or national. Because ways of addressing the preceding dimension are necessarily contextually dependent, this third dimension takes into account the perspectives of various constituencies and goals. The degree of innovative-ness as it appears to someone choosing a char- ter school would usually be informed by the local context (i.e., the set of options immediately available to a particular parent). Yet charter schools are authorized in state laws, which often set out expectations for then (hence, many of the reports are state-level evaluations). Still, theoretical expectations for innovation are usually framed in the con- text of system-wide sectors, as defined by governance (e.g., "govern- ment schools," "autonomous schools").

Each practice that was cited as innovative was categorized on these three dimensions. Although most practices could be neatly described as either "administrative" (marketing, merit pay) or "educational" (Afrocentric focus in curriculum, hands-on learning), some of the practices-especially program- matic ones-fell into both categories (an Edison school model, block sched- uling). Likewise, many of the practices that were cited as innovations would be quite familiar to educational researchers and other observers of school policy, history, and reform, but were new in a local community. For exam- ple, many teachers established charters to introduce child-centered practices popular in the progressive era into a local community; in some cases, although practices had been developed elsewhere, charter schools were the first schools in a given state to adopt a particular curriculum---Core Knowl- edge in Colorado, for instance. In most cases, it was relatively clear whether a practice was already in use elsewhere in the public school system before its appearance in a charter school. However, a few cases (e.g., Waldorf cur- riculum, parent contracts) required an examination of current practices in other schools to ascertain the degree of "newness" of a charter practice in a given state or in the nation. Practices for which no corresponding evidence of use elsewhere was found were then treated as being innovative at some level (e.g., the "Reggio Emilia" approach, teacher-run cooperative). Furthermore, the simple existence of a practice in surrounding noncharter public schools, for instance, did not disqualify that practice as an innovation in this analysis. As R&D centers, charter schools are expected to develop and diffuse practices to other schools. This study focused on the development function. Therefore, charter practices are identified here as innovative even if they are also in use in other schools, provided they were developed, adapted, or substantially altered first by charter schools before adoption elsewhere.

This analysis draws from these varied reports in considering charter school innovations in comparison to practices in noncharter public schools.9 Hence, the analytical approach employed here offers the advantage of dis- tinguishing areas and types of change by sector. Furthermore, it is consistent

408

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

not only with the assumptions of market theory but with the pronounced policy goals spelled out in charter school legislation, mission statements, and stakeholder expectations for "new" and "innovative" approaches to educa- tion different from practices currently in use in the public school system.

Findings on Types of Innovation

By the fact of their existence, charter schools often enrich the range of options available to parents in a given locality. Overall, based on the range of prac- tices reported as innovative in these and other studies, it would appear that charter schools are embracing a variety of approaches regarding both orga- nizational structure and curriculum. For instance, a number of charters incorporate curricular programs such as Core Knowledge or a Montessori philosophy (Arsen, Plank, & Sykes, 1999; Clayton Foundation, 1997, 1998, 1999; Colorado Department of Education, 2001; Gifford, Phillips, & Ogle, 2000; Hassel, 1999a; Horn & Miron, 2000; Lange, Lehr, Seppanen, & Sinclair, 1998; Legislative Audit Bureau [Wisconsin], 1998; Little Hoover Commission, 1996; Maranto, 1999; Vanourek et al., 1997; Viteritti, 1999). Others establish discipline codes, require student uniforms, solicit parental involvement, or use marketing techniques to promote information about themselves.10 Still others experiment with instructional and technological support for children schooled at home (Clayton Foundation, 1999; Huerta, 2000). Clearly, many charter schools are free to try new or different practices in any number of areas.

However, the R&D function that is assumed in their design has produced mixed results, with obvious innovations in organizational activities but fewer clear innovations in the classroom. Findings in this regard sometimes vary by study-even within a single state. To illustrate this variance, Table 1 offers synopses of findings on a sample of states-the three states that have been subject to the most studies.11

Legislation in California and Colorado is judged to be moderately strong, while Michigan's law is among the most favorable for charter schools, according to charter proponents (Center for Education Reform, 2001a). The studies in Michigan were conducted by different research teams during the same approximate period of time, and the findings are rather similar across studies. Findings from annual evaluations of charter schools in Colorado are relatively consistent over time, with researchers noting new practices in gov- ernance, for instance, while educators in charter schools emphasized peda- gogical innovations. Some studies of California charter schools have found a range of innovations; others conclude that schools are not reaching their innovative potential (indeed, they report a substantial degree of conformity to standard practices). The diversity of findings in these various reports-by state, and within states--demonstrates the ways in which both perspective and institutional context may shape perceptions of the innovative aspects of charter schools. But it also exemplifies the distinct areas of focus on differ- ent types of innovation, and it highlights the need for an interpretive syn- thesis of the disparate findings.

409

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

Table 1 Sample of Findings of Studies, by State

Study Findings on innovation

California Anderson, L., & Marsh, J. (1998) Innovations in hiring and employment and parental

participation requirements. Teacher interviews and classroom observations indicated little innovation in classroom practice, except in home-based instruction.

Becker, H. J., Nakagawa, K., Use of parent contracts, student selection. & Corwin, R. G. (1997)

Corwin, R. G., & Implementing more innovations than comparison Flaherty, J. F. (1995) district schools. Innovations included project-

based instruction, site-based management, com- munity and parent participation, and targeting of specific populations.

Flaherty, J. F. (1995) Similar rate of implementation of self-reported edu- cational and organizational innovations between charter schools and comparison schools. Innova- tions in project and technology-based learning, targeting specific populations.

Link, J., Gordon, H., & Reported on three district-chartered schools, finding Khanna, R. (1999) innovations in governance and curriculum:

scheduling, language requirements, etc. Use of curriculum packages, focus on leadership and international themes.

Little Hoover Commission (1996) Found much diversity. Some "innovations" in curric- ular themes preceded charter status, but most were familiar.

Rothstein, R., Carnoy, M., & Found more differences within school sectors than Benveniste, L. (1999) between them. Differences between schools were

more a matter of social class of community than school type. Charter teachers defended pedagogy from parent demands for academics.

SRI International (1997) Innovations in governance, home-based instruction, mandatory parent contracts; 87% of charter respon- dents used traditional classroom approaches.

Wohlstetter, P., & Griffin, N. Interviewed founders in Los Angeles (and cities in (1997, 1998) other states), finding that more autonomy led to

greater flexibility for adopting programs, but that schools were not capitalizing on opportunities "for implementing cutting-edge innovations in teaching and learning."

Colorado Clayton Foundation Charters provided diverse options. Innovations in

(1997, 1998, 1999) governance, organization, parent involvement, and teacher employment practices. Curricular programs and innovations already available in district schools. Charters were not serving as "laboratories of innovation."

410

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

Table 1 Sample of Findings of Studies, by State (Continued)

Study Findings on innovation

Colorado Department of More than 60% of schools used recognized national Education (2001) reform models. They used pedagogical approaches,

student grouping strategies, and team teaching method that were already widely available in district schools.

Fitzgerald, J. (1995, 2000) Found innovations in governance and employment, parent involvement. Reported respondents' descrip- tions of innovative teaching.

Michigan Arsen, D., Plank, D., & Sykes, G. Innovations in organization, governance, and man-

(1999) agement. Some schools employed curricular pack- ages and ethnic themes. Otherwise, innovations in teaching and learning were marginal and no more significant or frequent than those available in dis- trict schools.

Horn, J., & Miron, G. "Few and limited innovations," usually in manage- (1999, 2000) ment and operations (although desirability was

questioned). Self-reported "innovations" in class- room practices were familiar and often distinctly traditional.

Khouri, N., Kleine, R., White, R., Innovations in administration: site-based control & Cummings, L. (1999) counteracted by EMOs. Organizing around themes;

"basic" approaches and other "common" methods. Niche schools focused on ethnic or at-risk groups.

Mintrom, M. (2000) Striking similarities across school types, with charter innovations no more frequent or remarkable than in district schools. Innovations in scheduling, foreign language requirements, uniforms.

Miron, G., & Nelson, C. (2002) Innovations in organization but few in curriculum and instruction. Competition is leading to uniforms and marketing.

Plank, D. N., & Sykes, G. (1999) Innovations tend to appear as programmatic add-ons, not in technical core; move to traditionalist instruc- tion and basic skills. Exceptions are Edison and ethnic-based schools. Competition is leading to advertising.

Reynolds, K. (2000) Increased diversity of options. Self-reported innova- tions in organization, administration, and gover- nance, including class size, scheduling, uniforms, and parent involvement. Educare school was inno- vative. Study found educational innovations in themes and in character and content focus, but in familiar areas.

Note. The three states included here have been examined by a number of studies over relatively long time periods.

411

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Organizational and Administrative Changes

As noted earlier, school responses to autonomy and competition are likely to appear in different ways-in administrative-level innovations and in educa- tional innovations in classroom activities at the technical core of the organiza- tion (Daft & Becker, 1978). At the administrative level there is much evidence of both new and different practices in charter schools. As substantially auton- omous schools, charters tend to have more control over their budgets and can direct resources in response to local conditions and goals. Several reports note that the administration of charter schools is becoming more entrepre- neurial than is typically seen in public schools (Finn et al., 2000; Nathan, 1996a; Teske, Schneider, Buckley, & Clark, 2000; Triant, 2001; Vanourek et al., 1997). Many charter schools are experimenting with governance, financial arrangements, and employment practices such as merit pay that are not in use in most public schools (Anderson & Marsh, 1998; Podgursky & Ballou, 2001). Similarly, charter schools often experiment with new forms of stake- holder input into school governance, such as instituting formalized agree- ments with parents or seeking to enhance communication with the child's home (Becker, Nakagawa, & Corwin, 1997; Rosenblum Brigham Associates, 1998; SRI International, 1997; Teske et al., 2000).

Based on the evidence in the research on charter practices, charter schools appear to be using their administrative autonomy to experiment with many structural and programmatic approaches that offer parents more options (the "different" part of the "different and innovative" mandate). In many states, char- ters are implementing a range of organizational practices; some are familiar, but many are new in local communities as well as in the publicly funded sec- tor as a whole. Indeed, in organizational behavior and administrative practice, charter schools are engaging in a whole range of approaches to governance and administration, as they have been designed with a degree of institutional autonomy that affords them opportunities to operate in ways currently unavail- able to most district schools. For example, many charter schools are smaller or have smaller class sizes, or both-characteristics made possible through admin- istrative flexibility that allows schools to shift resources as they see fit (Clayton Foundation, 1999; Education Commission of the States, 1995; Good & Braden, 2000; Kane, 1998; Miron & Nelson, 2000; Podgursky & Ballou, 2001; Urahn & Stewart, 1994). A substantial number of the schools adjust traditional bound- aries of schooling-scheduling and age-grouping, for instance-to provide a distinctive option for parents (Clayton Foundation, 1997, 1998, 1999; Colorado Department of Education, 2001; Fitzgerald, 2000; General Accounting Office, 1995; Gifford et al., 2000; Link, Gordon, & Khanna, 1999; Little Hoover Com- mission, 1996; Mintrom, 2000b; Miron & Nelson, 2000; Urahn & Stewart, 1994). Charter schools are able to move away from the comprehensive or common school model of being "all things to all people" by focusing on serving specific groups-based on interest, ethnicity, risk factors, and so on (Bosetti, 2001; Bosetti et al., 2000; Corwin & Flaherty, 1995; Education Commission of the States, 1995; Flaherty, 1995; Lange et al., 1998; Legislative Audit Bureau

412

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

[Wisconsin], 1998; Little Hoover Commission, 1996; Rebarber, 1997; Rofes, 1998b). There is a wide range of organizational activities in charter schools, many of which appear as clear innovations across contexts. The evidence in this respect supports the general consensus in these reports regarding the success of this reform in developing new organizational practices.

Educational Changes

Regarding educational practices in the classroom, charters employ diverse approaches that often distinguish them from other schools in their area, thus offering choices to parents through a range of classroom-level options. For instance, many charter schools use technology as a tool to deliver or support instruction or as an instructional theme (Clayton Foundation, 1997, 1998, 1999; Corwin & Flaherty, 1995; Education Commission of the States, 1995; Flaherty, 1995; Gifford et al., 2000; Little Hoover Commission, 1996; Miron & Nelson, 2000; Price, 1998; Rebarber, 1997; Reynolds, 2000; SRI International, 1997; Teske et al., 2000; Urahn & Stewart, 1994). And, certainly, while public schools have used technology in distance education, for example, on-line charter schools are introducing new types of delivery-often profit-driven- representing an innovation in school organization with a great potential for significant educational innovations. Another notable trend that many would consider to be innovative is evident in the number of schools that use indi- vidualized education planning or instruction for all students-a possibility directly related to their smaller size and favorable student-staff ratios, which in turn are related to their administrative flexibility for directing resources as they see fit (Bosetti, 2001; Clayton Foundation, 1997, 1998, 1999; Division of Charter Schools & Texas Education Agency, 2000; Gifford et al., 2000; Miron & Nelson, 2000; Reynolds, 2000; Rosenblum Brigham Associates, 1998; Urahn & Stewart, 1994; Vanourek et al., 1997; Viteritti, 1999). Overall, about half of the reports found "innovative" or "diverse" practices in charter school classrooms.

