Inequality and Partisanship: A Look at State Level Trends in Ticket Splitting

35
Inequality and Partisanship: A Look at State Level Trends in Ticket Splitting Matthew Sommerfeld George Mason University PUB 840 Professor Pfiffner Fall 2014

Transcript of Inequality and Partisanship: A Look at State Level Trends in Ticket Splitting

                               Inequality  and  Partisanship:  A  Look  at  State  Level  Trends  in  Ticket  Splitting  

 Matthew  Sommerfeld  

George  Mason  University  PUB  840  -­‐  Professor  Pfiffner  

Fall  2014                                                  

  2  

Ticket  Splitting  and  Partisanship  

Much  has  been  written,  both  in  the  popular  media  and  in  scholarship,  about  

the  increasing  partisanship  and  polarization  among  voters  and  politicians  in  

Washington.1  Indeed,  a  cursory  examination  of  election  data  over  the  last  30  years  

reveals  trends  that  indicate  voters  are  becoming  less  willing  to  vote  for  politicians  

opposite  to  that  of  their  individual  partisan  loyalties.2  As  these  partisan  and  

ideological  loyalties  become  stronger  with  each  passing  election,  the  willingness  of  

voters  to  ‘split  their  ticket’  becomes  less  prevalent  as  well.3  The  convergence  of  

elite-­‐level  polarization,  mass  level  partisan  sorting,  and  consequently  the  decline  of  

ticket  splitting  have  led  to  various  scholars  to  conclude  that,  short  of  substantial  

process  reforms,  politics  in  Washington  is  destined  to  continue  down  its  current  

trend  of  gridlock,  particularly  in  times  of  divided  government.4    

Since  1972  polarization  and  partisan  sorting  have  both  increased  

substantially,  and  consequently  ticket  splitting  has  predictably  decreased  as  well.  

For  instance,  the  number  of  House  districts  with  opposite  party  candidates  winning  

elections  has  decreased  from  44  in  1972  to  just  6  in  2012.  Likewise,  in  the  Senate  

the  number  of  Senators  representing  a  state  in  which  their  party’s  presidential  

                                                                                                               1  Nolan  McCarthy,  Keith  T.  Poole,  and  Rosenthal,  Polarized  America:  The  Dance  of  Ideology  and  Unequal  Riches,  First  MIT  Press  Paperback  Ed.  (Cambridge,  MA:2006);  Alan  I.  Abramowitz  and  Kyle  L.  Saunders,  “Is  Polarization  a  Myth?”  The  Journal  of  Politics.  Vol.  Vol.  70,  No.  2,  (2008),  Pp.  542–555;  Morris  P.  Fiorina  and  Samuel  J.  Abrams,  “Political  Polarization  in  the  American  Public,”  Annual  Review  of  Political  Science,  Vol.  11,  (2008)  pp.  563-­‐568.  2  Gary  C.  Jacobson,  “Partisan  Polarization  in  American  Politics:  A  Background  Paper,”  Presidential  Studies  Quarterly,  Vol.  43.  No.  4  (2013),  pp.  688-­‐708.  3  Ticket  splitting  refers  to  when  an  individual  votes  for  different  parties  for  different  offices  on  the  same  ticket,  i.e.  if  someone  votes  Democratic  for  Congress  and  Republican  for  President.  4  Sarah  Binder,  Stalemate:  Causes  and  Consequences  of  Legislative  Gridlock,  Brookings  Institution  (Washington,  DC:2003);  Thomas  E.  Mann  and  Norman  J.  Orstein,  It’s  Even  Worse  than  It  Looks:  How  the  American  Constitutional  System  Collided  with  the  New  Politics  of  Extremism,  Basic  Books  (New  York:2012).  

  3  

candidate  lost  in  the  most  recent  election  has  decreased  from  59  to  21  during  that  

same  time  duration  (Figure  1).5  As  Republicans  and  Democrats  in  Congress  have  

become  more  ideologically  homogenous  in  their  respective  caucuses,  and  

individuals  in  the  electorate  more  ideologically  consistent,  the  propensity  among  

voters  to  support  candidates  from  different  parties  for  different  offices,  broadly  

speaking,  has  simultaneously  decreased.    

 Data  taken  from  Jacobson  (2013),  pp.  701  

 

Although  ticket  splitting  saw  a  short-­‐lived  spike  in  the  late  1980s  (largely  

due  to  Reagan  Democrats),  the  trend  dropped  off  precipitously  in  the  early  1990s,  

just  as  the  Southern  Realignment  crystallized  under  Gingrich’s  tutelage.6  Many  of  

the  explanations  regarding  polarization  and  partisan  sorting  can  be  applied  to  the  

decline  of  ticket  splitting  –  as  voters  become  more  ideologically  consistent,  and  thus  

                                                                                                               5  Jacobson,  “Partisan  Polarization  in  American  Politics:  A  Background  Paper,”  (2013),  pp.  701  6  Sean  M.  Theriault  and  David  W.  Rohde,  “The  Gingrich  Senators  and  Party  Polarization  in  the  U.S.  Senate,”  The  Journal  of  Politics,  Vol.  73,  No.  4,  (2011),  Pp.  1011–1024.  

0  

10  

20  

30  

40  

50  

60  

70  

1972  1976  1980  1984  1988  1992  1996  2000  2004  2008  2012  

Figure  1:  Split  Ticket  Voting  in  Districts  and  Senate  Seats  (1972-­‐2012)    

Senate  

House  

  4  

hold  stronger  partisan  loyalty,  then  their  willingness  to  support  candidates  of  

opposite  parties  for  different  offices  should  decline  as  well.    

However,  despite  these  trends,  some  states  continue  to  split  their  ticket  with  

a  higher  frequency  than  other  states  (see  figure  2).7  Since  the  Senate  went  to  a  

popular  vote  (1912),  tendency  to  ticket  split  at  the  state  level  ranges  from  about  

53%  (Montana)  to  5.5  percent  (Kansas).  Most  ticket  splitting  scholarship  focuses  on  

micro-­‐level  characteristics  of  voters  or  particularistic  factors  of  certain  Senate  and  

House  campaigns.  However,  few  have  examined  statewide  factors  in  order  to  

explain  the  variance  of  a  state’s  willingness  to  vote  for  different  parties  for  President  

and  the  Senate.  This  analysis  attempts  to  fill  this  empirical  shortcoming,  specifically  

emphasizing  economic  inequality  as  a  key  causal  variable  influencing  why  some  

states  split  their  tickets  more  frequently  than  others.    

 Data  taken  from  Ostermeier  (2011)  

 

                                                                                                               7  Eric  Ostermeier,  “Which  States  Have  the  Most  Split-­‐Ticket  Voting  in  Presidential-­‐U.S.  Senate  Election  Cycles?”  University  of  Minnesota  Humphrey  School  of  Public  Policy,  Oct.  5,  2011,  URL:  http://blog.lib.umn.edu/cspg/smartpolitics/2011/04/which_states_have_the_most_spl.php,  accessed  on:  11/02/14.  

0  

10  

20  

30  

40  

50  

60  

MT   ND   RI  

OR  

LA  

MN  

AR  

DE  

NH  

PA  

MA  

MO   GA  

NV   NJ  

SD  

WA  

ME   TN  

AK  

AL  

NE  

NY   VA  

CA  

CO  

FL  

KY  

HI   IA  

MD   OH  

AZ  

MS  

NM  

SC  

WV   ID  

OK  

CT  

MI  

TX  

VT  

IL  

WI  

IN  

NC  

UT  

WY   KS  

Figure  2:  State  %  Split  Ticket  (1912-­‐2010)  

  5  

While  some  research  does  indeed  examine  inequality  in  relation  to  

polarization  in  Congress  and  micro-­‐level  partisan  sorting,  few  have  attempted  to  

empirically  test  the  correlation  between  macro-­‐level  inequality  and  partisanship.8  

The  micro-­‐level  theoretical  foundations  in  support  of  inequality  as  a  contributing  

factor  to  polarization  and  partisan  sorting  rests  on  the  notion  that  as  individuals  

find  themselves  either  on  the  lower  or  higher  ends  of  the  income  ladder,  they  tend  

to  base  their  voting  decisions  more  and  more  on  economic  policies,  particularly  

those  on  the  wealthier  end  of  the  spectrum.9  One  may  thus  hypothesize  that  similar  

dynamics  are  at  play  at  the  macro  level.  As  a  geographical  area  becomes  more  

unequal  economically,  and  the  percentage  of  the  populace  that  could  be  considered  

‘middle-­‐class’  declines,  the  levels  of  partisan  attachment  and  polarization  may  

increase  a  long  with  it.  Conversely,  as  inequality  becomes  more  pronounced,  the  

electorate  in  that  given  area  may  cling  to  partisan  and  ideological  attachments  more  

strongly.  Thus,  with  this  theoretical  foundation  in  mind,  a  hypothesis  is  formulated  

as  follows:  States  with  higher  levels  of  inequality  are  less  likely  to  split  their  ticket  

(Senate  and  President)  than  states  with  lower  levels  of  inequality.  The  subsequent  

sections  summarize  the  literature  regarding  polarization,  partisan  sorting,  and  

ticket  splitting  in  more  depth,  specify  the  analytical  framework  employed  to  test  the  

hypothesis,  and  finally  discuss  the  limitations  and  suggest  strategies  for  future  

research.    