However, such findings do not reflect a general consensus in the research regarding innovations at the classroom level-largely because of differing interpretations of "innovation." Almost one third of the reports cited few or no practices unique to charter classrooms (e.g., Good & Braden, 2000; Good, Braden, & Drury, 2000; Horn & Miron, 1999, 2000; Khouri et al., 1999; Legislative Audit Bureau [Wisconsin], 1998; Mintrom, 2000a; Miron & Nelson, 2000; Plank & Sykes, 1999; Stout & Garn, 1999; Wohlstetter & Griffin, 1998). For instance, the Clayton Foundation (1998, p. 21) noted in its evaluation of Colorado charter schools that almost "all of the approaches ... are being used by conventional public schools." Indeed, in view of the market theory critique of district governance, the R&D expectations specified in state charter school laws, and the initial expectations shared by charter school founders and teachers, there is a notable paucity of classroom practices developed in char- ter schools that were not already available outside the charter school model. Thus many of the reports finding innovations in charter schools are holding to a much lower standard than would be consistent with the assumptions of market theory or with other widely held expectations.

413

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

As an illustration of this, Table 2 lists practices that were reported as inno- vations in states with the strongest laws where charter schools had been in existence for the longest period. Although not exhaustive (because of space considerations), these lists are relatively comprehensive in that they capture the kinds of practices typically cited. Of the "strong" states, these four had the most schools-together representing approximately 30% of the all charter schools in the United States-and had been studied in multiple reports.

The types of practices listed in Table 2 tend to fall into three categories. First, there are a number of administrative innovations, many of which are rel- atively rare in district schools: employment practices such as merit pay, hiring noncredentialed teachers, contracting for services, and so on. As noted above, charter schools are developing clear innovations in these areas by almost all accounts and measures. Second, there are a number of innovative charter school practices that are not transferable to most public schools. A focus on hearing-impaired students, the use of parent contracts, or an Afrocentric cur- riculum may offer advantages for educating some students; yet such inno- vations, by their nature, are largely unfeasible in the district sector-contrary to the R&D function for charter schools. Finally, many of the educational practices listed as innovations were, in fact, already evident in the district- administered classrooms (e.g., hands-on learning, use of portfolios, and cooperative learning).12 Charter schools were reported to be innovative in offering parents options in such areas as technology-focused instruction, year-round schedules, an emphasis on safety and order, and "alternative" options such as Montessori or a "back-to-basics" approach. But so do many district schools. Other reported innovations such as small class size, multi- age grouping, and integrated curricula (General Accounting Office, 1995), and character and citizenship training (Rosenblum Brigham Associates, 1998) are also already practiced in many traditionally governed public schools.13 Indeed, even in cases where innovations straddle administrative and educa- tional categories-for example, block scheduling, all-day kindergarten, and nongraded classes-the evidence available in these reports indicates that the impact in the classroom tends to remain within the range of practices already available within the public sector. Whether such practices are "inno- vative" depends on the context in which one considers them. Table 3 offers a schematic representation of the analytical framework discussed above- applied here to classroom practices in charter schools.

In Table 3 the apparent originality of a classroom practice is scaled on the vertical classification on the left-from imitating established practices (familiar), to inventing novel approaches (new). Because familiarity and newness are context-dependent, the contextual perspectives relevant to ana- lyzing this issue (as outlined in the framework) are arranged along the hor- izontal classifications along the top-from the local (perspective of a parent, for instance), to the national (within the system of public sector schools).

As illustrated in this representation, charter classroom practices would appear in a local context as spanning the spectrum from the familiar to the new (the left column of the scheme). Yet in a state-level context (the middle

414

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

r Vr

Table 2 Practices Reported as Innovative, by State

Arizona Massachusetts Michigan Minnesota

* Employment practices * Multi-age grouping * Management and operations * Teacher-run co-op * Arts focus/integrated arts * Thematic instruction * Corporate governance * Community service projects * Back-to-basics * Vocational * Ethnicity-based curricula * Montessori * Computer-based * Employment practices * Technology theme * Afrocentric focus * Core knowledge * Coherent mission * School-to-work focus * Hearing-impaired focus * Great books focus * Extended schedule * Whole-school programs * Code of conduct * Marketing * Merit pay * Theme based * Discipline-intensive * Montessori * Parent contracts * Smaller school/smaller class size * Student-centered * Multiple intelligences * IEPs for all students * Employment practices * Curriculum-based measurement

emphasis * Character education * Parent involvement * Cooperative learning * Saxon math * Before-and-after-school programs * Basics/core knowledge focus * De-tracking * Waldorf * Gifted and talented programs * Character/citizenship focus * Team teaching * Block scheduling * Environmental focus * Multicultural emphasis * Hands-on learning * Non-graded classes * Museum-type approach * Contracting for services * Project-based learning * Thematic curriculum * At-risk focus * Advertising * Use of computers * Business focus * Academic rigor * All-day kindergarten * Low-income and at-risk focuses * Portfolios * Edison curriculum * Finance arrangements * IEPs for all students * Smaller class size * Marketing * Student uniforms * Multidisciplinary * Use of advertising * Ethnic focus See, e.g., Arsen, Plank, & Sykes, See, e.g., Lange et al., 1998; Urahn * Child-centered See, e.g., Hassel, 1999; Podgursky 1999; Dykgraaf & Lewis, 1998; & Stewart, 1994. * Active learning & Ballou, 2001; Rosenblum Horn & Miron, 1999, 2000; See, e.g., Gifford et al., Brigham Associates, 1998; Teske Khouri, Kleine, White, &

2000; Glassman, 1998; et al., 2000; Triant, 2001. Cummings, 1999; Mintrom, 2000; Maranto, 1999; Podgursky Miron & Nelson, 2002; Plank & & Ballou, 2001; Sykes, 1999. Stout & Garn, 1999.

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

Table 3 Originality of Classroom-Level Practices in Charter Schools, by Context

Context

Local State National Degree of originality (subjective) (legislative) (sector)

Familiar (replication/imitation) X X X Not new, but different in context

(adoption/adaptation) X X New (invention/innovation) X

Note. X indicates that practices have been identified in reports.

column), most of the practices that might seem innovative at the local level would now appear to replicate approaches already familiar in the state or known from elsewhere (an example is Massachusetts charters using the Edison curriculum). What is striking in the analysis at this level is how the areas of potential contribution most anticipated by market theorists-new practices not possible in the bureaucratically administered sector-are gen- erally vacant. This pattern is particularly apparent in the national context (the right column), where charters do not appear to be engaging in practices that are new or even different from practices already available in the district- governed sector of the nation's publicly funded school system-the compari- son group for market theorists. Hence, according to this representation, charter practices appear to be diversifying options for parents in some local contexts. Yet in the wider scheme of educational practice, charters are not developing options outside the range of what is already evident in schools. If these approaches are "innovative," then their earlier existence in public schools undermines the market theory premise that innovations occur outside the regulated bureaucratic sector. From the evidence available in the studies, it appears that charter classroom practices tend to be familiar, or different from other practices only in specific local contexts-thereby undercutting a critical R&D assumption of market-based school reform.

Evidence from Arizona and Michigan illustrates this pattern of organiza- tional change coupled with pedagogical and curricular conformity. Because of the perception that bureaucracy inhibits innovation and because proposed voucher legislation was not enacted (Bolick, 1998; Keegan, 1999), Arizona has been a leading state in the charter school movement in terms of the num- bers of schools and their institutional autonomy (Garn, 1998). In fact, Arizona charter schools have pioneered a number of organizational innovations, such as advertising their services and embracing new employment practices (Gifford et al., 2000; Glassman, 1998; Maranto, 1999; Podgursky & Ballou, 2001). Yet, in a comprehensive study of 75 Arizona charter schools, Stout and Garn (1999) found little to support the expectation that charter schools would develop new practices in the classroom.

416

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

Likewise, in Michigan, a state where inter-district choice and charter schools have substantially empowered parents as consumers and schools as quasi-autonomous providers, several recent reports cast doubt on presump- tions of innovation. Although Arsen, Plank, and Sykes (1999), Horn and Miron (1999, 2000), Khouri et al. (1999), and Mintrom (2000b) found diverse offerings across an array of charter schools, their reports demonstrate that charter schools are not achieving expected classroom innovations. After ana- lyzing innovations self-reported by charter schools, Horn and Miron (2000) concluded that few if any innovations were emerging:

We began our study of charter school initiatives with certain expec- tations and assumptions that innovations would occur in charter schools, that their sheer development would be cause for innovation. Unfortunately, overall innovations are not occurring in Michigan charter schools. (p. 26)

Instead, they found many schools reverting to traditional instructional prac- tices.

There are a few exceptions to this general pattern. For example, I did not identify any district-run schools with a comprehensive whole-school environ- mental focus or a museum-style structure; it appears that these are innova- tions developed in charter schools. In addition, the Reggio Emilia approach-a critical-thinking focus developed in Italy-was embraced by a California char- ter school (Link et al., 1999). Use of this early learning program is concentrated almost exclusively in private and university-run preschools; it has no real pres- ence in U.S. public schools. However, exceptions such as these are remark- ably infrequent and do not appear to represent any coherent trend of classroom-level innovations produced by charter schools.

Instead, much evidence indicates that there may be a trend toward stan- dardization of practice-rather than innovation-in many of these schools. For example, Hassel (1998, p. 255) analyzed the curricular and pedagogical approach of 80 charter schools in several states and found that 54% reported a "basics" emphasis, a vocational focus, a traditional subject orientation, or a "general" approach; 9% were specific culture-centric; another 36% were "alternative" but featured familiar educational models. Furthermore, he noted other states where operators were not breaking new ground in classroom practice but, rather, embracing "well-known" curricular approaches (Hassel, 1999b, p. 85). Price (1998) reports similar findings with data from the Center for Education Reform, noting that more than 40% of the 261 charter schools surveyed reported a "back to-basics" or core-knowledge approach (see also Center for Education Reform, 2000b). Similarly, Arsen et al. (1999) saw choice and charters as bringing more "traditional" forms of instruction into use rather than fostering innovations (see also Education Commission of the States, 1995; Gifford et al., 2000; Hassel, 1999a; Plank & Sykes, 1999; Stout & Garn, 1999; Viteritti, 1999). Where innovations do appear, they tend to be structural or programmatic supplements rather than fundamental changes in classroom practice (Plank & Sykes, 1997, 1999). Perhaps most important, despite their

417

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

initial optimism, teachers in charter schools confirm this perception of con- straints on innovation after working in the schools. The percentage of teach- ers agreeing with the statement "The school will support/is supporting innovative practices" declined significantly--down 25% from when they were surveyed on first joining a charter school (Khouri et al., 1999, p. 56; see also Miron & Nelson, 2000). Whereas teachers were often cast in roles as inno- vators developing new and exciting curricula (e.g., Finn, Manno, & Bierlein, 1996), the reality is that they often implement curricular decisions made by building or corporate managers or EMOs (Dykgraaf & Lewis, 1998; Horn & Miron, 2000; see also Finn et al., 2000; Triant, 2001).

In general, the findings of this analysis indicate that (a) by offering alter- natives for parents, charter schools are diversifying alternatives in areas such as class size, technology, and programmatic options; (b) charter schools are implementing innovations in governance, management, and other organiza- tional practices; and (c) with few exceptions, rather than developing new edu- cational practices, charter schools are embracing curricular and instructional approaches already in use in other public schools. Indeed, a substantial plu- rality of charter schools employ a traditional "basics" approach to instruction.

Hence, with respect to the logic of market-oriented prescriptions outlined above, the logic of quasi-market mechanisms has produced an outcome dif- ferent from what was anticipated in the logic of market-oriented reformers:

1 State policy changes--+ 2 Substantive institutional autonomy for schools and choice

for consumers-+ 3 Failure of incentives for innovation in practices not present

in district classrooms.

Despite the intentions of market theorists and policymakers, charters are not "breaking the mold" in classrooms. Instructional practices and materials in charter school classrooms are relatively familiar--despite institutional auton- omy, competitive incentives, and accountability to consumers. The problem with the original logic model appears to be located somewhere between the second and third assumptions. The dynamics of choice and competition built into the charter school design are likely contributing to changes in organiza- tional structures and administrative behaviors. However, contrary to the assumptions of market theorists regarding the need to base charter schools on these market-style mechanisms, the prior existence in the district-administered sector of practices cited as innovations in charter schools indicates that char- ter school status, as such, is neither sufficient nor necessary for the devel- opment of innovations in curriculum or instruction. Some may attribute these trends to the relative youth of the charter movement (Rofes, 1998b; Triant, 2001); however, little difference appears across states with newer or older legislation. And similar patterns are apparent in nations with more developed choice systems (Lubienski, 2001c). This consistency across time and context suggests that institutional and environmental considerations may be more

418

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

important than the longevity of choice and competition policies in explain- ing curricular conformity.