Polarization,  Partisan  Sorting,  and  Ticket  Splitting  

Polarized  Congress  –  Empirical  Evidence  and  Causes                                                                                                                  8  McCarty,  Poole,  and  Rosenthal,  Polarized  America  (2006)  9  McCarty,  Poole,  and  Rosenthal,  Polarized  America  (2006),  pp.  71-­‐114  

  6  

  The  most  widely  accepted  measure  of  polarization  at  the  Congressional  level  

comes  from  McCarty,  Poole,  and  Rosenthal’s  DW-­‐NOMINATE  (NOM)  scoring  system,  

developed  in  the  early  1980s.  NOM  analyzes  every  roll  call  vote  in  Congress  and  

identifies  each  Members’  ‘ideal  point’,  ranging  from  -­‐1  (most  liberal)  to  +1  (most  

conservative).10  Common  definitions  of  polarization  in  Congress  take  into  account  

the  mean  scores  of  Republicans  and  Democrats,  while  measuring  the  distance  

between  them.  Based  on  this  method,  the  113th  Congress  was  the  most  polarized  

since  the  Civil  War  Era  (Figure  3).  

Figure  3:  Party  Polarization  (1879-­‐2012)  

 

  As  the  NOM  scores  were  finished  being  tabulated  for  the  113th  Congress,  

there  was  literally  zero  overlap  between  the  most  liberal  Republican  and  the  most  

Conservative  Democrat  for  the  first  time  in  recent  history.11  Likewise,  the  number  of  

moderates  (measured  as  having  a  NOM  score  between  -­‐0.25  and  +0.25)  has  

                                                                                                               10  Keith  Poole,  Voteview,  URL:  www.voteview.com.  Accessed  on  11/10/14  11  Mann  and  Ornstein,  It’s  Even  Worse  Than  It  Looks  (2012),  p.  45  

  7  

decreased  from  about  40%  in  1980  (both  the  Senate  and  the  House)  to  just  six  

percent  of  House  Members  and  13  percent  of  Senators  in  the  112th  Congress.12    

  Theoretically,  the  two-­‐party  system  employed  by  the  United  States  should  

induce  candidates  to  appeal  to  the  ‘median  voter’  within  their  respective  

constituencies,  thus  moderating  the  parties  overall.13  However,  as  the  foregoing  

data  indicate,  lawmakers  in  Washington  have  been  gravitating  towards  the  extreme  

ends  of  the  ideological  spectrum.  Initial  theories  explaining  this  phenomenon  

typically  attribute  the  Southern  Realignment  as  a  primary  causal  factor  that  led  to  

the  homogenization  of  the  two  parties.  Prior  to  the  1960s,  the  ‘one  party  South’  

unanimously  supported  Democratic  candidates  for  both  Presidential  and  

Congressional  races,  due  largely  to  lingering  resentment  directed  towards  the  party  

of  Lincoln.14  This  tended  to  ‘moderate’  the  Democratic  Party  because  southerners,  

despite  voting  Democratic,  remained  ideologically  conservative.  Thus,  various  

alliances  would  often  develop  between  Republicans  and  Southern  ‘Dixiecrats’  (the  

Conservative  Coalition),  most  notably  while  opposing  various  Civil  Rights  

proposals.15  Eventually,  Republican  candidates  for  president  began  to  gain  support  

from  Southern  constituencies,  beginning  with  the  1964  election  between  Lyndon  

Johnson  and  Barry  Goldwater  (later  Nixon  would  adopt  what  would  be  called  the  

‘Southern  Strategy’,  which  was  emulated  by  Reagan).  Polsby  attributes  this  

movement  among  southern  conservatives  to  the  invention  and  proliferation  of  air  

                                                                                                               12  Keith  Poole,  “An  Update  on  Political  Polarization  through  the  112th  Congress”,  URL:  http://voteview.com/blog/?p=726,    accessed  on  11/10/14.  13  Anthony  Downs,  An  Economic  Theory  of  Democracy,  Harper  and  Row,  1st  Ed.  (1957)  14  V.O.  Key,  Southern  Politics  in  State  and  Nation.  New  York:  A.A.  Knopf  (1949)  15  Nelson  W.  Polsby,  How  Congress  Evolves:  Social  Bases  of  Institutional  Change.  Oxford  University  Press  (New  York:  2004)  

  8  

conditioning,  which  facilitated  the  migration  of  northern  conservatives  to  the  

South.16  Others  argue  that  President  Johnson’s  support  of  the  Civil  Rights  Act  was  

the  beginning  of  the  end  for  Democrats  in  the  South,  as  racial  animosities  finally  

overcame  ideological  and  partisan  contradictions.17  These  assertions  are  supported  

by  Sunquist’s  observation  that  the  undertaking  of  new  issues,  and  thus  the  creation  

of  new  cleavages,  often  leads  to  party  realignments  within  the  electorate.18    

  During  that  transitional  period  from  about  1960-­‐1994,  polarization  in  

Congress  remained  relatively  low  as  a  result  of  conservative  Dixiecrats  in  the  South  

that  moderated  the  average  NOM  scores  for  the  Democratic  Party  as  a  whole.  

Meanwhile,  northern  Republicans,  who  have  since  largely  disappeared  since  the  

early  1990s  as  well,  provided  substantial  ideological  diversity  within  their  own  

party,  thus  decreasing  the  distance  between  parties.  However,  the  Gingrich-­‐led  

‘Republican  Revolution’  in  1994  shifted  partisan  loyalties  in  the  South  to  

Republicans  in  Congressional  races  for  the  first  time.19  The  completion  of  the  

realignment  has  resulted  in  the  recent  extinction  of  white  Democratic  Members  of  

Congress  representing  southern  districts,  further  exacerbating  polarization.20    

  Aside  from  the  Southern  Realignment,  other  institutional  explanations  have  

been  found  to  contribute  to  polarization  in  Congress  as  well.  For  instance,  the  

declining  competition  in  Congressional  races  has  been  blamed  on  a  combination  of  

                                                                                                               16  Polsby,  How  Congress  Evolves  (2004),  pp.  80-­‐82  17  Richard  H.  Pildes,  Why  the  Center  Does  Not  Hold:  The  Causes  of  Hyperpolarized  Democracy  in  America,  99  CALIF.  L.  REV.  273,  288  (2011).  18  James  L.  Sunquist,  Dynamics  of  the  Party  System:  Alignment  and  Realignment  of  Political  Parties  in  the  United  States,  The  Brookings  Institution,  (Washington,  D.C.:1983).  19  Mann  and  Ornstein,  It’s  Even  Worse  Than  It  Looks  (2012),  pp.  31-­‐43.  20    Deirdre  Walsh,  “Last  white  Democrat  from  Deep  South  loses  Congressional  seat,”  Nov.  5,  2014.  URL:  http://www.cnn.com/2014/11/05/politics/last-­‐southern-­‐white-­‐democrat-­‐in-­‐congress/;  accessed  on  11/20/14.  

  9  

gerrymandering  and  ‘partisan  sorting’.21  Arguing  for  the  latter,  Bishop  hypothesizes  

that  voters  have  been  self-­‐sorting  into  ideologically  like-­‐minded  geographical  areas,  

which  tends  to  result  in  single-­‐party  dominance  in  a  higher  proportion  of  districts  

than  was  the  case  in  the  past.  Silver’s  analysis  following  the  2012  election  supports  

this  claim,  as  the  number  of  competitive  seats  (+/-­‐  5%  of  the  national  popular  vote  

margin)  in  Congressional  elections  has  declined  drastically  since  1992.22  He  finds  

that  out  of  the  103  districts  (24%)  that  were  deemed  competitive  in  1992,  only  35  

remain  (8%).  Moreover,  Gerber  and  Morton  claim  that  closed  primaries  induce  

extremism  by  keeping  moderate  voters  (who  are  less  likely  to  register  with  one  of  

the  two  parties)  out  of  the  candidate  selection  process.23  However,  this  debate  is  far  

from  settled,  as  Hassel’s  more  recent  analysis  produced  mixed  results  on  the  

‘primary  effect’,  largely  due  to  the  fact  that  turnout  in  primaries  is  often  

inconsistent,  regardless  of  whether  it  is  open  or  closed.24  These  analyses  provide  

empirical  evidence  for  media  narratives  and  other  scholarly  research  that  

emphasize  the  impact  of  the  fear  of  being  ‘primaried’  from  a  more  ideologically  pure  

candidate  from  the  left  or  from  the  right,  respectively.25  This  fear  tends  to  

                                                                                                               21  Bill  Bishop.  The  Big  Sort:  Why  the  Clustering  of  Like-­‐Minded  America  is  Tearing  Us  Apart.  Mariner  Books  (2009).    22  Nate  Silver,  “As  Swing  Districts  Dwindle,  Can  a  Divided  House  Stand?”  The  New  York  Times.  27  Dec.  2012.  URL:  http://fivethirtyeight.blogs.nytimes.com/2012/12/27/as-­‐swing-­‐districts-­‐dwindle-­‐can-­‐a-­‐divided-­‐house-­‐stand/  ,  accessed  on:  11/20/14.  23  Elisabeth  R.  Gerber  and  Rebecca  B.  Morton,  “Primary  Election  Systems  and  Representation,”  Journal  of  Law,  Economics,  and  Organization,  Vol.  14  pp.  304-­‐324.  24  Hans  Hassel,  “The  Non-­‐Existent  Primary-­‐Ideology  Link,  or  Do  Open  Primaries  Actually  Limit  Party  Influence  in  Primary  Elections?  Presentation  at  the  2013  State  Politics  and  Policy  Conference,  University  of  Iowa,  Iowa  City,  Iowa.(2013)  25  Kathleen  Bawn,  Martin  Cohen,  David  Karol,  Seth  Masket,  Hans  Noel,  and  John  Zaller,  “A  Theory  of  Political  Parties:  Groups,  Policy  Demands  and  Nominations  in  American    Politics,  “  Perspectives  in  Politics,  Vol.  10,  (2012)  pp  571-­‐597.  