In attempting to explain such patterns, research suggests several reasons for the notable success that charter schools have demonstrated in some areas and the paucity of results in others. In the final section of this article, I discuss types of explanations for the disconnect between theoretical assumptions and the realities of the educational marketplace. After briefly reviewing several pro- posed explanations, I suggest that, rather than focusing on how to better lib- erate choice and competition as catalysts for change, policymakers might consider some ways in which the interactions of institutions within market dynamics may themselves cause curricular and pedagogical conformity.

Discussion: Understanding Patterns of Innovative Practices

Across charter schools in various states, research demonstrates virtually no innovations in curriculum or instructional strategies. In addition to the paucity of innovations in classroom practice, there may be underlying nascent ten- dencies toward homogenization, or "isomorphism," as schools use their new- found autonomy to emulate established practice found in successful schools. Several types of explanations for these patterns are available.

Dynamics of Consumer Choice

Because charter reforms elevate consumer preferences to a more influential position, there are distinct possibilities regarding the role of parental demand in shaping and, indeed, constraining provision.

Parents as Inherently Conservative Consumers

In an age that emphasizes diverse learning styles, arguments for elevating parental preferences as a primary determinant of educational provision pre- sume that parental preferences for education are diverse and that those preferences should influence providers to innovate to meet diverse demand (e.g., Viteritti, 1999). In fact, some evidence suggests that many parents- as an "inherently conservative clientele"-view public schools as overly innovative because these schools embrace many fads and progressive reforms (Ravitch, 2000; see Whitty et al., 1998, p. 90). Indeed, in contrast with reformers' preoccupation with innovation, many parents are often more concerned with immediate academic issues (Arsen et al., 1999; Kohn, 1998; Teske et al., 2000). While charters may empower teachers as profes- sionals to establish a school around a shared philosophy or pedagogical approach, they may run up against the discipline of the market, where parental preferences constrain opportunities for innovation (Rothstein, Carnoy, & Benveniste, 1999).

Nevertheless, it is important to avoid essentializing all parents as oppos- ing innovation, particularly in concluding that consumer-oriented schools will not be innovative (see, e.g., Arsen et al., 1999; Hassel, 1999b; Henig, 1996;

419

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

Lane, 1999; Maranto, Milliman, Hess, & Gresham, 1999b; Plank & Sykes, 1999). Parents in general may not look to enroll their children as guinea pigs in experimental schools, but that is not the point. Instead, market mechanisms in education are thought to have the potential not only to produce innova- tive options (product innovations), but innovative processes of production. Such processes can produce familiar outcomes but in more efficient and effective ways that are largely outside parents' view when they are "shopping for schools." That is, consumers may not be looking for innovations in socks or soft drinks, but they look to benefit from innovative production processes that give them better quality or lower prices, or both. Consumer demand is supposed to cause innovation, even if the demand is not for innovation itself (Hill & Jones, 1989).

Consumer Information

In a complicated and often obscured production process such as education, what consumers see may be an insufficient basis from which to make a rational and informed decision-but it is all they have to go on. The mar- ket theorist's idealized "rational chooser" would use whatever information is available in making a choice (Walberg, 2000). Yet school effectiveness is far from clear. Insofar as parents focus on enhancing a child's achievement over time, the evidence most readily available at any one time is a school's achievement-which is largely a reflection of the socioeconomic status (SES) of its student intake (and perhaps peer effects), not simply the school's value- adding potential. Thus "rational" parents may shop for schools on the basis of more obvious indicators of social characteristics in intake, as represented by other consumers, rather than on the basis of obscured information such as innovative processes. Shrewd administrators may concentrate on shaping their student intake through themes and marketing to attract higher SES stu- dents rather than on diversifying or innovating, because the consumer prod- uct, rather than the process, may be a more certain route to improved tests scores and market position.

Furthermore, even if parents do have a range of preferences regarding education, the need to judge institutions and outcomes requires standardized criteria for evaluation. The need for a unidimensional standard can limit the range of alternatives for schools competing for students. Educators may wish to experiment with alternative forms of instruction or assessment, but without guaranteed resources they need to demonstrate for consumers their effective- ness relative to other schools. Thus National Heritage Academies-the only profitable EMO-does not focus on innovation but uses practices borrowed from religious schools (Golden, 1999; Schnaiberg, 1999; Walsh-Sarnecki, 1999). Charter pioneer Joe Nathan (1998, p. 502) advises charter schools "to look at carefully evaluated, proven approaches." Therefore, presumptions about the deadening conformity in public schools may, in fact, have it back- wards. Indeed, autonomous schools can use their newfound freedom to be familiar-by focusing on narrowed "instrumentalist" conceptions of school-

420

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

ing (Lubienski, 2001a, in press). Although, according to many critics, coher- ence of mission on academic goals is not necessarily a bad thing, it can limit opportunities for innovation promised by reformers, particularly regarding some of the other societal goals imposed on public schools. Thus educators who establish a school on an idea such as heterogeneous grouping or serv- ing at-risk students may find it difficult to provide consumers with evidence justifying their approach.

Quasi-Market Failures

If public provision engenders pathologies in satisfying individual preferences, then the continued public role in market-style provision also creates problems that hinder the capacity for innovation through "quasi-markets" (see Bartlett, 1993). Unlike businesses in a "genuine market," schools are in an ambiguous position for sensing and responding to market-style signals (Hirschman, 1970; Meyer, 1992). Likewise, the production processes are difficult to control, and outcomes are difficult to measure (Meyer, 1992). Particularly when bound by obligations such as open access and equity, schools often do a poor job of acting like private providers in many respects, including innovation (Lehman, 1997; Payne, 2000). Whereas a typical business may innovate in response to the exit of patrons, administrators in open-access institutions are sometimes relieved to be free of the burden of quarrelsome patrons.14

In education the identity of the consumer-a central role in the economic cast of characters-is ambiguous and is confounded by the production process. Students most immediately "consume" education, but usually are not themselves the "customers" choosing between options in an education mar- ket system. Parents are the "proxy-consumers" in choosing for their children, but they do not "consume" in the sense of enjoying the individualized capi- tal effects of education as a direct personal benefit (Brighouse, 1997; see also Brown, 1992). Others see the community or society as the ultimate consumer of education because the externalities of widespread provision involve gen- eral social effects (Labaree, 2000; Meyer & Rowan, 1992b), such as crime rates, fertility rates, and social capital. Yet many economists dispute the idea that society is the consumer; in their view, societal benefits are external or subsequent to the purpose of education, which is directed at individuals (e.g., Gintis, 1995). Finally, there is an underlying theme in school reform- evident in many charter schools-that employers are the primary consumers of the "product" of education: skilled graduates (Gerstner, Semerad, Doyle, & Johnston, 1994; Kearns & Doyle, 1988). Without a clear sense of the consumer-a lead character in a market system-the beneficiary of (and, therefore, motivation and purpose for) innovation is uncertain.

Furthermore, there is not a clear distinction between the purchaser and the consumer-a conflation of market characters, with implications for inno- vation. Market logic usually advances from the premise that the purchaser is also the consumer-which is not the case when a parent chooses a child's school at public expense. Because funding in these cases is public, it removes

421

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

a crucial market dynamic in school choice systems. Although parents may effectively serve as "proxy-consumers," they are acting on behalf of the child-beneficiary, not the public-purchaser. Market theorists expect con- sumers to choose rationally between options partially on the basis of cost- effectiveness; however, the cost side of the equation is absent from the consumer's perspective in a system of fully-funded school choice. The lack of immediate consumer pressure on costs corrupts incentives for providers regarding their costs, up to the threshold of funding paid by public authorities. Of course, there is an incentive for the producer to control costs to increase profit margins. But that does not directly influence the cost efficiency of the funder-in this case, the public-as is necessary in a pure market context (Lehman, 1997). Thus, in many cases incentives for innovation and experi- mentation are skewed, as some market purists note (e.g., Coulson, 1999; Lieberman, 2001). In fully subsidized school-choice programs, consumers do not have the incentive to shop around for lower costs; and for-profit providers can realize a profit incentive only by enlarging their customer base or by reducing costs associated with quality or R&D-factors that discourage innovation. Without the ability to charge customers more for new options, the incentive to innovate can be de-emphasized for producers (Coulson, 1999; Friedman, 1995; Henderson, 1997).

Dynamics of Provider Competition

The institutional environments in which schools operate interact with parental preferences in shaping patterns of educational provision. Examinations of these dynamics focus on both the organizational behavior of schools and patterns across populations of organizations within environments character- ized by bounded rationality, imperfect information, and uncertainty about current abilities and future prospects (e.g., Adnett & Davies, 2000; Brown, 1992). Other attempts to address these patterns tend to exemplify a rather innocuous view of the effects of choice and competition on education practices. If market forces were allowed to operate more naturally, it is assumed, they would likely fulfill their presumed potential in inducing sub- stantive change in practice (e.g., Adnett & Davies, 2000; Mintrom, 2000b). Their uneven record to this point, in this view, indicates only isolated incidents of (quasi-)market failure caused, for example, by start-up effects, peculiar con- sumer preferences and uses of information, or continued state participation in funding. Consequently, although reformers did not necessarily anticipate these problems, they hope to address them through simple policy correctives. Suchreformers tend to believe that, although choice and competition may not be, in and of themselves, producing the expected results for various reasons, they can be made more effective with public sector intervention and support (for instance, through parent information centers and communication net- works to diffuse innovations). Here I suggest another possibility.

Organizational theory and institutional ecology provide a developed basis from which to consider organizational isomorphism in view of the

422

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

internal logic of these competitive environments. In this regard, the paucity of classroom innovations emerges not simply in spite of the market forces that have been brought to bear through changes in school governance. Instead, curricular conformity and standardization may be encouraged by the very market forces that were unleashed to address those ills.

Mimetic Isomorpbism

Even as reformers seek to diversify options through choice and competition, standardizing tendencies appear to be embedded in those forces which- under certain conditions-may produce consequences at odds with reform- ers' stated goals. Analyses of institutional environments suggest that, within an organizational field, organizations inhabiting the same environment sense similar pressures and common constraints. Consequently, they adapt their internal structures in similar ways, even as the environmental conditions shape the distribution of the population of organizations (Hannan & Freeman, 1977). As sociologists have examined educational organizations, they note "an oppressive conformism and homogeneity" across schools in the United States (Meyer, Scott, Strang, & Creighton, 1994, p. 180; Meyer, Scott, & Deal, 1992). While similar patterns in market systems can be understood in terms of firms seeking to survive in a competitive environment (Meyer et al., 1992), in the edu- cation sector, environmental factors in the shape of normative expectations- both societal and within institutional fields--encourage homogeneity across specific contexts (Meyer & Rowan, 1992b). Consequently, although schools are remarkable in the rate at which they adopt innovations, they are much more likely to implement and sustain innovations outside of core instruc- tional areas, avoiding substantive changes in definitive classroom practices (Meyer et al., 1992).

Examinations of homogenization across organizational fields suggest a nar- rowing range of practices within fields, despite efforts toward diversification. In focusing on institutional isomorphism for less competitive fields, DiMaggio and Powell (1983) outline three related forms of institutional isomorphism operating both across populations of institutions and within individual insti- tutions in homogenizing organizational behaviors. Normative isomorphism (described above) emerges from professional values and practices within fields. Coercive isomorphism, primarily associated with the interactions between organizations, also involves cultural expectations placed on insti- tutions that require particular practices (regardless of effectiveness) as the price of legitimacy (see also Meyer & Rowan, 1992a; Meyer et al., 1992). For example, when parents express expectations of what constitutes "real" school- ing, they thereby constrain opportunities for schools to explore alternatives (Metz, 1990; Raywid, 1996; Tyack & Tobin, 1994).

Perhaps more pertinent here, however, is the concept of mimetic iso- morphism, wherein institutions employ a constricted set of responses to uncertainty. Particularly when facing a precarious environment or when oper- ating on ambiguous goals, organizations are more likely to emulate "similar

423

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

organizations in their field that they perceive to be more legitimate or suc- cessful" (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983, p. 152). While marketlike conditions may engender uncertainty for organizations, Brown (1992) describes uncertainty as a product of providers' and consumers' imperfect information on school production processes and of "bounded rationality" (inability to know beyond the horizon) about abilities and future market conditions. Schools accommo- date and try to minimize consumer concerns by standardizing core services (in classroom-level practices, curriculum, etc.) across sectors-what Brown calls "comprehensive uniformity." Faced with complex and obscured pro- duction processes (as with the problematic role of peer-effects, for instance), necessarily inexperienced consumers are at a disadvantage relative to pro- ducers in terms of access to useful information from which to make rational choices (see also Meyer, 1992). Consequently, producers realize an incen- tive to shape their intake as much as possible through image presentation (Brown, 1992) rather than committing resources to innovations in the pro- duction process itself. Employing standardized practices and strategies based on "appearances" may be a more effective and less costly option for an orga- nization than experimenting with new approaches or mediating between conflicting goals (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983).

Corporate Capture and Competitive Isomorphism

In some sense, it would appear that charter schools could escape the grav- itational pull toward the center because they are designed to be flexible in adapting to changing landscapes of consumer preferences. Furthermore, many charter schools can access private resources for their laboratory func- tion. As Edison chairman Benno Schmidt notes, "We provide R&D, private sector capital, technology and training: all of which strengthen the state edu- cation system" (quoted in Bilefsky, 1998, p. 18). Although people often look to emerging and dynamic sectors such as technology for examples of innova- tion driven by small start-up firms, larger firms tend to be better equipped to sustain product development and process innovations over time (Davies & Lyons, 1988; Hill & Jones, 1989). Indeed, in some states, larger and more estab- lished EMOs control a substantial share of the charter management market (Hill et al., 2001; Horn & Miron, 1999, 2000; Khouri et al., 1999). In light of that trend, it is possible that potential economies of scale-not "provider capture"-may provide incentives for standardized approaches to curriculum development (particularly if educational preferences are monolithic). Yet insofar as prefer- ences are broadly distributed, some theorists contend that such a dynamic also provokes organizations to standardize practices (e.g., Brown, 1992; DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). Even if autonomous charter schools can focus on a coherent purpose, DiMaggio and Powell's hypotheses suggest that the ensuing effect of competition on district schools-which must continue to negotiate com- peting claims and goals (e.g., Labaree, 1997)-can still induce mimetic iso- morphism rather than diversity and innovation. Competitive isomorphism, particularly in unstable environments, shapes populations of organizations

424

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

into centripetal patterns, often favoring larger-scale organizations (Hannan & Freeman, 1977).15

In another sense, one might expect that the charter movement has the potential to promote innovation because of the high proportion of new start-up schools that are less encumbered by traditions, habits, or estab- lished practices. Indeed, in that regard, the fact that charters tend to have more inexperienced teachers, for instance, could be seen as an advantage (Lange et al., 1998; Miron & Nelson, 2002). In fact, management theory posits that the rate of product innovation is highest for organizations in their earli- est stages of development (Hill & Jones, 1989). Still, "in fields characterized by a high degree of uncertainty, new entrants, which could serve as sources of innovation and variation, will seek to overcome the liability of newness by imitating established practices within the field" (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983, p. 156). There is ample evidence from more developed school choice sys- tems that many autonomous schools tend to emulate traditional elite private schools in curriculum, discipline codes, and uniforms (Gauri, 1998; Lauder et al., 1999; Lubienski, 2001c; Whitty et al., 1998; Woods et al., 1998). Indeed, as education institutions such as the American public high school emerged, they engaged in forms of image presentation and management that invoked classical learning-isomorphic to their more prestigious competitors in the academy system (Reese, 1995; Tyack, 1974). In view of the concern of some observers regarding the propensity for public administrations to waste resources that "could be devoted to creative and innovative education pro- gramming" (Little Hoover Commission, 1996, on-line; see also Hoxby, 1994), it is somewhat ironic to observe how competition effects of charter schools often induce competing schools to mount marketing campaigns (Gifford et al., 2000; Keegan, 1999; Mackinac Center, 1999; Maranto, Milliman, Hess, & Gresham, 1999a; Miron & Nelson, 2002; Pini, 2001; Powers & Cookson, 1999).

In essence, choice-style incentives in competitive environments appear to encourage isomorphism in many cases. Part of the point of market approaches is to free public schools to act more like private schools and businesses in management. Yet such organizational behavior may decrease the overall options available to parents as schools are pulled toward a standard model, and those that are "deviant" from the model are punished by market disci- pline (Oettle, 1997; Whitty et al., 1998).

Other Considerations: Horizontal Differentiation and Vertical Distinctions

As reformers take schools deeper into marketlike environments through choice and competition, and as new and autonomous schools realize the same difficulties in changing core practices that have plagued educators for years, it may be useful to consider in more detail how emerging trends in edu- cation quasi-markets reflect standardizing tendencies in markets for consumer goods. Although such markets often serve as models for education reformers, more careful consideration suggests that schools could respond in ways not entirely anticipated by these reformers but predicted by economic analyses-

425

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

highlighting the blunt manner in which the logic of markets has been projected onto schools. Indeed, while many schools re-embrace core academic prac- tices, organizational efforts in areas such as marketing, symbolic presentation (uniforms, physical plant, etc.), and brand loyalty--rather than curricular innovation-may serve as more attractive opportunities for differentiation.

As with markets for many consumer goods, emerging education quasi- markets are defined neither by perfect competition (of multiple service providers, with ease of entry) nor by the pure monopoly control of one entrenched provider. Instead, incipient quasi-markets for schooling operate between these two extremes, as is the case with many other services and goods where close substitutes are available, and thus fall under conditions of "monopolistic competition" (Chamberlin, 1933; Robinson, 1933). Under this theory, any given firm such as an EMO has a monopoly over its partic- ular brand, 16 but other firms in the "product group" produce brands that are very similar. Although there can be some perceived product differentiation, the distinctions can also be "spurious" matters of image and advertising to encourage brand loyalty (Mansfield, 1970, p. 286)-even when, overall, there is substantive uniformity in service or product, as with gasoline, tooth- paste, evening news, or over-the-counter pain medication.17 Perceived, rather than substantive, product differentiation is more likely when infor- mation on products or processes is obscured for consumers. That is, in lieu of perfect information, they must make decisions based on the "fenders" rather than the "motor" (Meyer, 1992, p. 251). Often, in such cases, "a lot of persuasive advertising relates to products that vary very little in their objec- tive characteristics." (George & Joll, 1981, p. 174)

Under conditions of monopoly competition, organizations have spe- cific options for sustaining or increasing market share. Businesses can (a) lower prices, (b) create a better product, or (c) use more effective marketing (Mansfield, 1970). Although some producers use price and quality adjustments to target "up-" and "down-market" demographics, the set per-pupil funding in public education means that the price option is essentially unavailable in the case of charter schools. Furthermore, regarding the quality option, although some producers can substantively improve a product or simply embrace gim- micks, the preceding discussion outlines the substantial difficulties in innovat- ing core practices in education. On the other hand, schools can try to shape "quality" of intake. In turn, the third option becomes imbued with relatively attractive opportunities and incentives for schools. Providers may seek to use marketing as a way to distinguish their services (and consumers) through symbols rather than through substantive but difficult innovations in core practices. Such promotional practices would offer any given provider some security in its market share. However, such incentive structures may short- circuit the intentions of reformers who would like autonomous schools to encourage innovation in the classroom.18

Furthermore, such conditions may engender incentives that provoke ver- tical rather than horizontal product distinctions (Davies & Lyons, 1988). Unfor- tunately, in the case of schools, obscure or imperfect information in education

426

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

processes may encourage diversification based on social characteristics of student intake rather than school effectiveness enhanced by innovations. This should be a significant consideration for any policymakers seeking to use market-style incentives to promote "different-but-equal" curricular and programmatic options for parents. Indeed, an emerging research literature suggests that, when given more administrative flexibility in a competitive envi- ronment, schools generally have not responded to the uncertainty inherent in market-style incentive structures by diversifying educational options. Instead, they often tend to use advertising and other forms of symbolic presentation in seeking advantageous market positions from which they may better shape their student intake-producing not curricular differentiation but, rather, a sys- tem of school choices defined by students' social characteristics (Lubienski, 2002).19 Therefore, options may differ largely on a vertical scale of social segre- gation rather than on a range of different-but-equal educational options. These issues are evident in research on choice in the United States (Glazerman, 1998; Henig, 1994; Howe, Eisenhart, & Betebenner, 2001; Levin, 1998; Moore & Davenport, 1990; Reardon & Yun, 2002; Ritter, Rush, & Rush, 2002; Smith & Meier, 1995; Wells, 1993; on charters, see Cobb & Glass, 1999), but they have yet to receive due consideration in the specific context of North American charter schools.

Conclusion

Many hope that market mechanisms of choice and competition can change the ways that schooling is practiced. Charter schools, in particular, have shoul- dered an extremely difficult task in this respect, because classroom practices have been remarkably resilient over the years in the face of efforts to effect change through reforms in governance and administration (Cuban, 1984; Levin & Riffel, 1997; Meyer, 1992; Tyack & Cuban, 1995). As a policy innovation, charter schools represent what Tyack (1974, p. 169) aptly terms "the lure of the structural panacea" for policymakers seeking to reform the entrenched practices of schooling. Insofar as reformers now recognize the difficulties of effecting substantive educational change, many are qualifying this particular expectation or distancing themselves from initial optimistic predictions of innovation (e.g., Finn et al., 2000; Fitzgerald, 2000; Hassel, 1999b). As Lauder et al. (1999, p. 135) note elsewhere, "it is clear that the world is a far more complex place than they envisaged."

In fact, the question of innovation in charter schools is complex and problematic-much more so than was initially anticipated. Consistent with research on more developed school choice systems in other nations, patterns in charter schools call into question the early expectations regarding the poten- tial of choice and competition to provoke innovations in classroom instruc- tion. Organizational analyses, which are largely descriptive, suggest some alternative effects of competition and choice not usually acknowledged in the prescriptive analyses of market theory as it has been applied to education. The application of market theory, and of public choice theory in particular,

427

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

has been too blunt and simplistic on this particular issue. There appears to be no direct causal relationship-counter to what market advocates have assumed-between bringing market mechanisms to education and inducing educational innovation. In fact, the very causal direction is in question in view of the fact that government intervention, rather than market forces, is the cause of the charters' most frequently acknowledged innovation: the policy innovation in school governance (Center for Education Reform, 2000a, 2000c, 2000d; Rofes, 1998a). Insofar as innovation in classroom practice represents a means for enhancing choice, achievement, and equity, reformers may do well to consider the conditions under which competition and choice lead to change. Accounting for these patterns not only contributes to an under- standing of the record of charter schools in promoting classroom innovation but also can inform appraisals of the potential for other market-oriented approaches either to cultivate new practices in teaching and learning or to standardize provision and product.

Notes

The author gratefully acknowledges Sarah Theule Lubienski and three anonymous reviewers for helpful comments and suggestions on drafts of this article. Iowa State Univer- sity's College of Education granted support for this research.

' Essentially, charter schools are public-private hybrids-publicly funded and privately managed (Lubienski, 2001b). Although details of the legislative acts vary, the schools are generally given a waiver from many regulations in the hope that the resulting autonomy will lead to experimentation and innovation in increasing student achievement (Garn, 1998; Nathan, 1996a; Wells et al., 1998). Unlike other forms of school choice, such as a vouch- ers system (where exit is meant to increase academic achievement) or magnet schools (for integration or to stem exit), charters are an effective subject for this study because they are explicitly intended to foster innovation.

2The similarities in expectations and policy goals may be due to the prevalence of public-choice thinking on the subjects of uniformity of practice in the district system and the promise of market mechanisms for creating innovation and diversity. However, they may also be due to the fact that state legislators appear to borrow language from organi- zations such as the American Legislative Exchange Council, which has a website that pro- vides templates for legislation, including a model charter school law. This, in turn appears to be largely lifted from the original charter legislation in Minnesota. Regardless of how the language was diffused, the easy acceptance of the link between market mechanisms and innovation is telling.

For the sake of simplicity and brevity, I did not examine special education or assess- ment practices--two other areas where lawmakers assumed innovation would occur. Nor did I appraise the diffusion of practices from charter schools to district schools; instead, I tested the presupposition that charters are in fact producing innovations that can then be adopted in other schools.

4While this form of diffusion is often assumed, the evidence is mixed, at best, for the initial expectation that district schools are adopting charter school practices (particularly classroom practices) because of competition-hence, the call for formal networks to dis- seminate charter innovations (e.g., Bosetti, 2000; Clayton Foundation, 1999; Garn & Stout, 1999; Mintrom, 2000b; Rosenblum Brigham Associates, 1998; Teske, Schneider, Buckley, & Clark, 2000; Wells et al., 1998). Certainly, charter schools are often put in the untenable situation of being asked to develop innovations and then voluntarily share them with com- petitors. However, this article focuses on practices within charter schools, so the diffusion issue (a.k.a. "competition effect" or "ripple effect") is essentially outside the scope of this analysis. (Furthermore, the focus on diffusion begs the question of whether practices should be mirrored simply because they are popular in the marketplace.)