  10  

incentivize  lawmakers  to  cater  to  the  more  extreme  members  of  their  party,  rather  

than  to  the  median  voter  in  their  district  or  state.    

Partisan  Sorting  within  the  Electorate  

  The  foregoing  trends  regarding  the  polarization  of  Congress  and  the  decline  

of  competitive  seats  and  states  in  presidential  and  Congressional  elections  had  led  

scholars  to  inquire  as  to  whether  the  general  electorate  is  becoming  more  extreme  

in  their  views  as  well.  This  debate  is  largely  unsettled,  with  disagreements  centering  

on  measurement  issues  and  conceptualization  of  what  it  means  to  be  ‘polarized.’26  

At  the  center  of  the  dispute  are  Abramowitz  and  Fiorina,  the  former  contending  that  

the  electorate  is  in  fact  moving  further  apart,  while  the  latter  arguing  that  rather  

than  polarization,  the  phenomenon  we  are  experiencing  can  be  better  characterized  

as  ‘partisan  sorting’.27  Fiorina  concedes  that  voters  have  become  more  ideologically  

consistent  and  tend  to  identify  more  strongly  with  a  party  than  they  had  in  the  past;  

however,  he  claims  that  the  extremity  of  their  views  is  not  necessarily  more  

pronounced  than  in  past  decades.28  Depending  on  the  issue,  Fiorina  finds,  the  

electorate  has  either  shifted  to  the  right  or  left  collectively,  but  not  necessarily  more  

extreme  on  the  ends,  aside  from  a  few  issues.  That  being  the  case,  there  is  no  need  to  

sound  the  alarmist  bells  that  the  population  at  large  is  on  the  brink  of  tearing  each  

other  apart  over  political  differences.    

                                                                                                               26  Morris  P.  Fiorina,  Samuel  A.  Abrams,  Jeremy  C.  Pope,  “Polarization  in  the  American  Public:  Misconceptions  and  Misreadings,”  The  Journal  of  Politics,  Vol.  70,  No.  2,  (2008),  Pp.  556–560;  Abramowitz  and  Saunders,  “Is  Polarization  a  Myth?”  (2008).  27  Matthew  Levendusky,  The  Partisan  Sorty:  How  Liberals  Became  Democrats  and  Conservatives  Became  Republicans.  University  of  Chicago  Press  (2009).    28  Levendusky,  The  Partisan  Sort  (2009)  

  11  

Scholars  do  tend  to  agree  that  at  the  very  least,  a  significant  increase  in  

partisan  sorting  has  been  taking  place  in  recent  decades.  A  2014  Pew  Report  

underscores  these  trends,  finding  that  both  Republicans  and  Democrats  become  

more  ideologically  consistent  from  1994-­‐2014,  with  perceptions  of  the  ‘other  party’  

becoming  more  negative  as  well.  29  While  it  is  unclear  whether  individuals  in  the  

mass  public  hold  stronger  views  on  an  issue-­‐by-­‐issue  basis  than  they  did  in  the  past,  

the  evidence  is  clear  that  politics  has  become  more  tribal  in  recent  decades.      

Explanations  regarding  the  causal  mechanisms  for  partisan  sorting  vary  as  

well.  For  instance,  Levendusky  attributes  partisan  sorting  to  elite  polarization,  with  

a  causal  process  similar  to  that  of  Katz  and  Lazarsfeld’s  influential  two-­‐step  flow  

model  of  media  effects.30  He  argues  that  polarized  elites  contribute  to  voters  

becoming  more  loyal  to  their  partisan  identification  (and  more  adversarial  to  the  

opposite  side)  with  the  language  they  use  and  the  bills  proposed  in  Congress.  

Levendusky’s  causal  process  centers  on  two  diverging  routes  that  voters  may  take  

to  become  more  sorted:  altering  their  ideology  to  conform  to  their  partisanship,  or  

vice  versa  -­‐  altering  their  partisanship  to  match  their  ideology.  This  elite-­‐driven  

explanation  is  supported  by  Abramowitz  and  Saunders’  argument,  which  posits  

increases  in  education  levels  over  the  past  50  years  has  made  individuals  more  

cognizant  of  their  ideological  and  partisan  leanings,  and  thus  voters  become  more  

consistent  and  polarized  in  the  process  (rather  than  changing  their  opinions  on  an  

issue  based  on  cognitive  accessibility).    

                                                                                                               29  Pew  Research  Center,  “Political  Polarization  in  the  American  Public”  (2014)  30  See  Levendusky,  p.  12-­‐37  (2009);  Elihu  Katz  and  Paul  Lazarsfeld  Personal  Influence:  The  Part  Played  by  People  in  the  Flow  of  Mass  Communications.  Transaction  Publishers,  2nd  (2005)  

  12  

However,  considerable  scholarship  identifies  information  sources  as  the  

primary  culprits  contributing  to  partisan  sorting  and  polarization.  Prior’s  emphasis  

on  the  media  environment  serves  as  an  especially  compelling  example.31  He  argues  

that  when  individuals  only  consumed  network  news  because  of  a  lack  of  

alternatives,  their  views  were  moderated  by  the  more  objective  reporting  

disseminated  by  these  stations,  a  phenomenon  often  referred  to  as  ‘by-­‐product’  

learning.32As  cable  news  sources  proliferated,  only  the  genuinely  interested  (and  

more  inherently  partisan)  remained  attuned  to  politics  of  the  day,  resulting  in  

increased  demand  for  more  partisan  and  extreme  commentary  in  the  media  (those  

who  were  not  genuinely  interested  have  opted  for  entertainment  programming,  an  

option  that  was  not  available  in  the  ‘pre-­‐cable  era’).  While  the  polarizing  effect  on  

the  latent  public  may  not  be  that  pronounced,  according  to  Prior,  those  who  have  

maintained  interest  in  political  news,  despite  other  entertainment  options,  have  

become  more  polarized  over  time.  Contributing  to  the  polarizing  phenomenon,  the  

consumers  of  partisan  political  news  are  also  more  likely  to  participate  in  the  

selection  of  candidates  for  office,  leaving  the  disengaged  ‘moderates’  to  choose  

between  the  two  extremes.  Prior’s  findings  lend  support  to  Fiorina’s  claims  that,  

while  active  partisans  may  have  become  more  extreme  in  recent  decades,  a  

substantial  ‘moderate  middle’  remains.    

 

 

                                                                                                               31  Markus  Prior,  Post-­‐Broadcast  Democracy:  How  Media  Choice  Increases  Inequality  in  Political  Involvement  and  Polarizes  Elections.  Cambridge  University  Press  (2007).  32  Downs,  An  Economic  Theory  of  Democracy  (1957),  p.  223  

  13  

Ticket  Splitting:  Micro  and  Macro  Explanations  

  Historically,  ticket  splitting  has  followed  a  similar  path  to  that  of  polarization  

and  partisan  sorting,  albeit  inversely.  As  polarization  in  Congress  and  partisan  

sorting  in  the  electorate  have  increased,  ticket  splitting  has  simultaneously  

decreased  as  well.  Focusing  just  on  the  Senate,  one  can  see  this  inverse  relationship  

between  the  percentage  of  the  electorate  with  ‘strong  political  attachments’  and  the  

number  of  Senators  representing  states  that  voted  for  the  opposite  party’s  

candidate  in  the  most  recent  presidential  election  (Figure  4).33      

 Data  taken  from  Jacobson  (2013)    

    Research  regarding  Senate  voting  behavior  largely  supports  this  trend,  

finding  ideology  and  partisanship  as  key  factors  influencing  individuals’  candidate  

preferences.34  Abramowitz,  for  instance,  examines  the  political  and  demographic  

characteristics  of  the  state  (partisanship,  ideology,  and  population),  characteristics  

                                                                                                               33  Jacobson,  “Partisan  Polarization  in  American  Politics:  A  Background  Paper”  (2013)  34  Alan  I.  Abramowitz,  “Explaining  Senate  Election  Outcomes,”  The  American  Political  Science  Review,  Vol.  82,  No.  2  (1988),  pp.  385-­‐403;  (1988);  Philip  E.  Converse,  “The  Concept  of  the  ‘Normal  Vote’”,  in  Elections  and  the  Political  Order,  ed.  Angus  Campbell,  Philip  E.  Converse,  Warren  E.  Miller  and  Donald  E.  Stokes.  New  York:  Wiley  (1966);  Steven  J.  Rosenstone,  Forecasting  Presidential  Elections.  Yale  University  Press,  (New  Have:1983).    