428

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

5Discussions of innovations in governance-this article included-tend to refrain from critical judgments on the democratic implications of these policy innovations in gov- ernance. For such analyses, see Lubienski (2001b) and Mintrom (2001).

6 In addition to a number of newspaper reports that were discarded for lack of sys- tematic evidence, most of the published works that were not used in this analysis were advocacy pieces (such as op-ed columns and newsletter articles) that repeated the assump- tion that charter schools were developing innovations without offering evidence as such. For instance, one author stated that charter schools "have become oases of innovation in a larger desert of monopolistic and cookie-cutter schools," yet provided no evidence to sup- port that conclusion; others argued that there is "no evidence that [charter schools] will make a difference" but, similarly, made no systematic attempt to find evidence that would test that claim (From, 1999; Garcia & Garcia, 1996, p. 34; see also, e.g., Halpern & Culbertson, 1994; Bardallis, 1999). Such reports were not useful here for identifying practices reported to be innovative and so were set aside. Others simply noted the presumed potential for innova- tion in charter schools-based on the theoretical assumption that is the subject of the pre- sent study-again, without any attempt to present evidence on the results of that potential (e.g., Allen, 2001; Kolderie, 1993, 1994, 1995; McCutchen, 1999; Osborne, 1999). Because my analysis focuses on the development of innovations, I did not use studies that looked only at the diffusion of innovations from charter schools to district schools, unless those studies indi- cated that a particular practice was developed first in charter schools (e.g., Fulford et al., 1997; Rofes, 1998b; Wells et al., 1998). Finally, published works were not used here if they described charter schools as a policy innovation-which they are-but did not report on innovative practices in charter schools (e.g., Garcia & Garcia, 1996; Kolderie, 1998).

7This analysis focuses on published works that presented evidence on the issue of innovations in charter schools as a central, or ancillary yet significant, consideration. Of these, 15 were academic journal articles, books, or chapters (and an additional 2 were ref- ereed conference papers) that had undergone a process of scholarly review. The major- ity of studies analyzed here (29) were research or evaluation reports conducted and published by research organizations that would generally be regarded as objective on charter schools and related educational policies; these included universities, regional edu- cational laboratories, government research entities, and nongovernmental research orga- nizations commissioned to conduct official evaluations of charter school programs. In addition, I analyzed 12 reports from policy organizations that are usually regarded as hav- ing established positions on charter schools-10 of which would be seen as strong pro- ponents of choice and charter schools (e.g., the Center for Education Reform, the Center for Market-Based Education, and the Fordham Foundation). These studies-in view of their acknowledged predispositions, data, and methods-were nevertheless useful here in providing valuable insights into charter school practices.

8There is the possibility that publication bias could cause authors of published stud- ies to underrepresent seemingly minor or unremarkable innovations. Thus it is important to note that these reports were published by a diverse set of organizations representing a range of perspectives on the issue of innovation in charter schools. Some might be seen as opponents by charter advocates. But more of these organizations have been active in promoting charter schools or have an interest in their success-so it is reasonable to sus- pect that they would highlight more practices as innovations, given the contentious nature of the issue. Moreover, although some of the reports had been peer-reviewed, others were published directly by the organizations, which would lessen the likelihood that seemingly marginal innovations could be underreported, as they might be for a peer-review sub- mission. Finally, it is notable that, whereas innovation was a central consideration for some of these reports, it was an ancillary issue in others-suggesting different levels of incen- tives to exaggerate or de-emphasize evidence of innovation. Taken together, these factors help to ameliorate any publication bias that would substantially underrepresent the pres- ence of innovative practices.

9 Such a comparison is rather stringent in some respects. In following the market the- ory assumptions regarding governance sectors as the unit of analysis, this approach does not account for the possibility that particular practices may be more highly concentrated in charter schools than in district schools. Nor, as a system-wide analysis, does it give weight to the argument that charter schools may be innovative if they adopt innovations

429

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

that are new in a local context. Indeed, although such conceptions of "innovation" may be valid, they are not consistent with the R&D thesis under scrutiny here; they invoke the analogy not of a "laboratory" for producing new innovations unavailable in district schools but, rather, of a "showroom" for particular educational approaches-perhaps innovative, but not in the sense assumed in market theory.

10 Several researchers note that district schools and even private schools are advertising as a way to differentiate themselves, possibly in response to charter competition (Center for Education Reform, 2000d; Gifford et al., 2000; Glassman, 1998; Keegan, 1999; Lange et al., 1998; Maranto et al., 1999a; Mintrom, 2000b; Miron & Nelson, 2000, 2002; Plank & Sykes, 1999; Reynolds, 2000).

1 The findings regarding innovation, mostly from evidence in single-state (or multi- city) studies, are consistent with evidence available in other state (and province) reports (e.g., Bosetti, 1998, 2001, 2000; Division of Charter Schools & Texas Education Agency, 2000; Dykgraaf & Lewis, 1998; Gifford et al., 2000; Glassman, 1998; Good et al., 2000; Lange et al., 1998; Legislative Audit Bureau [Wisconsin], 1998; Miron & Nelson, 2000; Rosenblum Brigham Associates, 1998; Teske et al., 2000; Triant, 2001; Urahn & Stewart, 1994). They are also consistent with the evidence from multi-state and national-level reports (e.g., Center for Education Reform, 2000b, 2001b; Education Commission of the States, 1995; Finn et al., 1996; Fuller, 2000b; General Accounting Office, 1995; Good & Braden, 2000; Hassel, 1998, 1999a; Manno et al., 1998b; Podgursky & Ballou, 2001; Rebarber, 1997; RPP International, 1997, 1998, 1999; Vanourek et al., 1997, 1998).

12 It may be that charter schools are more likely to adopt innovations than other schools-a possibility beyond the scope of this analysis. For example, it would not be inaccurate to describe team teaching or contracting for certain services as "innovative," even though they were developed outside the charter sector, because such practices rep- resent a significant departure from standard practices in the nations' schools. However, there is a difference between "being innovative" by using innovative practices (adopting innovations developed by others) and "innovating" (developing innovations).

13The Rosenblum Brigham Associates (1998) report contends that charter schools are recombining preexisting practices rather than developing new practices: "[S]pecific practices are not the key innovation implemented in charter schools, but rather the integration of prac- tices around a central vision, and the balance of autonomy and accountability that allows the schools to match practices (including hiring) to the vision." However, most if not all of the "innovations" that the report cited were already in practice in public schools. Perhaps the most comprehensive list of innovative practices in charter schools comes from a report by the Center for Market-Based Education on Arizona charter schools, with examples drawn from case studies (Gifford et al., 2000). However, again, although the authors listed a num- ber of "unique" characteristics of various schools, virtually every aspect was already prac- ticed in public schools, represented changes in administration or governance rather than classroom practice, or had to do with symbolic presentation such as advertising.

"4In Hirschman's (1970) framework, public education is structured to respond to political pressure as a public good-voice expressed through political processes. Public schools are generally not designed to be directly responsive to exit, because (as critics note) they have a semi-monopoly status. But they still often incite dissatisfied users to exit or vote with their feet (see Tiebout, 1956). Thus pathology results. Indeed, as Hirschman notes, as a lazy monopoly, primarily responsive to political pressure, schools may prefer or even encourage dissatisfied and vocal parents to exit in order to get rid of "difficult" individuals.

15Similar centripetal patterns are evident in dual-party political systems and-perhaps counterintuitively-in multiparty politics as well (Mueller, 1979).

16On encouraging brand name recognition in education provisions, see Finn et al. (2000) and Hill (1996). Hill, for instance, lauds the fact that choice and competition can encourage "brand loyalty"-schools should embrace unique approaches as a form of product differentiation.

17Although some argue that advertising associated with product differentiation can promote innovation by increasing overall sales, the general level of demand for education is largely immune to advertising. Furthermore, "many of the innovations introduced by heavily differentiated advertising-intensive industries are of very limited benefit to the con- sumer" (George & Joll, 1981, p. 185).

430

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

18 The possibility that administrative innovations and symbolic activities such as adver- tising can preempt intended innovations in educational activities is apparent in the research on similar reforms in other nations (for an overview, see Lubienski, 2001c). For instance, in the competitive education quasi-market in New Zealand, administrators rec- ognize the relative advantages that can be had through relatively simple changes in sym- bols such as school uniforms, as opposed to the more onerous and costly endeavor of reforming the curriculum (Lauder et al., 1999).

19 Such patterns are evident from a number of contexts, including research on market- oriented school reform in Chile (Espinola, 1993; Gauri, 1998; McEwan & Carnoy, 2000); New Zealand (Fiske & Ladd, 2000; Lauder et al., 1999; Thrupp, 1999; Whitty et al., 1998); and the United Kingdom (Glatter, Woods, & Bagley, 1997; Tomlinson, 1997; Willms & Echols, 1992; Woods et al., 1998). For a review of this literature, see Lubienski (2001c); in the United Kingdom, Gorard, Fitz, and Taylor have challenged claims of resegregation (Fitz & Gorard, 2000; Fitz, Gorard, & Taylor, 2002; Gorard, 1998; Gorard, Fitz, & Taylor, 2001, 2002).

References

Adnett, N., & Davies, P. (2000). Competition and curriculum diversity in local schooling markets: Theory and evidence. Journal of Education Policy, 15(2), 157-167.

Allen, J. (2001). Education by charter: The new neighborhood schools. In J. C. Goodman, & F. F. Steiger (Eds.), An education agenda: Letparents choose their children's school (pp. 56-64). Dallas, TX: National Center for Policy Analysis.

Anderson, L., & Marsh, J. (1998). Early results of a reform experiment: Charter schools in California. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Educational Research Association, San Diego.

Anderson, R. (1997, Spring). Boomers want choice. NWEducation, 2(3). Retrieved November 11, 1999, from http.//www.nwrel.org/nwedu/spring_97/article3.html

Anthes, K., & Ziebarth, T. (2001). Collection of charter schools ECS State Notes. Den- ver, CO: National Center for Governing America's Schools, Education Commis- sion of the States.

Arizona Education Association. (1998, March/April). Charting a change of course: The good, the bad, and the ugly in Arizona's charter schools. AEA Advocate, 24, 14-15.

Arsen, D., Plank, D., & Sykes, G. (1999). School choicepolicies in Michigan: The rules matter. East Lansing: Michigan State University.

Ascher, C., Berne, R., & Fruchter, N. (1996). Hard lessons: Public schools andpriva- tization. New York: Twentieth Century Fund Press.

Bardallis, D. (1999). School choice: It works! [Radio commentary in the "Free Market Moments" series, read by J. Lehman]. Midland, MI: Mackinac Center for Public Policy.

Bartlett, W. (1993). Quasi-markets and educational reforms. In J. LeGrand, & W. Bartlett (Eds.), Quasi-markets and socialpolicy (pp. 125-153). London: Macmillan.

Becker, G. (1999, September 12). Competition. Paper presented at the Address for the Heritage Foundation 25th Anniversary Leadership for America Lectures, Chicago.

Becker, H. J., Nakagawa, K., & Corwin, R. G. (1997). Parent involvement contracts in California's charter schools: Strategy for educational improvement or method of exclusion. Teachers College Record, 98(3), 511-536.

Bennett, W. J., Fair, W., Finn, C. E., Flake, F. H., Hirsch, E. D., Marshall, W., & Ravitch, D. (1998). A nation still at risk. Policy Review (90), 23-29.

Bierlein, L. (1997). The charter school movement. In D. Ravitch & J. P. Viteritti (Eds.), New schools for a new century: The redesign of urban education (pp. 37-60). New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

431

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

Bierlein, L., & Mulholland, L. A. (1994). The promise of charter schools. Educational Leadership, 52(1), 34-36.

Bilefsky, D. (1998, January 30). Welcome to the (1)earning zone. New Statesman, 11, 18-19.

Bolick, C. (1998, May/June). Blocking the exits: Libertarian opposition to school vouchers is an attack on freedom. Policy Review, 42-45.

Bosetti, L. (1998). Canada's charter schools: Initial report. Calgary, AB, Canada: University of Calgary, Society for the Advancement of Excellence in Education.

Bosetti, L. (2001). The Alberta charter school experience. In C. R. Hepburn (Ed.), Can the market save our schools? (pp. 101-120). Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

Bosetti, L., Foulkes, E., O'Reilly, B., & Sande, D. (2000). Canadian charter schools at the crossroads. Calgary, AB: University of Calgary, Society for Advancement of Excellence in Education.

Brandl, J. E. (1998). Governance and educational quality. In P. E. Peterson & B. C. Hassel (Eds.), Learningfrom school choice (pp. 55-81). Washington, DC: Brook- ings Institution Press.

Brighouse, H. (1997). Two philosophical errors concerning school choice. Oxford Review of Education, 23(4), 503-510.