0  

10  

20  

30  

40  

50  

60  

70  

1972  1976   1980  1984  1988   1992  1996   2000  2004  2008   2012  

%  Ticket  Splitting/Strong  Party  

Attachment  

Figure  4:  Senate  Ticket  Splitting  and  Party  Attachment  (1972-­‐2012)  

  14  

of  the  candidates  (voting  record  and  congruence  with  ideology  of  electorate,  

scandals,  personal  health,  intra-­‐party  conflict,  available  funds,  quality  of  challenger),  

and  national  political  conditions  (party  competence  evaluations,  midterm  or  

presidential  year),  finding  that  candidate  characteristics  had  the  strongest  impact  on  

election  outcomes.35  Jacobson,  however,  argues  that  campaign  spending  may  

contribute  to  challengers  overcoming  incumbency  advantages,  but  only  at  the  

margins.36  Southwell  examines  the  degree  to  which  intra-­‐party  conflict  potentially  

damages  incumbents  in  the  form  of  a  primary  challenge.37  She  finds  that  divisive  

attacks  during  primaries  can  in  fact  leave  partisans  disappointed  with  their  party’s  

candidate  during  the  general  election,  thus  hurting  their  reelection  chances.  Finally,  

Lewis-­‐Beck  and  Rice  find  that  presidential  approval  and  the  state  of  economy  have  a  

positive  effect  on  Senate  candidates  who  share  the  same  party  label  as  the  

president.38  

   In  regards  to  the  particular  phenomenon  of  ticket  splitting,  Campell  and  

Sumners  examine  the  ‘coattail  effect’  in  presidential  and  senate  elections  from  1972  

to  1988.  They  find  only  a  modest  bump  for  Senate  candidates  of  the  same  party  as  

the  president,  as  partisanship  and  ideology  are  more  predictive.39  Jacobson  analyzes  

candidate  aptitude  in  order  to  explain  why  voters  in  the  South  continued  to  support  

Democrats  in  House  elections,  despite  consistently  voting  Republican  in  presidential  

                                                                                                               35  Abramowitz,  “Explaining  Senate  Election  Outcomes”  (1988)  36  Gary  Jacobson,  “The  Effects  of  Campaign  Spending  on  Congressional  Elections,”  American  Political  Science  Review,  Vol.  72  (1978),  pp.  769-­‐783.  37  Priscilla  Southwell,  “The  Politics  of  Disgruntlement:  Nonvoting  and  Defection  among  Supporters  of  Nomination  Losers,  1968-­‐1984,”  Political  Behavior,  Vol.  8  (1986)  pp.  81-­‐95.    38  Michael  S.  Lewis-­‐Beck  and  Tom  W.  Rice,  "Are  Senate  Election  Outcomes  Predictable?"  PS:  Political  Science  &  Politics,  Vol.  18.4  (1985)  pp.  745-­‐754.  39  James  E.  Campbell  and  Joe  A.  Sumners,  “Presidential  Coattails  in  Senate  Elections,”  The  American  Political  Science  Review,  Vol.  84,  No.  2  (1990),  pp.  513-­‐524.  

  15  

races  from  1946-­‐1988.40  He  claims  that  in  addition  to  the  Democrats  fielding  higher  

quality  candidates,  voters  actually  preferred  to  have  conservatives  in  charge  of  

national  finances  (the  presidency),  while  simultaneously  supporting  Democratic  

House  candidates  who  continue  to  support  spending  programs  locally.  Alesina  and  

Rosenthal  contribute  to  these  findings,  putting  forward  a  ‘policy  balancing’  model  in  

order  to  explain  voter  preference  for  divided  government,  and  thus  ticket  splitting.41  

They  claim  that  many  voters  strategically  split  their  ticket  in  order  to  achieve  

moderate  policies,  which  they  perceive  is  the  result  of  forcing  the  two  parties  to  

compromise  over  major  legislation.    

Others  have  since  tested  and  refuted  the  ‘candidate  centered  hypothesis’,  

finding  a  strong  correlation  between  the  increase  in  party  loyalty  and  a  decrease  in  

ticket  splitting  over  the  years,  the  effect  of  which  trumps  any  candidate-­‐specific  

qualities  or  economic  conditions.42  In  summary,  the  key  micro-­‐level  characteristics  

that  predict  ticket  splitting  tend  to  center  on  the  strength  of  partisanship,  ideology,  

and  candidate  characteristics;  while  macro-­‐level  explanations  emphasize  national  

economic  conditions  and  presidential  approval.  However,  the  causal  variable  seems  

to  be  influenced  heavily  on  the  time  period  in  question.  When  ticket  splitting  was  

common  (from  about  1950-­‐1988),  individual  candidate  qualities  were  more  

predictive  of  electoral  success;  however,  as  we  have  entered  an  era  in  which  ticket  

                                                                                                               40  Gary  Jacobson,  The  Electoral  Origin  of  Divided  Government:  Competition  in  U.S.  House  Elections,  1946-­‐1988.  Westview  Press  (1990).  41  Alberto  Alesina  and  Howard  Rosenthal,  Partisan  Politics,  Divided  Government,  and  the  Economy,  Cambridge  University  Press  (1995).  42  Martin  P.  Wattenberg,  The  Rise  of  Candidate-­‐Centerted  Politics:  Presidential  Elections  of  the  1980s.  Harvard  University  Press,  (Cambridge,  MA:1991);  Elizabeth  Gerber  and  Adam  Many,  “Incumbency-­‐Led  Ideological  Balancing:  A  Hybrid  Model  of  Split-­‐Ticket  Voting,”  Presented  at  the  annual  meeting  of  Midwest  Political  Science  Association,  Chicago  (1996).    

  16  

splitting  is  less  common,  ideology  and  partisanship  of  the  voters  has  become  more  

relevant.    

Inequality  and  Ticket  Splitting  

  Despite  the  plethora  of  scholarship  on  ticket  splitting,  partisanship,  and  

voting  behavior,  few  have  examined  the  effect  that  rising  inequality  may  have  on  the  

political  divisiveness.  As  the  gap  between  the  ‘haves’  and  the  ‘have  nots’  becomes  

more  pronounced,  do  individuals  become  more  partisan  as  well?  It  stands  to  reason  

that  as  individuals  find  themselves  in  economic  hardship,  their  opinions  become  

more  favorable  to  redistribution  policies.43  Similarly,  as  one  becomes  more  affluent,  

he  or  she  is  likely  to  prefer  policies  that  decrease  the  tax  burden  on  those  in  the  

wealthiest  tax  brackets.    

As  alluded  to  previously,  McCarty,  Poole,  and  Rosenthal  do  examine  this  

relationship,  hypothesizing  that  ‘income  inequality  has  important  implications  for  

political  conflict.44  They  find  that  individuals  are  more  likely  to  vote  on  economic  

issues  than  they  did  in  the  past,  a  trend  that  can  largely  be  explained  by  rising  

inequality,  which  began  to  take  off  in  the  early  1980s.45  For  instance,  in  1956,  a  

respondent  from  the  highest  income  quintile  was  only  25%  more  likely  to  identify  

as  a  Republican  than  was  a  respondent  from  the  lowest  economic  quintile.  However,  

in  1960,  that  number  was  only  13%,  and  throughout  the  1990s,  a  respondent  is  

more  than  twice  (100%)  as  likely  to  identify  as  a  Republican  if  she  is  in  the  highest  

quintile  than  if  she  is  in  the  lowest.  Although  they  employ  these  findings  in  order  to  

                                                                                                               43  McCarty,  Poole,  and  Rosenthall,,  Polarized  America  (2006)  p.  71-­‐114  44  McCarty,  Poole,  and  Rosenthal,  Polarized  America  (2006)  pp.  75.  45  McCarty,  Poole,  and  Rosenthall,,  Polarized  America  (2006)  p.  71-­‐114  

  17  

explain  Congressional  polarization,  similar  theoretical  logic  may  be  attributed  to  

partisan  strength  at  the  state  level.    

Going  back  further  in  history,  Ingraham  plots  the  correlation  between  

inequality  and  polarization  from  1917  to  2011.46  Years  in  which  income  inequality  

has  been  the  most  pronounced  (1927,  2007)  have  also  been  times  of  high  political  

polarization.  He  notes  that  the  post-­‐World  War  II  era,  in  which  both  polarization  

and  inequality  were  low,  relatively  speaking,  may  actually  have  been  an  anomaly.  He  

then  looks  at  individual  voter  preferences  and  the  relationship  with  the  proportion  

of  the  income  owned  by  the  top  1%  of  the  population.  As  Figure  5  illustrates,  

Republicans  have  become  much  more  partisan  as  wealthiest  have  accumulated  a  

higher  percentage  of  the  country’s  total  income  (R2  =  0.56).  Meanwhile,  Democrats’  

partisanship  has  increased  as  well,  but  not  nearly  to  the  same  degree  (R2  =  0.08).  

Figure  5:  Inequality  and  Partisanship  Republicans  

 

Democrats  

 

Tables  taken  from  Ingraham  (2014)  

                                                                                                               46  Christopher  Ingraham,  “Inequality  and  political  polarization  have  been  rising  in  tandem  for  three  decades,”  Washington  Post  Wong  Blog,  May,  27,  2014.  URL:  http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2014/05/27/inequality-­‐and-­‐political-­‐polarization-­‐have-­‐been-­‐rising-­‐in-­‐tandem-­‐for-­‐three-­‐decades/,  accessed  on:  11/25/14.  