Brown, B. W. (1992). Why governments run schools. Economics ofEducation Review, 11(4), 287-300.

Buchanan, J. M. (2000). The limits of liberty. Between anarchy and leviathan. Indi- anapolis: Liberty Fund.

Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1999). The calculus of consent: Logicalfoundations of constitutional democracy. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

Budde, R. (1988). Education by charter: Restructuring school districts: Key to long- term continuing improvement in American education. Andover, MA: Regional Laboratory for Educational Improvement of the Northeast & Islands.

Buechler, M. (1997, September). Charter schools so far. Education Digest, 63, 60-63. Bush, G. W. (2001). No child left behind: Education blueprint. Washington, DC: The

White House. Caudell, L. S. (1997, Spring). Charters for change. NWEducation, 2. Retrieved Novem-

ber 11, 1999, from http.//www.nwrel.org/nwedu/spring_97/article2.html Center for Education Reform. (2000a, October 17). Center for Education Reform

Newswire, 2(38), 2. Available at http://www.edreform.com/update/001017.html Center for Education Reform. (2000b). Charter schools today: Changing the face of

American education. Washington, DC: Author. Center for Education Reform. (2000c). NSBA charter school report full of holes (CER

Analysis). Washington, DC: Author. Center for Education Reform. (2000d). What the research reveals about charter

schools. Washington, DC: Author. Center for Education Reform. (2001a). Charter school laws: Scorecard and rankings.

Washington, DC: Author. Center for Education Reform. (2001b). What the research reveals about charter

schools. Washington, DC: Author. Chamberlin, E. (1933). The theory of monopolistic competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard

University Press. Chubb, J. E., & Moe, T. M. (1990). Politics, markets, andAmerica's schools. Washington,

DC: Brookings Institution Press. Clayton Foundation. (1997). The Colorado charter schools evaluation, 1996. Denver,

CO: Colorado Department of Education. Clayton Foundation. (1998). 1997 Colorado charter schools evaluation study: The

characteristics, status and student achievement data of Colorado charter schools. Denver, CO: Colorado Department of Education.

432

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

Clayton Foundation. (1999). 1998 Colorado charter schools evaluation study: The characteristics, status and student achievement data of Colorado charter schools. Denver, CO: Colorado Department of Education.

Clinton, W. J. (1997a). President Clinton's call to action for American education in the 21st century. Retrieved August 11, 1998, from http://www.ed.gov/updates/ PresEDPla n/pa rt1996. b tm l

Clinton, W. J. (1997b). State of the Union address. Clinton, W. J. (1999). State of the Union address. Available at http://www.nytimes.

com/library/politics/012099sou-text.html Cobb, C. D., & Glass, G. V. (1999). Ethnic segregation in Arizona charter schools. Edu-

cation Policy Analysis Archives, 7(1). Available at http://epaa.asu.edu/epaa/v7n1/ Coleman, J. S. (1990). Choice, community and future schools. In W. H. Clune & J. F.

Witte (Eds.), Choice and control in American education: Vol. 1. The theory of choice and control in education (pp. ix-xxii). London: Falmer.

Coleman, J. S. (1997). The design of schools as output-driven organizations. In R. Shapira & P. W. Cookson (Eds.), Autonomy and choice in context: An interna- tionalperspective (pp. 249-270). Oxford, UK: Pergamon.

Colorado Department of Education. (2001). The state of charter schools in Colorado, 1999-2000: The characteristics, status and performance record of Colorado charter schools. Denver, CO: Author.

Corwin, R. G., & Flaherty, J. F. (Eds.). (1995). Freedom and innovation in California's charter schools. Los Alamitos, CA: Southwest Regional Laboratory.

Coulson, A. J. (1994). Human life, human organization, and education. Education PolicyAnalysis Archives, 2(9). Retrieved November 14, 1997, from http://olam.ed. asu.edu/epaa/v2n9.btml

Coulson, A. J. (1996). Markets versus monopolies in education: The historical evi- dence. Education Policy Analysis Archives, 4(9). Retrieved November 14, 1997, from http://olam.ed.asu.edu/epaa/v1994nl999.html

Coulson, A. J. (1999). Market education: The unknown history. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.

Cuban, L. (1984). How teachers taught: Constancy and change in American class- rooms, 1890-1980. New York: Longman.

Daft, R. L., & Becker, S. W. (1978). Innovation in organizations: Innovation adop- tion in school organizations. New York: Elsevier.

Davies, S. (1988). Technical change, productivity, and market structure. In S. Davies (Ed.), Economics of industrial organisation (pp. 192-246). London: Longman.

Davies, S., & Lyons, B. (Eds.). (1988). Economics of industrial organisation. London: Longman.

DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomor- phism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2), 147-160.

Division of Charter Schools & Texas Education Agency. (2000). Texas open-enrollment charter schools: Third-year evaluation. Austin, TX: Division of Charter Schools, Texas Education Agency.

Drost, C. (2002, April 30). Pilot charter school program encourages innovative teach- ing. Retrieved from LexusNexis, Associated Press State & Local Wire, dateline Des Moines, IA.

du Pont, P. (2001). A backgrounder on school choice: We can do better. In J. C. Goodman & F. F. Steiger (Eds.), An education agenda: Let parents choose their children's school (pp. 2-10). Dallas, TX: National Center for Policy Analysis.

Dunne, S., Reed, W. R., & Wilbanks, J. (1997). Endogenizing the median voter: Public choice goes to school. Public Choice, 93(1/2), 99-118.

Durant, W. C. (1997). The gift of a child: The promise of freedom: Creative approaches to learning, teaching, and schooling. The Freeman, 4 7(6), 360-364.

433

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

Dykgraaf, C. L., & Lewis, S. K. (1998, October). For-profit charter schools: What the public needs to know. Educational Leadership, 56, 51-54.

Education Commission of the States. (1995). Charter schools: What are they up to? Denver, CO: Author.

Education Commission of the States & National Conference of State Legislatures. (1998). The charter school roadmap. Office of Educational Research and Improvement, U.S. Department of Education.

Espinola, V. (1993). The educational reform of the military regime in Chile: The school system 's response to competition, choice, and market relations. Unpublished doc- toral dissertation, University of Wales, Cardiff.

Finn, C. E., & Gau, R. L. (1998). New ways of education. The Public Interest (130), 79-92.

Finn, C. E., & Manno, B. V. (1998a, September). Support your local charter school. Policy Review, 18-25.

Finn, C. E., & Manno, B. V. (1998b, July/August). The twelve labors of charter schools. The New Democrat, 10. Available at http://www.ndol.org/ndol_ci.cfm?kaid= 11 0&subid= 134&contentid= 1554

Finn, C. E., Manno, B. V., & Bierlein, L. A. (1996). Charter schools in action: What have we learned? Washington, DC: Hudson Institute.

Finn, C. E., Manno, B. V., & Vanourek, G. (2000). Charter schools in action: Renew- ingpublic education. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Fiske, E. B., & Ladd, H. F. (2000). When schools compete: A cautionary tale. Wash- ington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

Fitz, J., & Gorard, S. (2000). School choice and SES stratification ofschools: Newfind- ingsfrom England and Wales. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Educational Research Association, New Orleans.

Fitz, J., Gorard, S., & Taylor, C. (2002, April). Diversifying public education or creat- ing a two-tier system? Lessonsfrom England. Paper presented at the annual meet- ing of the American Educational Research Association, New Orleans.

Fitzgerald, J. (1995). Charter schools in Colorado. Denver, CO: Colorado Children's Campaign.

Fitzgerald, J. (2000). 1998-99 Colorado charter schools evaluation study: The char- acteristics, status and performance record of Colorado charter schools. Denver, CO: Colorado Department of Education.

Flaherty, J. F. (1995). Innovations: What are the schools doing? In R. G. Corwin & J. F. Flaherty (Eds.), Freedom and innovation in California's charter schools (pp. 63-73). Los Alamitos, CA: Southwest Regional Laboratory.

Flake, J. L. (1999). Profits and honor: Whyfor-profit education is a good idea (pp. 99-16). Phoenix, AZ: Goldwater Institute.

Forstmann, T. J. (1999). A competitive vision for American education. Imprimis, 28(9). Available at http://www.hillsdale.edu/imprimis/1999/September/September Text.html

Friedman, M. (1955). The role of government in education. In R. A. Solo (Ed.), Eco- nomics and thepublic interest (pp. 127-134). New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers Uni- versity Press.

Friedman, M. (1994). The case for choice. In K. L. Billingsley (Ed.), Voices on choice: The education reform debate (pp. 91-101). San Francisco: Pacific Research Insti- tute for Public Policy.

Friedman, M. (1995). Public schools: Make them private (Briefing Paper 23). Wash- ington, DC: Cato Institute.

Friedman, M., & Friedman, R. (1980). Free to choose: A personal statement. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

434

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

From, A. (1999, Fall). Where we stand: New Democrats' 10 key reforms for revitalizing American education. Blueprint. Retrieved December 13, 1999, from http://www. dlc.org/blueprint/fall/1999/wherewestand.html

Fulford, N., Raack, L., & Sunderman, G. (1997). Charter schools as change agents: Will they deliver? In North Central Regional Education Laboratory (Ed.), Charters in our midst: The impact of charter schools on school districts. Oak Brook, IL: North Central Regional Education Laboratory.

Fuller, B. (2000a). The public square, big or small? Charter schools in political con- text. In B. Fuller (Ed.), Inside charter schools:. Theparadox of radical decentral- ization (pp. 12-65). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Fuller, B. (Ed.). (2000b). Inside charter schools: The paradox of radical decentral- ization. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Garcia, G. F., & Garcia, M. (1996). Charter schools: Another top-down innovation. Educational Researcher, 25(8), 34-36.

Garn, G. A. (1998, October). The thinking behind Arizona's charter movement. Edu- cational Leadership, 56, 48-51.

Garn, G. A., & Stout, R. T. (1999). Closing charters: How a good theory failed in prac- tice. In R. Maranto, S. Milliman, F. Hess, & A. Gresham (Eds.), School choice in the real world: Lessonsfrom Arizona charter schools (pp. 142-158). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Gauri, V. (1998). School choice in Chile: Two decades of educational reform. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.

General Accounting Office. (1995). Charter schools: A new model forpublic schools provides opportunities and challenges (Report to Congress HEHS-95-42). Wash- ington, DC: Author.

George, K. D., & Joll, C. (1981). Industrial organisation: Competition, growth, and structural change (3rd ed.). London: Allen & Unwin.

Gerstner, L. V., Semerad, R. D., Doyle, D. P., & Johnston, W. B. (1994). Reinventing education: Entrepreneurship in America's public schools. New York: Dutton.

Gifford, M., Phillips, K., & Ogle, M. (2000). Five-year charter school study (Arizona Education Analysis). Phoenix, AZ: Center for Market-Based Education, Gold- water Institute.

Gill, B. P., Timpane, P. M., Ross, K. E., & Brewer, D. J. (2001). Rhetoric versus real- ity: What we know and what we need to know about vouchers and charter schools (MR-1118-EDU). Santa Monica, CA: RAND Education.

Gintis, H. (1995). The political economy of school choice. Teachers College Record, 96(3), 462-511.

Glass, G. V. (1994). School choice: A discussion with Herbert Gintis. Education Pol- icy Analysis Archives, 2(6). Retrieved February 18, 1997, from http://olam.ed. asu.edu/epaa/v1992n1996.html

Glassman, J. K. (1998, April). Class acts. Reason, 29, 24-30. Glatter, R., Woods, P. A., & Bagley, C. (Eds.). (1997). Choice and diversity in school-

ing: Perspectives and prospects. London and New York: Routledge. Glazerman, S. (1998). School quality and social stratification: The determinants and

consequences ofparental school choice. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Educational Research Association, San Diego.

Golden, D. (1999, September 15). Old-time religion gets a boost at a chain of charter schools. Wall Street Journal, pp. Al, 14.

Good, T. L., & Braden, J. S. (2000). The great school debate: Choice, vouchers, and charters. Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum.

Good, T. L., Braden, J. S., & Drury, D. W. (2000). Charting a new course: Fact and fiction about charter schools (11-130-W). Alexandria, VA: National School Boards Association.

435

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

Gorard, S. (1998). Social movement in undeveloped markets: An apparent contra- diction. Educational Review, 50(3), 249-258.

Gorard, S., Fitz, J., & Taylor, C. (2001). School choice impacts: What do we know? Educational Researcher, 30(7), 18-23.

Gorard, S., Fitz, J., & Taylor, C. (2002, April). Measuring markets: The impact ofl2years of school choice. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Educa- tional Research Association, New Orleans.

Greer, D. F. (1984). Industrial organization andpublic policy (2nd ed.). New York: Macmillan.

Halpern, K., & Culbertson, E. R. (1994). Blueprintforchange: Charterschools. Wash- ington, DC: Democratic Leadership Council.