  18  

  Indeed,  strong  correlations  can  be  found  between  various  measures  of  

ideological  and  partisan  strength  and  inequality  (measured  as  the  share  of  the  total  

income  accumulated  by  the  top  10%  of  the  population).  Figure  6  illustrates  the  

correlation  between  the  percentage  of  income  owned  by  the  top  10%  of  the  

population  and  the  percentage  of  the  population  who  hold  ‘strong  party  

attachment’,  from  1973-­‐2012.47  As  inequality  has  increased,  the  proportion  of  the  

electorate  identifying  with  either  the  Republicans  or  Democrats  has  increased  as  

well.  

 Inequality  data  take  from  Frank  (2012);  party  attachment  data  taken  from  Green,  Coffey,  and  

Cohen  (2014)    

  Similarly,  ideological  sorting  and  consistency  correlates  with  increases  in  

inequality.  Figure  7  illustrates  the  mean  difference  between  liberals  and  

conservatives  on  the  self-­‐placement,  seven-­‐category  scale.  In  1972,  the  ideological  

difference  between  liberals  and  conservatives  was  nearly  non-­‐existent,  with  a  

majority  of  respondents  landing  somewhere  near  the  moderate  ‘four’  response.  In  

                                                                                                               47John  C.  Green,  Daniel  J.  Coffey,  and  David  B.  Cohen,  The  State  of  the  Parties:  The  Changing  Role  of  Contemporary  American  Parties,  Rowman  &  Littlefield  Publishers;  7th  Edition  (2014).  

15.00%  20.00%  25.00%  30.00%  35.00%  40.00%  45.00%  50.00%  

1972   1976   1980   1984   1988   1992   1996   2000   2004   2008   2012  

Figure  6:  Inequality  and  Party  Attachment  (1972-­‐2012)  

Top  10%     %  Strong  Party  Attachment    

  19  

2012,  however,  the  average  liberal  and  conservative  is  nearly  two  full  points  from  

each  other  on  the  self-­‐placement  scale.    

 Inequality  data  take  from  Frank  (2012);  ideological  strength  data  taken  from  Green,  Coffey,  and  

Cohen  (2014)    

  Over  the  past  few  decades,  partisanship  at  the  state  level  has  been  on  the  rise  

as  well.  Figure  8  plots  the  rising  average  partisan  strength  of  all  the  states  and  

inequality  since  1994.  The  data  presented  here  corresponds  to  Abramowitz  and  

Saunders  claims  regarding  the  decline  of  ‘purple’  states  that  presidential  candidates  

tend  to  focus  on  during  campaigns.  Measured  with  Cook’s  PVI,  the  average  

partisanship  has  increased  from  4.95  in  1994  to  10.18  in  2014.48    

 Inequality  data  take  from  Frank  (2012);  Cook’s  PVI  data  taken  from  Cook  Political  Report  (2013)  

                                                                                                               48  Cook’s  PVI  explanation  -­‐  A  state’s  PVI  is  calculated  by  averaging  a  state’s  two  party  presidential  vote  in  the  previous  two  elections  to  the  national  share  of  the  popular  vote.  

0  

1  

2  

3  

25.00%  

35.00%  

45.00%  

55.00%  

1972   1976   1980   1984   1988   1992   1996   2000   2004   2008   2012  

Figure  7:  Inequality  and  Differences  Between  Liberals  and  Conservatives  (1972-­‐2012)  

Top  10%  (left)   Mean  Difference  Lib-­‐Cons  

2  

7  

12  

30.00%  35.00%  40.00%  45.00%  50.00%  

1994   1998   2002   2006   2010   2014  

Figure  8:    Inequality  and  Partisanship  in  the  States  (1994-­‐2014)  

Top  10%  (left)   Cook's  PVI  (right)  

  20  

    Finally,  as  is  the  case  with  partisanship  and  ticket  splitting,  an  inverse  

relationship  exists  between  rising  inequality  and  the  decline  of  ticket  splitting  

(Figure  9).  As  the  percentage  of  the  total  income  owned  by  the  top  10%  of  the  

population  has  increased  since  1972,  the  number  of  Senators  from  states  with  

opposite  partisanship  for  presidential  voting  has  decreased  along  with  it.    

 Inequality  data  take  from  Frank  (2012);  ticket  splitting  data  taken  from  Jacobson  (2013)  

      The  foregoing  data  are  thus  the  theoretical  basis  for  the  hypothesis,  restated  

here:  the  more  unequal  a  state  is  economically,  the  less  likely  it  is  that  voters  will  split  

their  tickets  in  Senate  and  Presidential  voting.  Although  the  data  indicating  

correlations  do  not  necessarily  indicate  a  causal  relationship,  purpose  of  the  

subsequent  sections  is  an  attempt  to  isolate  the  effect  of  inequality  on  partisanship,  

measured  in  this  instance  by  ticket  splitting.  

Methodology  and  Data  

In  order  to  isolate  and  measure  the  relationship  between  an  inequality  and  

ticket  splitting,  an  ordinary  least  squares  (OLS)  statistical  test  is  conducted.  A  

10  

20  

30  

40  

50  

60  

70  

25.00%  

30.00%  

35.00%  

40.00%  

45.00%  

50.00%  

1972   1976   1980   1984   1988   1992   1996   2000   2004   2008   2012  

Figure  9:  Inequality  and  Ticket  Splitting  

Top  10%  (left)   #  Split  Ticket  Senators  (right)  

  21  

number  of  control  variables  that  have  been  found  to  contribute  to  ticket  splitting  

have  been  added  to  the  model  in  order  to  isolate  the  effect  of  inequality  on  the  

dependent  variable,  ticket  splitting.  

Dependent  Variable  –  Ticket  Splitting  

The  dependent  variable,  ticket  splitting,  is  measured  by  tabulating  the  

percentage  of  years  that  a  state  was  represented  by  a  Senator(s)  from  the  party  

opposite  to  that  of  which  it  voted  in  elections  from  2001-­‐2013.  Thus  a  state  is  ‘red’  

or  ‘blue’  if  it  voted  either  Republican  or  Democratic  in  every  election  during  that  

time  span.  Any  state  that  voted  for  both  a  Republican  and  Democratic  candidate  

between  2001-­‐2013  is  dropped  from  the  analysis.49  The  percentage  of  ticket  

splitting  is  calculated  by  dividing  the  number  of  years  an  opposite  party  Senator  

held  the  seat  by  26  (13  years,  multiplied  by  two  seats  for  each  state).  Figures  9  and  

10  illustrate  the  breakdown  of  ticket  splitting  in  red  and  blue  states,  respectively.  

The  proportion  of  ‘blue  state  Republicans’  ranges  from  96.2%  (Maine)  to  0%  (10  

states)  (Figure  11).  Similarly,  the  proportion  of  ‘red  state  Democrats’  ranges  from  

100%  (West  Virginia)  to  0%  (10  states)  (Figure  12).    

 

 

 

 

 

                                                                                                               49  Nate  Silver,  “Party-­‐Line  Voting  Makes  Scott  Brown  Part  of  a  Dying  Breed  in  the  Senate,”  538  Politics,  Feb.  4,  2013,  URL:  http://fivethirtyeight.com/features/party-­‐line-­‐voting-­‐makes-­‐scott-­‐brown-­‐part-­‐of-­‐a-­‐dying-­‐breed-­‐in-­‐the-­‐senate/,  accessed  on:  10/05/14,  note  that  there  are  40  total  red  and  blue  states,  10  ‘purple’  states  are  omitted  from  the  analysis.  

  22  

Figure  10:  Republican  Senators  in  Blue  States  (2001-­‐2013)  

 Data  taken  from  Silver  (2013)  

 Figure  11:  Democratic  Senators  in  Red  States  (2001-­‐2013)  

 Data  taken  from  Silver  (2013)  

    This  analysis  focuses  only  on  Senate  races  for  a  number  of  reasons.  First,  

previous  scholarship  has  found  that  individuals  tend  to  have  more  familiarity  with  

  23  

Senate  races  than  those  in  the  House  because  the  elections  are  more  prominent.50  

Secondly,  fewer  Senators  run  unopposed,  and  thus  the  elections  tend  to  be  more  

competitive  overall.51  Finally,  since  this  analysis  is  focusing  on  statewide  

characteristics,  focusing  on  an  office  in  which  the  entire  state  is  the  constituency  

lends  more  validity  to  the  methodology.  House  races  may  provide  diverging  insights  

regarding  candidate  characteristics  and  geographical  sorting  effects;  however,  

analyzing  Senate  races  enables  one  to  test  the  inequality  hypothesis  put  forward  

here  more  effectively.  

Independent  Variable  -­‐  Inequality  

  The  primary  independent  variable,  income  inequality,  is  measured  by  the  

percentage  of  the  income  owned  by  the  wealthiest  10%  within  each  state.  Data  was  

collected  from  Mark  W.  Frank’s  database;  income  shares  are  calculated  by  dividing  

top  income  series  by  total  personal  income.52    Aside  from  the  convenience  of  data  

collection,  the  ‘top  10%’  measure  is  widely  used  and  accepted  by  economists  and  

political  scientists  alike.  Although  the  primary  strength  of  the  measurement  is  its  

ability  to  delineate  among  types  of  income  sources  (which  is  not  the  purpose  here),  

it  is  also  highly  correlative  with  other  commonly  used  inequality  measures  like  the  

GINI  coefficient  and  the  top  1%  income  share.  A  state-­‐by-­‐state  breakdown  of  income  

inequality  is  presented  in  Figure  12.  The  value  of  each  state’s  inequality  is  derived  

from  its  average  percentage  from  the  years  2001-­‐2012.  Values  range  from  about  

                                                                                                               50  From  Campbell  and  Sumners,  “Presidential  Coattails  in  Senate  Elections”  (1990)  51  Abramowitz,  “Explaining  Senate  Election  Outcomes”  (1988)  52  Mark  W.  Frank,  “U.S.  State-­‐Level  Income  Inequality  Data,”  URL:  http://www.shsu.edu/eco_mwf/inequality.html,  accessed  on  10/20/14;  Thomas  Piketty  and  Emmanuel  Saez,  “The  Evolution  of  Top  Incomes:  A  Historical  and  International  Perspective,”  American  Economic  Association  Papers  and  Proceedings,  Vol.  96,  No.  2  (2006)  pp.  200-­‐205.  

  24  

50%  (New  York)  to  41%  (Utah  and  Alaska),  with  a  higher  percentage  representing  

greater  inequality.  

 

Control  Variables  

  A  number  of  control  variables  that  have  been  found  to  be  influential  in  

explaining  ticket  splitting  in  previous  scholarship  are  also  added  to  the  model.  In  

order  to  account  for  the  ideological  strength  within  each  state,  data  is  extracted  from  

a  pooled  CBS  News  and  New  York  Times  poll,  which  measures  the  percentage  of  

individuals  who  identify  as  liberals  and  conservatives  in  each  state  from  1993-­‐

1999.53  One  would  expect  states  with  a  higher  proportion  of  individuals  identifying  

as  either  liberals  or  conservative  to  be  less  likely  to  split  their  ticket.  Partisanship  is  

measured  with  Cook’s  PVI,  a  common  metric  that  attempts  to  capture  the  strength  

of  a  state’s  preference  for  either  the  Republican  or  Democratic  Party.54  Population  

density,  measured  by  a  state’s  population  per  square  mile,  is  also  added  to  the  model  

                                                                                                               53  Gerald  C.  Wright,  Robert  Erikson,  and  John  P.  McIver,  Statehouse  Democracy.  Cambridge  University  Press  (1993).    54  Cook’s  Political  Report  (2013)  

0.4  

0.42  

0.44  

0.46  

0.48  

0.5  

0.52  

NY   LA   TX   CA   GA   MA   NJ   AR   PA   RI   MO   OR   KS   MD  MT  MN   NE   HI   WI   AK  

Figure  12:  Inequality  in  the  States  (2001-­‐2012)  

  25  

to  account  for  variation  as  a  result  of  smaller  population  states  in  which  

‘incumbency  bumps’  may  be  stronger.55  The  logic  behind  this  assertion  is  that  

residents  of  rural  states  may  have  a  stronger  ‘personal  connection’  with  their  

Senators  and  may  be  more  inclined  to  cross  partisan  lines  to  support  an  incumbent  

they  are  personally  familiar  with.  Finally,  in  order  to  account  for  the  ‘Southern  

Effect’,  a  dummy  variable  is  created  to  ensure  test  whether  those  in  the  South  are  

more  or  less  likely  to  split  their  tickets,  as  was  the  case  in  previous  decades.    

OLS  Results  

  Table  1  summarizes  the  results  of  the  OLS  regression,  with  ticket  splitting  as  

the  dependent  variable.  The  entire  model  predicts  about  20%  of  the  variation  of  

ticket  splitting  in  the  states  in  years  2001-­‐2013  (R2  =  0.205),  although  it  is  not  

statistically  significant  as  a  whole  (F  =  1.417;  p-­‐value  =  0.238).  Interestingly,  the  

only  variable  that  is  statistically  significant  is  inequality  (90%  confidence).  As  

inequality  decreases  across  the  states,  the  probability  of  an  opposite  party  Senator  

occupying  one  or  both  of  the  states  increases,  controlling  for  other  sources  of  

variation.  In  other  words,  moving  from  Utah  or  Alaska  (the  lowest  inequality)  to  

New  York  (the  highest  inequality)  decreases  the  probability  of  a  state  being  

represented  by  an  opposite  party  Senator(s)  by  about  27.65%.    

                                                                                                               55  Population  density  data  obtained  from  2005  US  Census  Bureau;  Abramowitz,  “Explaining  Senate  Outcomes”  (1988)  pp.  387;  John  R.  Hibbing  and  Sara  L.  Brandes,  “State  Population  and  the  Electoral  Success  of  U.S.  Senators.  American  Journal  of  Political  Science,  Vol.  25  (1981)  pp.  808-­‐819.  

  26  

 

  Also  noteworthy,  none  of  the  other  variables  are  found  to  be  statistically  

significant,  although  the  standardized  coefficient  of  partisanship  nearly  matches  

inequality  (-­‐.28  and  -­‐.27  respectively).  Although  certain  states  may  have  a  higher  

proportion  of  individuals  who  identify  as  either  liberal  or  conservative,  this  

ideological  identity  does  not  seem  to  influence  a  state  electorate’s  propensity  to  split  

its  ticket.  Similarly,  population  density  (and  the  corresponding  ‘personal  connection’  

that  theoretically  comes  along  with  it)  does  not  influence  whether  a  state  splits  its  

ticket  between  Senate  and  presidential  voting.  Finally,  the  ‘Southern  Effect’  seems  to  

have  disappeared  over  the  past  few  decades,  as  southerners  are  not  more  or  less  

likely  to  vote  for  candidates  of  opposite  parties  for  Senate  and  presidential  elections.    

Limitations  and  Future  Research  

  Despite  the  intriguing  results,  one  must  proceed  with  caution  before  

declaring  inequality  as  the  primary  culprit  in  the  decline  of  ticket  splitting.  First,  the  

duration  of  the  data  examined  is  limited  to  elections  over  a  13-­‐year  period  of  which  

  27  

ticket  splitting  had  already  been  in  decline  for  about  10  years.  Measuring  the  

number  of  years  an  opposite  party  Senator  occupied  a  state’s  seat  tells  us  something  

about  that  specific  time  frame,  but  extending  the  data  beyond  the  current  era  of  

polarization  and  partisan  sorting  would  present  a  more  thorough  depiction  of  this  

phenomenon.  Senate  terms  are  six  years  long,  and  thus  one  split  ticket  outcome  may  

drastically  influence  the  results  over  such  short  time  duration.  Future  research  

should  examine  ticket  splitting  from  the  time  of  its  ascension  in  1972  (or  even  since  

the  inception  of  popular  voting  for  Senate  in  1912),  and  examine  it  through  the  

years  of  decline.  In  order  for  the  findings  of  this  analysis  to  maintain  their  validity,  

one  must  demonstrate  that  at  different  points  in  time,  states  with  lower  inequality  

more  frequently  split  their  ticket.    

It  is  likely,  that  the  control  variables  would  also  become  more  predictive  if  

the  duration  of  the  study  allowed  for  more  variation  of  the  dependent  variable.  

Ticket  splitting  had  already  started  its  decline  by  2001,  and  thus  the  few  states  left  

continuing  to  split  their  tickets  could  be  considered  holdovers  with  strong  

incumbents,  as  was  likely  the  case  in  North  Dakota’s  three  Democrat  congressional  

delegation  from  1992-­‐2008.  The  state  currently  boasts  two  Republicans  and  one  

Democrat  in  its  delegation  (one  of  each  in  the  Senate),  and  it  remains  unclear  

whether  the  cause  of  this  is  increased  inequality  (from  the  oil  boom),  or  simply  

strong  incumbents  deciding  to  retire  (only  one  of  the  Democrats  lost  a  reelection  

bid).  Expanding  the  data  set  would  prevent  a  single  strong  incumbent  from  skewing  

the  results  drastically,  as  may  have  been  the  case  in  a  number  of  states  in  this  

analysis.    

  28  

Finally,  a  number  of  limitations  with  regards  to  data  collection  are  present  as  

well.  Population  density  is  but  a  one-­‐year  measure  (2005),  and  ideology  is  an  average  

of  the  years  1993-­‐1999.  Although  it  is  likely  that  neither  has  fluctuated  greatly  from  

2001-­‐2013,  a  more  rigorous  approach  would  identically  match  the  time  frames  of  

the  data.  Time  constraints  and  data  access  limitations  prevent  this  analysis  from  

employing  the  amount  of  rigor  and  validity  required  for  this  type  of  undertaking.  

Future  efforts  at  explaining  ticket  splitting  should  take  these  limitations  into  

account  and  develop  more  sophisticated  methods  of  operationalizing  the  variables.      

Conclusion  

Despite  the  foregoing  limitations,  the  results  here  are  encouraging  and  do  

support  the  hypothesis.  Similar  to  what  is  theorized  by  McCarty,  Poole,  and  

Rosenthal,  economic  inequality  does  tend  to  ‘breed  polarizing  politics’,  or  more  

accurately  characterized  as  inducing  more  tribal  partisan  attachments.  In  states  in  

which  these  economic  disparities  are  more  pronounced,  voters  cling  more  strongly  

to  partisan  and  ideological  identities,  and  thus  are  less  willing  to  vote  across  party  

lines  for  different  offices.  As  a  higher  proportion  of  the  populace  can  be  

characterized  as  genuinely  ‘middle  class’,  the  electorate  generally  is  more  open  to  

the  idea  of  voting  for  different  parties  for  different  elective  offices.    