Hannan, M. T., & Freeman, J. H. (1977). The population ecology of organizations. American Journal of Sociology, 82(5), 929-964.

Hassel, B. C. (1998). Charter schools: Politics and practice in four states. In P. E. Peterson & B. C. Hassel (Eds.), Learning from school choice (pp. 249-271). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

Hassel, B. C. (1999a). The charter school challenge: Avoiding thepitfalls, fulfilling the promise. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

Hassel, B. C. (1999b). Charter schools: A national innovation, an Arizona revolution. In R. Maranto, S. Milliman, F. Hess, & A. Gresham (Eds.), School choice in the real world: Lessons from Arizona charter schools (pp. 68-95). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Henderson, R. (1997, January). Schools of thought. Reason Online. Available at http:// www. reason.com/9701/fe. rick.html

Henig, J. (1994). Rethinking school choice: Limits of the market metaphor. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Henig, J. (1996). The local dynamics of choice: Ethnic preferences and institutional responses. In B. Fuller & R. F. Elmore (Eds.), Who chooses? Who loses? Culture, institutions, and the unequal effects of school choice. New York: Teachers Col- lege Press.

Hess, F. M. (1998). Policy churn and the plight of urban school reform. In P. E. Peter- son & B. C. Hassel (Eds.), Learning from school choice (pp. 107-129). Washing- ton, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

Hill, C. W. L., & Jones, G. R. (1989). Strategic management theory: An integrated approach. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.

Hill, P. T. (1996, June). The educational consequences of choice. Phi Delta Kappan, 77, 671-676.

Hill, P. T., Lake, R., Celio, M. B., Campbell, C., Herdman, P., & Bulkley, K. (2001). A study ofcharter school accountability. Seattle, WA: Center on Reinventing Pub- lic Education, Daniel J. Evans School of Public Affairs, University of Washington.

Hill, P. T., Pierce, L. C., & Guthrie, J. W. (1997). Reinventingpublic education: How con- tracting can transform America 's schools. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Hirschman, A. 0. (1970). Exit, voice, and loyalty: Responses to decline infirms, orga- nizations, and states. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Horn, J., & Miron, G. (1999). Evaluation of the Michigan public school academy initiative. (Final Report). Kalamazoo, MI: Evaluation Center, Western Michigan University.

Horn, J., & Miron, G. (2000). An evaluation of the Michigan charter school initiative: Performance, accountability, and impact (Final Report). Kalamazoo, MI: Evalu- ation Center, Western Michigan University.

Howe, K. R. (1997). Understanding equal educational opportunity: Social justice, democracy, and schooling. New York: Teachers College Press.

436

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

Howe, K. R., Eisenhart, M., & Betebenner, D. (2001, October). School choice crucible: A case study of Boulder Valley. Phi Delta Kappan, 83, 137-146.

Hoxby, C. M. (1994). Doprivate schoolsprovide competitionforpublic schools? (Work- ing Paper 4978). Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Huerta, L. A. (2000). Losing public accountability: A home schooling charter. In B. Fuller (Ed.), Inside charterschools: Theparadox of radical decentralization (pp. 177-202). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Illinois School Code, ? 27A-2 (b). (1996). Available at http.//www.isbe.state.il.us/charter/ law.html

Jacobson, L. (1997, January). Charting the charters: As charter schools sweep the coun- try, the big question for researches is: Do they work? TeacherMagazine, 8, 12-15.

Jacquemin, A. (1987). The new industrial organization: Market forces and strategic behavior. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Kalt, J. P., & Zupan, M. A. (1984). Capture and ideology in economic theory of pol- itics. American Economic Review, 74(3), 279-300.

Kane, P. R. (1998, October 14). Charter schools: Paying attention to ancillary findings. Education Week, 18, 42, 45.

Kearns, D. T., & Doyle, D. P. (1988). Winning the brain race: A boldplan to make our schools competitive. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies Press.

Keegan, L. G. (1999). The empowerment of market-based school reform. In R. Maranto, S. Milliman, F. Hess, & A. Gresham (Eds.), School choice in the real world: Lessons from Arizona charter schools (pp. 189-197). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Khouri, N., Kleine, R., White, R., & Cummings, L. (1999). Michigan's charter school initiative: From theory to practice (Final Report). Lansing, MI: Public Sector Consultants and MAXIMUS.

Kohn, A. (1998, April). Only for my kid: How privileged parents undermine school reform. Phi Delta Kappan, 79, 568-578.

Kolderie, T. (1990). Beyond choice to newpublic schools: Withdrawing the exclusive franchise in public education (Policy Report 8). Washington, DC: Progressive Policy Institute.

Kolderie, T. (1992). Chartering diversity. Equity and Choice, 9(1), 28-31. Kolderie, T. (1993, November). The states begin to withdraw the "exclusive." Chang-

ing Schools, 21, 1-8. Kolderie, T. (1994). Charters: An invitation to change. Educational Leadership,

52(1), 36. Kolderie, T. (1995, September 22). The charter idea: Update andprospects: Fall '95.

Washington, DC: Center for Education Reform. Kolderie, T. (1998). What does it mean to ask: "Is 'charterschools' working?" (ED426133).

St. Paul, MN: Charter Friends National Network. Labaree, D. F. (1997). Public goods, private goods: The American struggle over edu-

cational goals. American Educational Research Journal, 34(1), 39-81. Labaree, D. F. (2000). No exit: Public education as an inescapably public good. In

L. Cuban & D. Shipps (Eds.), Reconstructing the common good in education: Coping with intractable American dilemmas (pp. 110-129). Stanford, CA: Stan- ford University Press.

Lane, B. (1999). Choice matters: Policy alternatives and implications for charter schools. Portland, OR: Northwest Regional Educational Laboratory.

Lange, C., Lehr, C., Seppanen, P., & Sinclair, M. (1998). Minnesota charter schools evaluation: Final report. Center for Applied Research and Educational Improve- ment, College of Education and Human Development, University of Minnesota.

Lauder, H., Hughes, D., Watson, S., Waslander, S., Thrupp, M., Strathdee, R., et al. (1999). Trading in futures: Why markets in education don't work. Buckingham, UK: Open University Press.

437

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

Legislative Audit Bureau (Wisconsin). (1998). An evaluation, charter schoolprogram, State of Wisconsin (98-15). Madison, WI: Legislative Audit Bureau.

Lehman, T. E. (1997). Government schooling: The bureaucratization of the mind. The Freeman, 48(7), 266-269.

Leonardi, R. C. (1998). Charter schools in Ohio: The rush to mend them should not end them (Perspective on Current Issues). Dayton, OH: Buckeye Institute for Public Policy Solutions.

Levin, B. (1997). The lessons of international education reform. Journal ofEducation Policy, 12(4), 253-266.

Levin, B., & Riffel, J. A. (1997). School system responses to external change: Implica- tions for parental choice of schools. In R. Glatter, P. A. Woods, & C. Bagley (Eds.), Choice and diversity in schooling: Perspectives andprospects (pp. 44-58). London: Routledge.

Levin, B., & Young, J. (1999). The origins of educational reform: A comparative per- spective. CanadianJournal ofEducationalAdministration and Policy (12). Avail- able at http://www.umanitoba.ca/publications/cjeap/articles/younglevin.html

Levin, H. M. (1998). Educational vouchers: Effectiveness, choice, and costs. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 17(3), 373-392.

Lieberman, M. (2001). Innovation in the school choice debate (Brief 010801). Wash- ington, DC: Education Policy Institute.

Light, R. J., & Pillemer, D. B. (1984). Summing up: The science of reviewing research. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Link, J., Gordon, H., & Khanna, R. (1999). Urban seedbedsfor charter schools: A thou- sand flowers blooming. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Educational Research Association, Montreal.

Little Hoover Commission. (1996). The charter movement: Education reform, school by school (Report No. 138). Sacramento, CA: State of California.

Lubienski, C. (2001a). Institutionalist and instrumentalist perspectives on 'public" education: Strategies and implications of the school choice movement in Michi- gan (Occasional Paper 39). New York: National Center for the Study of Privati- zation in Education, Teachers College, Columbia University.

Lubienski, C. (2001b). Redefining "public" education: Charter schools, common schools, and the rhetoric of reform. Teachers College Record, 103(4), 634-666.

Lubienski, C. (2001c). The relationship of competition and choice to innovation in education markets: A review of research on four cases (Occasional Paper 26). New York: National Center for the Study of Privatization in Education, Teachers College, Columbia University.

Lubienski, C. (2002). Horizontal and vertical diversification in school choice systems: Evidence and implications. Unpublished manuscript, Iowa State University.

Lubieksni, C. (in press). Instrumentalist perspectives on the "public" in public edu- cation: Incentives and purposes. Educational Policy.

Mackinac Center for Public Policy. (1999, Winter). Public schools step up marketing. Michigan Education Report. Available at http://www.educationreport.org/pubs/mer/ cover.asp?ID= 1562

Manno, B. V. (2001, May). The case against charter schools. The School Administra- tor. Available at http://www.aasa.org/publications/sa/2OlO5/2O001_manno. htm

Manno, B. V., Finn, C. E., Bierlein, L. A., & Vanourek, G. (1998a). Charter schools: Accomplishments and dilemmas. Teachers College Record, 99(3), 537-558.

Manno, B. V., Finn, C. E., Bierlein, L. A., & Vanourek, G. (1998b, March). How char- ter schools are different: Lessons and implications for a national study. Phi Delta Kappan, 79, 489-498.

438

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

Mansfield, E. (1970). Microeconomics: Theory and applications. New York: Norton. Maranto, R. (1999). The death of one best way: Charter schools as reinventing gov-

ernment. In R. Maranto, S. Milliman, F. Hess, & A. Gresham (Eds.), School choice in the real world: Lessonsfrom Arizona charter schools (pp. 39-57). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Maranto, R., Milliman, S., Hess, F., & Gresham, A. (1999a). Do charter schools improve district schools? Three approaches to the question. In R. Maranto, S. Milliman, F. Hess, & A. Gresham (Eds.), School choice in the real world: Lessons from Arizona charter schools (pp. 129-141). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Maranto, R., Milliman, S., Hess, F., & Gresham, A. (1999b). In lieu of conclusions: Tentative lessons from a contested frontier. In R. Maranto, S. Milliman, F. Hess, & A. Gresham (Eds.), School choice in the real world: Lessonsfrom Arizona char- ter schools (pp. 237-247). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

McCutchen, K. (1999). World class school shows potential of Georgia charter school law (Commentary). Atlanta: Georgia Public Policy Foundation.

McEwan, P. J., & Carnoy, M. (2000). The effectiveness and efficiency of private schools in Chile's voucher system. Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis, 22(3), 213-239.

Medler, A. (1996). Promise and progress. American School Board Journal, 183(3), 26-28.

Metz, M. H. (1990). Real school: A universal drama amid disparate experience. In D. E. Mitchell & M. E. Goertz (Eds.), Education politics for the new century (pp. 75-91). New York: Falmer.

Meyer, J. W. (1992). Innovation and knowledge use in American public education. In J. W. Meyer & W. R. Scott (Eds.), Organizational environments: Ritual and rationality (updated ed., pp. 233-260). Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications.

Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1992a). Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. In J. W. Meyer & W. R. Scott (Eds.), Organizational envi- ronments: Ritual and rationality (updated ed., pp. 21-44). Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications.

Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1992b). The structure of educational organizations. In J. W. Meyer & W. R. Scott (Eds.), Organizational environments: Ritual and rational- ity (updated ed., pp. 71-97). Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications.

Meyer, J. W., Scott, W. R., & Deal, T. E. (1992). Institutional and technical sources of organizational structure: Explaining the structure of educational organiza- tions. In J. W. Meyer, & W. R. Scott (Eds.), Organizational environments: Ritual and rationality (updated ed., pp. 45-67). Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Pub- lications.

Meyer, J. W., Scott, W. R., Strang, D., & Creighton, A. L. (1994). Bureaucratization without centralization: Changes in the organizational system of U.S. Public edu- cation, 1940-1980. In W. R. Scott & J. W. Meyer & Associates (Eds.), Institutional environments and organizations: Structural complexity and individualism (pp. 179-205). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.

Minnesota Statutes, Education Code: Prekindergarten-Grade 12?124D.10, Sub. 1. (1991). Available at http://www.isbe.state. il. us/charter/law.html.

Mintrom, M. (1997). The state-local nexus in policy innovation diffusion: The case of school choice. Publius, 27(3), 41-59.

Mintrom, M. (2000a). Does choice encourage innovation and improvement in school? In D. N. Plank & G. Sykes (Eds.), The school choice debate: Framing the issues (pp. 23-30). East Lansing, MI: Education Policy Center at Michigan State University.

Mintrom, M. (2000b). Leveraging local innovation: The case of Michigan's charter schools. East Lansing, MI: Michigan State University.