The  results  contribute  to  the  growing  body  of  literature  regarding  the  causes  

polarization,  partisan  sorting,  and  in  particular,  ticket  splitting.  However,  as  

mentioned  previously,  one  must  be  reticent  when  attributing  causal  processes  to  

such  a  complex  phenomenon.  Although  the  correlation  between  inequality  and  

partisanship  is  highly  suggestive,  it  is  highly  possible  that  the  partisanship  increase  

  29  

occurred  first,  only  to  be  followed  by  inequality.  Indeed,  the  contention  put  forward  

by  McCarty,  Poole,  and  Rosenthal  emphasizes  the  lack  of  responsiveness  on  the  part  

of  Congressional  leaders  to  address  inequality,  as  some  have  theorized:  as  more  

people  become  worse  off,  relatively  speaking,  they  would  tend  to  prefer  a  higher  

degree  of  redistribution  in  regards  to  economic  policies.  They  argue  that  this  has  not  

happened  because  those  who  are  worse  off  economically  are  less  likely  to  vote  or  

ineligible  (illegal  immigrants  and  felons),  and  thus  the  voting  public  is  skewed  

towards  those  who  oppose  redistributive  economic  policies.56  This  may  very  well  be  

the  case,  but  the  question  remains  as  to  whether  geographical  areas  with  lower  

degrees  of  inequality  have  residents  with  weaker  partisan  attachments,  and  are  thus  

more  likely  to  split  their  tickets.  This  analysis  provides  some  initial  insights  to  

clarifying  the  economic  inequality  effect  on  partisanship.    

Recent  scholarship  has  additionally  examined  the  effect  of  divided  

government  (which  may  or  may  not  be  the  result  of  ticket  splitting)  during  highly  

polarized  times.57  One  would  expect  to  see  less  divided  government  when  fewer  

voters  are  splitting  their  tickets;  however,  divided  government  has  been  the  norm  in  

recent  elections,  with  the  President  and  Congress  representing  opposite  parties  in  

12  of  the  last  22  years  (55%).  This  trend  is  likely  to  continue,  not  because  of  ticket  

splitting,  but  to  due  to  a  partisan  advantage  favoring  Republicans  in  House  races,  in  

addition  to  a  similar  Electoral  College  favoring  Democrats  for  the  presidency.58  It  is  

                                                                                                               56  McCarty,  Poole,  and  Rosenthal,  Polarized  America  (2006)  pp.  165-­‐190.  57  Binder,  Stalemate  (2003);  David  Mayhew,  Divided  We  Govern,  Party  Control,  Lawmaking,  and  Investigations,  1946-­‐1990.  New  Haven,  London:  Yale  University  Press  (1991).  58Jowei  Chen  and  Jonathan  Rodden,  “Unintentional  Gerrymandering:  Political  Geography  and  Electoral  Bias  in  Legislatures.”  Quarterly  Journal  of  Political  Science.  Vol.  8  (2013)  pp.  239–269;  Ben  Highton,  “A  big  Electoral  College  advantage  for  the  Democrats  is  looming,”  Washington  Post  Monkey  

  30  

one  thing  for  democracy  when  a  government  is  divided  because  voters  prefer  it  that  

way  in  order  to  moderate  policy;  it  is  quite  another  when  it  results  from  

institutional  vagaries  that  exaggerate  seat  allocation  in  Congress  or  Electoral  Vote  

support  for  the  White  House.59  We  are  experiencing  the  consequences  of  these  

trends  in  the  form  of  constant  threats  of  government  shutdowns  and  the  habitual  

use  of  continuing  resolutions  to  fund  the  government,  rather  than  more  

comprehensive  and  predictable  budgetary  practices.    

Additionally,  if  the  conclusions  presented  here  do  indeed  withstand  further  

scrutiny  and  testing,  it  indicates  yet  another  troubling  development  for  income  

inequality  in  a  society.  Aside  from  the  moral  implications,  many  claim  that  

exorbitant  inequality  may  slow  economic  growth,  decrease  social  mobility,  worsen  

social  relations,  and  perhaps  most  troubling,  facilitate  the  arrival  of  a  genuine  

‘plutocracy’  in  America  (these  implications  are  interrelated).60  In  recent  years,  social  

movements  on  the  left  (Occupy  Wall  Street)  and  the  right  (Tea  Party)  that  

emphasize  inequality  and  government  corruption  have  gained  momentum.  

However,  a  vicious  cycle  seems  to  have  developed  in  the  process:  as  the  electorate  

becomes  more  cynical  about  economic  inequality,  they  exacerbate  it  by  becoming  

more  strongly  attached  to  their  partisan  and  ideological  identities,  thus  

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                         Cage  Blog,  Apr.  28,  2014.  URL:  http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/monkey-­‐cage/wp/2014/04/28/a-­‐big-­‐electoral-­‐college-­‐advantage-­‐for-­‐the-­‐democrats-­‐is-­‐looming/,  accessed  on  11/25/14.  59  Jacobson,  The  Electoral  Origin  of  Divided  Government:  Competition  in  U.S.  House  Elections,  1946-­‐1988  (1990);  Alesina  and  Rosenthal,  Partisan  Politics,  Divided  Government,  and  the  Economy  (1995).  60  Eduardo  Porter,  “Income  Equality:  A  Search  for  Consequences,”  New  York  Times,  March  25,  2014,  URL:  http://www.nytimes.com/2014/03/26/business/economy/making-­‐sense-­‐of-­‐income-­‐inequality.html,  accessed  on:  11/25/14.  Martin  Gilens  and  Benjamin  I.  Page,  “Testing  Theories  of  American  Politics:  Elites,  Interest  Groups,  and  Average  Citizens,”  Perspectives  in  Politics,  Vol.  12,  No.  3  (2014).  

  31  

incentivizing  lawmakers  to  ignore  the  issue.  Short  of  restructuring  the  governing  or  

party  system,  it  is  not  entirely  clear  what  the  potential  remedies  are  to  improve  

these  troubling  trends.  The  findings  of  this  analysis  do  indicate,  however,  that  

extreme  economic  inequality  has  consequences  beyond  that  of  social  mobility  and  

economic  growth  –  it  impacts  how  people  think  about  partisan  attachments,  and  

thus  how  a  democracy  functions  as  well.      

     

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

  32  

References:    

Abramowitz,  Alan  I.  (1988)  “Explaining  Senate  Election  Outcomes,”  The  American  Political  Science  Review,  Vol.  82,  No.  2,  pp.  385-­‐403.  

 Abramowitz,  Alan  I.  Kile  L  and  Saunders  (2008)  “Is  Polarization  a  Myth?”  The  

Journal  of  Politics,  Vol.  70,  No.  2,  542–555.    Alesina,  Alberto  and  Howard  Rosenthal,  (1995)  Partisan  Politics,  Divided  

Government,  and  the  Economy,  Cambridge  University  Press.    Bawn,    Kathleen;  Cohen,  Martin;  Karol,  David;  Masket,  Seth;  Noel,  Hans;  and  John  

Zaller  (2012)  “A  Theory  of  Political  Parties:  Groups,  Policy  Demands  and  Nominations  in  American  Politics,  “  Perspectives  in  Politics,  Vol.  10,  pp  571-­‐597.  

 Binder,  Sarah  (2003)  Stalemate:  Causes  and  Consequences  of  Legislative  Gridlock,  

Washington,  DC:  Brookings  Institution.    Bishop,  Bill  (2009)  The  Big  Sort:  Why  the  Clustering  of  Like-­‐Minded  America  is  

Tearing  Us  Apart.  Mariner  Books.    Campbell,  James  E.  and  Joe  A.  Sumners,  (1990)  “Presidential  Coattails  in  Senate  

Elections,”  The  American  Political  Science  Review,  Vol.  84,  No.  2,  pp.  513-­‐524.    Chen,  Jowei  and  Jonathan  Rodden,  (2013)  “Unintentional  Gerrymandering:  Political  

Geography  and  Electoral  Bias  in  Legislatures.”  Quarterly  Journal  of  Political  Science.  Vol.  8,  pp.  239–269.  

 Converse,  Philip  E.  (1983)  “The  Concept  of  the  ‘Normal  Vote’”,  in  Elections  and  the  

Political  Order,  ed.  Angus  Campbell,  Philip  E.  Converse,  Warren  E.  Miller  and  Donald  E.  Stokes.  New  York:  Wiley  (1966);  Steven  J.  Rosenstone,  Forecasting  Presidential  Elections.  Yale  University  Press,  New  Haven.  

 Cook  Political  Report  (2014)  “Partisan  Voter  Index  by  State,  1994-­‐2014,”  The  Cook  

Political  Report.      Downs,  Anthony  (1957)  Economic  Theory  of  Democracy.  Harper  and  Row,  First  Ed.    Fiorina,  Morris  P.  and  Samuel  J.  Abrams  (2008)  “Political  Polarization  in  the  

American  Public,”  Annual  Review  of  Political  Science.  Vol.  11:563–588.    Fiorina,  Abrams  and  Pope  (2008)  “Polarization  in  the  American  Public:  

Misconceptions  and  Misreadings,”  The  Journal  of  Politics,  Vol.  70,  No.  2,  556–560.  

 

  33  

Frank,  Mark  W.  (2014)  “U.S.  State-­‐Level  Income  Inequality  Data,”  URL:  http://www.shsu.edu/eco_mwf/inequality.html,  accessed  on  10/20/14.  

 Gerber,  Elizabeth  and  Adam  Many,  (1996)  “Incumbency-­‐Led  Ideological  Balancing:  

A  Hybrid  Model  of  Split-­‐Ticket  Voting,”  Presented  at  the  annual  meeting  of  Midwest  Political  Science  Association,  Chicago.  

 Gerber,  Elisabeth  R;  and  Rebecca  B.  Morton  (1998).  “Primary  Election  Systems  and  

Representation.”  Oxford  University  Press.        Gilens,  Martin  and  Benjamin  I.  Page  (2014)“Testing  Theories  of  American  Politics:  

Elites,  Interest  Groups,  and  Average  Citizens,”  Perspectives  in  Politics,  Vol.  12,  No.  3.  

 Green,  John  C.;  Coffey,  Daniel  J.;  and  David  B.  Cohen,  (2014)  The  State  of  the  Parties:  

The  Changing  Role  of  Contemporary  American  Parties,  Rowman  &  Littlefield  Publishers;  7th  Edition.  

 Hassell,  Hans  (2013).  “The  Non-­‐existent  Primary-­‐Ideology  Link,  or  Do  Open  

Primaries  Actually  Limit  Party  Influence  in  Primary  Elections?”  Presentation  at  the  2013  State  Politics  and  Policy  Conference,  University  of  Iowa,  Iowa  City,  Iowa.  

 Hibbing,  John  R.  and  Sara  L.  Brandes  (1981)  “State  Population  and  the  Electoral  

Success  of  U.S.  Senators.  American  Journal  of  Political  Science,  Vol.  25,  pp.  808-­‐819.  

 Highton,  Ben  (2014)  “A  big  Electoral  College  advantage  for  the  Democrats  is  

looming,”  Washington  Post  Monkey  Cage  Blog,  Apr.  28,  2014.  URL:  http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/monkey-­‐cage/wp/2014/04/28/a-­‐big-­‐electoral-­‐college-­‐advantage-­‐for-­‐the-­‐democrats-­‐is-­‐looming/,  accessed  on  11/25/14.  

 Ingraham,  Christopher  (2014)  “Inequality  and  political  polarization  have  been  rising  

in  tandem  for  three  decades,”  Washington  Post  Wong  Blog,  May,  27,  2014.  URL:  http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/wonkblog/wp/2014/05/27/inequality-­‐and-­‐political-­‐polarization-­‐have-­‐been-­‐rising-­‐in-­‐tandem-­‐for-­‐three-­‐decades/,  accessed  on:  11/25/14.  

 Jacobson,  Gary  (1990)  The  Electoral  Origin  of  Divided  Government:  Competition  in  

U.S.  House  Elections,  1946-­‐1988.  Westview  Press.    Jacobson,  Gary  C.  (2013)  “Partisan  Polarization  in  American  Politics:  A  Background  

Paper,”  Presidential  Studies  Quarterly,  Vol.  43.  No.  4,  pp.  688-­‐708.    

  34  

Katz,  Elihu  and  Paul  Lazarsfeld  (2005)  Personal  Influence:  The  Part  Played  by  People  in  the  Flow  of  Mass  Communications.  Transaction  Publishers,  2nd  Ed.  

 Key,  V.O.  (1949).  Southern  Politics  in  State  and  Nation.  New  York:  A.  A.  Knopf.    Levendusky,  Matthew  (2009)  The  Partisan  Sorty:  How  Liberals  Became  Democrats  

and  Conservatives  Became  Republicans.  University  of  Chicago  Press.    Lewis-­‐Beck,  Michael  S.  and  Tom  W.  Rice,  (1985)"Are  Senate  Election  Outcomes  

Predictable?"  PS:  Political  Science  &  Politics,  Vol.  18.,  No.  4,  pp.  745-­‐754.    Mann,  Thomas  E.;  and  Norman  J.  Ornstein  (2012)    It’s  Even  Worse  Than  It  Looks:  

Howl  the  American  Constitutional  System  Collided  with  the  New  Politics  of  Extremism.  Basic  Books.    

 Mayhew,  David  (1991)  Divided  We  Govern,  Party  Control,  Lawmaking,  and  

Investigations,  1946-­‐1990.  New  Haven,  London:  Yale  University  Press.    McCarty,  Poole,  Rosenthal  (2006)  Polarized  America:  The  Dance  of  Ideology  and  

Unequal  Riches.  MIT  Press.      Ostermeier,  Eric  (2011)  “Which  States  Have  the  Most  Split-­‐Ticket  Voting  in  

Presidential-­‐U.S.  Senate  Election  Cycles?”  University  of  Minnesota  Humphrey  School  of  Public  Policy,  Oct.  5,  2011,  URL:  http://blog.lib.umn.edu/cspg/smartpolitics/2011/04/which_states_have_the_most_spl.php,  accessed  on:  11/02/14.  

 Pew  Research  Center  (2014)  “Political  Polarization  in  the  American  Public,”  Pew  

Research  Center.    Piketty,  Thomas  and  Emmanuel  Saez,  (2006)  “The  Evolution  of  Top  Incomes:  A  

Historical  and  International  Perspective,”  American  Economic  Association  Papers  and  Proceedings,  Vol.  96,  No.  2,  pp.  200-­‐205.  

 Pildes,  Richard  H.    (2011)  “Why  the  Center  Does  Not  Hold:  The  Causes  of  

Hyperpolarized  Democracy  in  America,”  California  Law  Review,  Vol.  99  273,  288.  

 Polsby,  Nelson  W.  (2004)  How  Congress  Evolves:  Social  Bases  of  Institutional  Change.  

Oxford  University  Press.    Poole,  Keith  (2014)  Voteview,  URL:  www.voteview.com.  Accessed  on  11/10/14.    Poole,  Keith  (2014)  “An  Update  on  Political  Polarization  through  the  112th  Congress”,  

URL:  http://voteview.com/blog/?p=726,    accessed  on  11/10/14.    

  35  

Porter,  Eduardo  (2014)  “Income  Equality:  A  Search  for  Consequences,”  New  York  Times,  March  25,  2014,  URL:  http://www.nytimes.com/2014/03/26/business/economy/making-­‐sense-­‐of-­‐income-­‐inequality.html,  accessed  on:  11/25/14  

 Prior,  Markus  (2007)  Post-­‐Broadcast  Democracy:  How  Media  Choice  Increases  

Inequality  in  Political  Involvement  and  Polarizes  Elections.  Cambridge  Studies  in  Public  Opinion  and  Political  Psychology.  

 Silver,  Nate  (2012).  “As  Swing  Districts  Dwindle,  Can  a  Divided  House  Stand?”  The  

New  York  Times.  27  Dec.  2012.  Nov.  15,  2013.    Silver,  Nate  (2014)  “Party-­‐Line  Voting  Makes  Scott  Brown  Part  of  a  Dying  Breed  in  

the  Senate,”  538  Politics,  Feb.  4,  2013,  URL:  http://fivethirtyeight.com/features/party-­‐line-­‐voting-­‐makes-­‐scott-­‐brown-­‐part-­‐of-­‐a-­‐dying-­‐breed-­‐in-­‐the-­‐senate/,  accessed  on:  10/05/14.  

 Southwell,  Priscilla  (1986)  “The  Politics  of  Disgruntlement:  Nonvoting  and  Defection  

among  Supporters  of  Nomination  Losers,  1968-­‐1984,”  Political  Behavior,  Vol.  8,  pp.  81-­‐95.  

 Sunquist,  James  L.  (1983)  Dynamics  of  the  Party  System:  Alignment  and  Realignment  

of  Political  Parties  in  the  United  States,  The  Brookings  Institution,  Washington,  D.C..  

 Theriault,  Sean  M.  and  David  W.  Rohde  (2011)  “The  Gingrich  Senators  and  Party  

Polarization  in  the  U.S.  Senate,”  The  Journal  of  Politics,  Vol.  73,  No.  4,  Pp.  1011–1024.  

 US  Census  Bureau  (2005),  “U.S.  Census  Bureau,  Statistical  Abstract  of  the  United  

States:  2004-­‐2005,”  US  Census  Bureau.    Walsh,  Deirdre  (2014)  “Last  white  Democrat  from  Deep  South  loses  Congressional  

seat,”  Nov.  5,  2014.  URL:  http://www.cnn.com/2014/11/05/politics/last-­‐southern-­‐white-­‐democrat-­‐in-­‐congress/;  accessed  on  11/20/14.  

 Wattenberg,  Martin  P.  (1991)  The  Rise  of  Candidate-­‐Centerted  Politics:  Presidential  

Elections  of  the  1980s.  Harvard  University  Press,  Cambridge,  MA.    Wright,  Gerald  C.;  Erikson,  Robert;  and  John  P.  McIver  (1993)  Statehouse  Democracy.  

Cambridge  University  Press.