439

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

Mintrom, M. (2000c). Policy entrepreneurs and school choice. Washington, DC: George- town University Press.

Mintrom, M. (2001). Educational governance and democratic practice. Educational Policy, 155), 615-643.

Mintrom, M., & Vergari, S. (1997). Charter schools as a state policy innovation: Assess- ing recent developments. State & Local Government Review, 29(1), 43-49.

Miron, G., & Nelson, C. (2000). Autonomy in exchange for accountability: An initial study ofPennsylvania charter schools. Kalamazoo, MI: Evaluation Center, Western Michigan University.

Miron, G., & Nelson, C. (2002). What'spublic about charter schools? Lessons learned about choice and accountability. Thousand Oaks, CA: Corwin Press.

Molnar, A. (1996, October). Charter schools: The smiling face of disinvestment. Edu- cational Leadership, 54, 9-15.

Moore, D., & Davenport, S. (1990). School choice: The new improved sorting machine. In W. Boyd & H. Walberg (Eds.), Choice in education (pp. 187-223). Berkeley, CA: McCutchan.

Mueller, D. C. (1979). Public choice. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Nathan, J. (1996a). Charterschools: Creating hope and opportunityforAmerican edu-

cation. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Nathan, J. (1996b, Winter). Progressives should support charter public schools.

Rethinking Schools, 11, 20-21. Nathan, J. (1998, March). Heat and light in the charter school movement. Phi Delta

Kappan, 79, 499-505. Nathan, J. (2002, May 29). A charter school decade. Education Week, 21, 32-35. Nathan, J., & Power, J. (1996). Policy-makers view the charter school movement. Cen-

ter for School Change, Humphrey Institute, University of Minnesota. National Governors' Association. (1986). Time for results. Washington, DC: Author. National Governors' Association. (1998). Charterschools: Challenging traditions and

changing attitudes (Issue Brief). Washington, DC: Author. New Jersey Department of Education. (2001). Report on charter school hearings.

Trenton, NJ: Author. Niskanen, W. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine. No Child Left Behind Act of 2001, Pub. L. No. 107-110 ? Title V. (2002). Available at

http://www. ed.gov/legislation/ESEA 02/. Oettle, K. (1997). Has there been a change of paradigm in managerial economics

from the public enterprise toward the regulated (privatized) enterprise? Annals of Public and Co-Operative Economy, 68(3), 367-377.

Osborne, D. (1999). Healthy competition: The benefits of charter schools. The New Republic. Retrieved August 31, 2000, from http://www.tnr.com/archive/1099/ 100499/osborne 00499.html

Payne, J. L. (2000). The agony of public education. Independent Review, 52), 265-275. Peterson, P. E. (1990). Monopoly and competition in American education. In

W. H. Clune & J. F. Witte (Eds.), Choice and control in American education: Vol. 1. The theory of choice and control in education (pp. 47-78). London: Falmer.

Peterson, P. E. (1998). School choice: A report card. In P. E. Peterson & B. C. Hassel (Eds.), Learning from school choice (pp. 3-32). Washington, DC: Brookings Insti- tution Press.

Pini, M. E. (2001). Moving public schools towardfor-profit management: Privatizing the public sphere. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Edu- cational Research Association, Seattle, WA.

Plank, D. N., & Sykes, G. (1997). Effects of charter schools and interdistrict choice. Paper presented at the Michigan State University College of Education, Policy Forum, East Lansing, MI.

440

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

Plank, D. N., & Sykes, G. (1999). How choice changes the education system: A Michi- gan case study. International Review ofEducation, 45(5/6), 385-416.

Podgursky, M., & Ballou, D. (2001). Personnelpolicy in charter schools. Washington, DC: Thomas B. Fordham Foundation.

Powers, J., & Cookson, P. (1999). Thepolitics of school choice research: Fact, fiction, and statistics. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Educa- tional Research Association, Montreal.

Price, J. H. (1998, June 22). America's quiet revolution. Insight on the News, 14, 40-42. Ravitch, D. (2000). Left back: A century offailed school reforms. New York: Simon &

Schuster. Raywid, M. A. (1996). The Wadleigh complex: A dream that soured. In R. L. Crow-

son, W. L. Boyd, & H. B. Mawhinney (Eds.), The politics of education and the new institutionalism: Reinventing the American school (pp. 101-114). Washing- ton, DC: Falmer.

Reardon, S. F., & Yun, J. T. (2002). Private school racial enrollments and segregation. Cambridge, MA: Civil Rights Project at Harvard University.

Rebarber, T. (1997). Charter school innovations: Keys to effective charter reform (Policy Study 228). Los Angeles: Reason Public Policy Institute.

Reese, W. J. (1995). The origins of the American high school. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

Reynolds, K. (2000). Innovations in charter schools: A summary of innovative or unique aspects ofMichigan charter schools. Kalamazoo, MI: Evaluation Center, Western Michigan University.

Ritter, G. W., Rush, A., & Rush, J. (2002). How might school choice affect racial inte- gration in schools? New evidence from the ECLS-K. Georgetown Public Policy Review, 7(2), 125-136.

Robinson, J. (1933). The economics of imperfect competition. London: Macmillan. Robson, W. (2001). Publicly funded education in Ontario: Breaking the deadlock. In

C. R. Hepburn (Ed.), Can the market save our schools? (pp. 13-39). Vancouver, BC, Canada: Fraser Institute.

Rofes, E. (1996). Charters: Finding the courage to face our contradictions. In R. Lowe, B. Miner, L. Miller, B. Peterson, & R. Tenorio (Eds.), Selling out our schools: Vouchers, markets, and the future ofpublic education (pp. 50-51). Milwaukee, WI: Rethinking Schools.

Rofes, E. (1998a, March/April). Charter schools expand: Will they encourage public school reform? Dollars and Sense (216), 27-31.

Rofes, E. (1998b). How are school districts responding to charter laws and charter schools? Berkeley, CA: Policy Analysis for California Education.

Rogers, E. M. (1995). Diffusion of innovations (4th ed.). New York: Free Press. Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1979). Bureaucrats versus voters: On the political econ-

omy of resource allocation by direct democracy. Quarterly Journal of Econom- ics, 93(4), 563-587.

Rosenblum Brigham Associates. (1998). Innovation and Massachusetts charterschools. Boston: Rosenblum Brigham Associates, for the Massachusetts Department of Education.

Rothstein, R., Carnoy, M., & Benveniste, L. (1999). Can public schools learn from private schools? Washington, DC: Economic Policy Institute and Aspen Institute.

RPP International. (1997). A study of charter schools: First-year report (SAI 97-3007). Washington, DC: Office of Educational Research and Improvement, U.S. Depart- ment of Education.

441

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Lubienski

RPP International. (1998). A national study of charter schools: Second-year report. Washington, DC: Office of Educational Research and Improvement, U.S. Depart- ment of Education.

RPP International. (1999). The state of charter schools: Third-year report (National Study of Charter Schools). Washington, DC: Office of Educational Research and Improvement, U.S. Department of Education.

RPP International. (2001). Challenge and opportunity: The impact of charter schools on school districts (A Report of the National Study of Charter Schools). Wash- ington, DC: Office of Educational Research and Improvement, U.S. Department of Education.

Schnaiberg, L. (1999, December 1). Entrepreneurs hoping to do good, make money. Education Week, 19, 1, 14, 16.

Scott, W. R., & Meyer, J. W. (1994). Environmental linkages and organizational com- plexity: Public and private schools. In W. R. Scott & J. W. Meyer & Associates (Eds.), Institutional environments and organizations: Structural complexity and individualism (pp. 137-159). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.

Shepherd, W. G. (1997). The economics of industrial organization: Analysis, markets, policies (4th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Smith, K. B., & Meier, K. J. (1995). The case against school choice: Politics, markets, and fools. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.

Smrekar, C. (1996). The impact of school choice and community: In the interest of families and schools. Albany: State University of New York Press.

SRI International. (1997). Evaluation of charter school effectiveness. Sacramento, CA: Office of the Legislative Analyst.

Stout, R. T., & Garn, G. A. (1999). Nothing new: Curricula in Arizona charter schools. In R. Maranto, S. Milliman, F. Hess, & A. Gresham (Eds.), School choice in the real world: Lessons from Arizona charter schools (pp. 159-172). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Symonds, W. C., Palmer, A. T., & Hylton, H. (2001, March 19). How to fix America's schools. Business Week. Retrieved March 17, 2001, from http://www.businessweek. com/magazine/content/2001_2012/b3 724001.htm

Teske, P., Schneider, M., Buckley, J., & Clark, S. (2000). Does charter school compe- tition improve traditional public schools? New York: Manhattan Institute for Pol- icy Research.

Thrupp, M. (1999). Schools making a difference--Let's be realistic! School mix, school effectiveness, and the social limits of reform. Philadelphia: Open University Press.

Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal ofPolitical Econ- omy, 64(4), 416-424.

Tomlinson, S. (1997). Diversity, choice, and ethnicity: The effects of educational markets on ethnic minorities. Oxford Review of Education, 23(1), 63-76.

Tooley, J. (1999). Asking different questions: Towards justifying markets in educa- tion. In N. Alexiadou & C. Brock (Eds.), Education as a commodity (pp. 9-19). Suffolk, UK: John Catt.

Triant, B. (2001). Autonomy and innovation: How do Massachusetts charter school principals use theirfreedom? Washington, DC: Thomas B. Fordham Foundation.

Tyack, D., (1974). The one best system: A history ofAmerican urban education. Cam- bridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Tyack, D., & Cuban, L. (1995). Tinkering toward Utopia: A century ofpublic school reform. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Tyack, D., & Tobin, W. (1994). The "grammar" of schooling: Why has it been so hard to change? American Educational Research Journal, 31(3), 453-480.

Urahn, S., & Stewart, D. (1994). Minnesota charter schools: A research report. St. Paul, MN: Minnesota State House Research Department.

442

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Innovation in Education Markets

Vanourek, G., Manno, B. V., Finn, C. E., & Bierlein, L. A. (1997). Charter schools in action. Indianapolis and Washington, DC: Hudson Institute.

Vanourek, G., Manno, B. V., Finn, C. E., & Bierlein, L. A. (1998). Charter schools as seen by students, teachers, and parents. In P. E. Peterson & B. C. Hassel (Eds.), Learning from school choice (pp. 187-211). Washington, DC: Brookings Institu- tion Press.

Viteritti, J. P. (1999). Choosing equality: School choice, the constitution and civil society. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

Wakeley, T. M. (1997). Innovation, welfare, and industrial structure: An evolution- ary analysis. Aldershot, UK: Avebury.

Walberg, H. J. (2000, July 12). Market theory of school choice. Education Week, 19, 46, 49.

Walberg, H. J., & Bast, J. L. (2001). Understanding market-based school reform: In M. C. Wang & H. J. Walberg (Eds.), School choice or best systems: What improves education? (pp. 3-38). Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum.

Walsh-Sarnecki, P. (1999, February 18). Grand Rapids firm near record charter school package. Detroit Free Press. Retrieved February 18, 1999, from http://www.freep. com/news/education/qchartl 8.htm

Wells, A. S. (1993). Time to choose: America at the crossroads of school choicepolicy. New York: Hill & Wang.

Wells, A. S., Artiles, L., Carnochan, S., Cooper, C. W., Grutzik, C., Holme, J. J., et al. (1998). Beyond the rhetoric of charter school reform: A study of ten California districts. Los Angeles: University of California, Graduate School of Education and Information Studies.

West, E. G. (1982). The public monopoly and the seeds of self-destruction. In M. E. Manley-Casimir (Ed.), Family choice in schooling: Issues and dilemmas (pp. 185-198). Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.

West, E. G. (1995). Education with and without the state (Working paper for the World Bank). Available at www.schoolchoices.org

West, E. G. (1996). Education vouchers in practice and principle: A world survey. World Bank Research Observer, 12(1), 83-103.

Whitty, G., Power, S., & Halpin, D. (1998). Devolution and choice in education: The school, the state, and the market. Bristol, PA: Open University Press.

Willms, J. D., & Echols, F. (1992). Alert and inert clients: The Scottish experience of parental choice of schools. Economics of Education Review, 11(4), 339-350.

Wohlstetter, P., & Griffin, N. (1997). First lessons: Charter schools as learning com- munities (Policy Brief RB 22). Philadelphia: Consortium for Policy Research in Education.

Wohlstetter, P., & Griffin, N. (1998). Creating and sustaining learning communities: Early lessons from charter schools (CPRE Occasional Paper Series OP-03). Philadelphia: Consortium for Policy Research in Education.

Woods, P. A., Bagley, C., & Glatter, R. (1998). School choice and competition: Mar- kets in the public interest? London: Routledge.

Manuscript received January 3, 2002 Revision received July 30, 2002

Accepted January 25, 2003

443

This content downloaded from 131.247.112.3 on Thu, 17 Oct 2013 11:58:59 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions