Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm...

39
Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? Carmona, Kahlil Marion H. De La Salle University, 2401 Taft Avenue, Manila, Philippines, E-mail: [email protected] Shi, Ailyn A. De La Salle University, 2401 Taft Avenue, Manila, Philippines, E-mail: [email protected] Tan, Alexis Georgette L. De La Salle University, 2401 Taft Avenue, Manila, Philippines, E-mail: [email protected] A common feature of the corporate sector of emerging markets like the Philippines is the prevalence of family-controlled conglomerates. This paper explores the effects of corporate diversification on firm value, particularly among family-controlled firms. Using firm-level data on 113 corporations that are listed in the Philippine Stock Exchange, we employ a generalized least squares random effects model to determine the effects of diversification behavior on firm value. We find that family owners play a significant role in moderating total diversification performance – said diversification tends to go beyond the optimal level, which reduces firm value. By further decomposing total diversification into its unrelated and related forms, we also find that most conglomerates are inclined to diversify to unrelated industries. With such findings, we assert that significant caution must be placed upon the use of unrelated corporate diversification among family firms due to the negative effects brought about by family entrenchment upon firm value. JEL Classification: G34, M14, G30 Keywords: Corporate Governance; Family Altruism; Diversification; Firm Value I. INTRODUCTION Family-controlled conglomerates are rapidly becoming the norm within the corporate sector, as can be gleaned from the literature. For instance, Shleifer and Vishny (1997) note that a lot of corporations around the world, including parts of Europe and East Asia, have controlling owners who may be the founders, themselves, or their offspring. In the Philippines, alone, Aquino (2003) asserts that influential families, such as the Aboitizes and Gokongweis, are the brains behind corporations that dominate the modern- day Philippine industry. Consistent with this is the finding of Claessens et al. (2000) that more than half of the local economy’s corporate assets are controlled by the country’s ten richest families. 1 In the case of the Philippine corporate sector, Figure 1.1 highlights the percentage of family ownership for Philippine Stock Exchange (PSE) firms from years 2008 to 2012, where controlling family ownership is seen to increase, albeit at a decreasing rate, throughout the five-year period. 1 Claessens and Fan (2003) have extensively delineated the unique ownership structure inherent in most Asian firms. A typical Asian corporation serves as the nexus for several more business groups, either public or private or both – all affiliated with a single family who holds most of the shares. This case is very much unlike companies in the Western region where shares are diffusely held. For a more substantial view on the case concerning firm ownership structures in several Asian countries, see Claessens et al. (2000). Figure 1.1. Family Ownership Families are theorized by the literature to be inclined towards entrenching themselves within the firm’s hierarchical structure due to psychological, rather than logical, reasons. The pressing need to maintain good family ties induces family owners to bequeath firm executive positions to kin (Karra et al., 2006). Furthermore, the welfare of the succeeding generations is accounted for through the creation of a succession plan involving the firm (Lien and Li, 2013). Thus, the nuances of diversification as a means of furthering family altruism and entrenchment have been widely explored. Aside from benefits pertaining to prolonged firm life and higher profits, it has been posited that the family legacy that is tied to the firm motivates such companies to diversify and, thus, attain improved firm value. However, it has also been 41.7205 41.721 41.7215 41.722 41.7225 41.723 41.7235 41.724 41.7245 41.725 41.7255 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Percentage of Family Ownership Year

Transcript of Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm...

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value?

Carmona, Kahlil Marion H. De La Salle University,

2401 Taft Avenue, Manila, Philippines, E-mail: [email protected]

Shi, Ailyn A. De La Salle University,

2401 Taft Avenue, Manila, Philippines, E-mail: [email protected]

Tan, Alexis Georgette L. De La Salle University,

2401 Taft Avenue, Manila, Philippines, E-mail: [email protected]

A common feature of the corporate sector of emerging markets like the Philippines is the prevalence of family-controlled conglomerates. This paper explores the effects of corporate diversification on firm value, particularly among family-controlled firms. Using firm-level data on 113 corporations that are listed in the Philippine Stock Exchange, we employ a generalized least squares random effects model to determine the effects of diversification behavior on firm value. We find that family owners play a significant role in moderating total diversification performance – said diversification tends to go beyond the optimal level, which reduces firm value. By further decomposing total diversification into its unrelated and related forms, we also find that most conglomerates are inclined to diversify to unrelated industries. With such findings, we assert that significant caution must be placed upon the use of unrelated corporate diversification among family firms due to the negative effects brought about by family entrenchment upon firm value. JEL Classification: G34, M14, G30 Keywords: Corporate Governance; Family Altruism; Diversification; Firm Value I. INTRODUCTION

Family-controlled conglomerates are rapidly becoming the norm within the corporate sector, as can be gleaned from the literature. For instance, Shleifer and Vishny (1997) note that a lot of corporations around the world, including parts of Europe and East Asia, have controlling owners who may be the founders, themselves, or their offspring. In the Philippines, alone, Aquino (2003) asserts that influential families, such as the Aboitizes and Gokongweis, are the brains behind corporations that dominate the modern-day Philippine industry. Consistent with this is the finding of Claessens et al. (2000) that more than half of the local economy’s corporate assets are controlled by the country’s ten richest families.1 In the case of the Philippine corporate sector, Figure 1.1 highlights the percentage of family ownership for Philippine Stock Exchange (PSE) firms from years 2008 to 2012, where controlling family ownership is seen to increase, albeit at a decreasing rate, throughout the five-year period.

                                                                                                               1   Claessens   and   Fan   (2003)   have   extensively   delineated   the  unique   ownership   structure   inherent   in   most   Asian   firms.   A  typical   Asian   corporation   serves   as   the   nexus   for   several   more  business   groups,   either   public   or   private   or   both   –   all   affiliated  with   a   single   family  who   holds  most   of   the   shares.   This   case   is  very  much  unlike  companies  in  the  Western  region  where  shares  are   diffusely   held.     For   a   more   substantial   view   on   the   case  concerning  firm  ownership  structures  in  several  Asian  countries,  see  Claessens  et  al.  (2000).    

Figure 1.1. Family Ownership

Families are theorized by the literature to be inclined

towards entrenching themselves within the firm’s hierarchical structure due to psychological, rather than logical, reasons. The pressing need to maintain good family ties induces family owners to bequeath firm executive positions to kin (Karra et al., 2006). Furthermore, the welfare of the succeeding generations is accounted for through the creation of a succession plan involving the firm (Lien and Li, 2013). Thus, the nuances of diversification as a means of furthering family altruism and entrenchment have been widely explored. Aside from benefits pertaining to prolonged firm life and higher profits, it has been posited that the family legacy that is tied to the firm motivates such companies to diversify and, thus, attain improved firm value. However, it has also been

41.7205 41.721

41.7215 41.722

41.7225 41.723

41.7235 41.724

41.7245 41.725

41.7255

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

Perc

enta

ge o

f Fam

ily O

wner

ship

Year

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 2 suggested that over-diversification may generate counter-effects.

In developing economies, firm diversification tends to include a wide range of activities; i.e., firms extend their businesses to industries, which are not technologically related to their original core activities (Ungson, Steers, and Park, 1997). Scholars have tried to determine the optimal level of firm diversification where marginal cost is equal to marginal benefit. Despite the threats presented by over-diversification, many companies simply diversify beyond the optimal level; thus, destroying shareholders’ wealth (Martin and Sayrak, 2003).

In the Philippine context, where diversified family-based conglomerates dominate the corporate sector (Aquino, 2003), it has been noted that most of these firms started out in a particular core activity. For instance, the Ayala Corporation’s initial business revolves around land development. The Aboitiz Group started out as a shipping company, which used to transfer goods within the Visayas region. Henry Sy’s famous success story commenced from a small shoe store in Quiapo, Manila; said business prospered and soon became SM Investments Corporation. Other examples include San Miguel Corporation’s brewery and JG Summit Holdings’ cornstarch production.

Such firms have diversified into various activities – only some of which are related to the original core business. From their initial land business, the Ayala Corporation has since delved into financial (e.g. Bank of the Philippine Islands) and telecommunications services (i.e. Globe Telecoms). Nowadays, Aboitiz Group has power generation (e.g. Visayas Electric Company) and food production (i.e. Pilmico Foods Inc.). Even SM Prime Holdings has diversified into real estate development (i.e. SM Development Corporation) and financial services (e.g. Banco de Oro Unibank).

Accounts of further diversification pursuits in the local setting abound. Dumlao (2012) writes about JG Summit’s sale of P3.2 billion worth of shares. The company, thriving under the lead of the Gokongweis, has found the need to sell its company’s shares in order to diversify their investor base and, thus, be better suited to handle the increasing market demand. Aside from its engagement with the food, airline, property, banking, and petrochemical industries, the conglomerate is once again the focus of attention, as it also takes part in the gaming and tourism sectors.

Moreover, Aboitiz Equity Ventures, Inc. has been reported to venture into water distribution. Its other joint ventures will consist of the Mactan International Airport construction and the production of bio-methane fuel. It was reported that the company’s net income reached P6.8 billion in the first quarter of 2013 wherein the largest contribution can be traced back to the firm’s power sector (Austria, 2013).

Like other diversified conglomerates, San Miguel Corporation awaits the outcome of its diversification activities, such as the construction of the Tarlac-Pangasinan-La Union Expressway and the expansion of the Boracay Airport. Montealegre (2013) discloses that said conglomerate’s new businesses already account for 70% of the corporation’s P699 billion worth of revenues for 2013. Other business groups have also followed suit.

There are only a few studies on how the diversification phenomenon affects firm variables in the Philippines. Gutierrez and Rodriguez (2013) find evidence on the inclination of the largest locally-based conglomerates – most of which are family-controlled firms – to diversify to unrelated, as opposed to related, industries. However, the impact of unrelated or related diversification on firm value has not been accounted for in their study. Aquino (2003) investigates diversification effects on the value of Philippine firms and reports mixed results; however, his study did not account for family altruism effects on firm value. Thus, there is also a need to empirically substantiate the tenuous connection between firm value and family altruism, as characterized by higher controlling family ownership for firms.

The main theories of this study revolve around two equally corroborative presumptions. The first strand revolves around the agency theory as the foundation behind the firm agent’s motive to maximize his own preferences (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). Consequently, conflicting interests between the principal and the agent generate information asymmetry costs, which inhibit the growth of firm value. Family-dominated firms, on the other hand, are presumed to be free from agency problems – firm principals and agents, both of whom are posited to come from the same bloodline, are likely to exhibit converging interests towards the successful perpetuation of the family business (Amit and Villalonga, 2006). Such aligned motives indicate positive firm performance and firm value consequences. Conversely, increased family presence within the company signifies a higher incentive for the controlling family to expropriate and take advantage of minority shareholders, which, in turn, inhibits improvement of firm value (Amit and Villalonga, 2006; Morck and Yeung, 2003a). Extant empirical literature supports the effects of both sides of agency theory on firm performance and value in family-controlled firms.

The second strand posits the significance of family altruism on diversification motives of family-controlled firms. Because man is assumed to pursue goals that would maximize his own utility [agency theory], Lien and Li (2013) hypothesize that family firm owners find satisfaction in pursuing the welfare of their own kin. Hence, such firms tend to diversify, in order to strengthen the firm as the family legacy and to prevent feuds among successors through the

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 3 allocation of subsidiaries to each one of them. However, over-entrenchment through diversification tends to destroy firm value for these corporations. Nevertheless, Kachaner et al. (2012) note that family wealth is protected by diversification through the dilution of concentrated risk to a number of firm segments.

Empirical studies concerning family altruism, diversification, and firm value have been widely conducted for Western and East Asian countries. However, only a few have deigned to study the subject using Philippine-based conglomerates as basis.2 Karra et al. (2006) examine a Turkish firm and reports an initial positive relationship between family altruism and firm value; however, further family entrenchment causes firm value reductions. On the other hand, Saldaña (2001) and De Dios and Hutchcroft (2003) observe that business groups diversify to protect themselves against changing political and economic conditions. This spreads non-systematic risk for the firms because of capital diversification to non-related businesses. Anderson and Reeb (2003) also find better firm performance in family firms in the U.S., as opposed to non-family ones. Conversely, Lang and Stulz (1994) and Berger and Ofek (1995) find evidence that the market lowers the value of publicly traded diversified U.S. firms.

For East Asian firms, Chakrabarti et al. (2007) find that economies with developed institutional regulatory frameworks incur firm performance losses due to diversification, whereas those with underdeveloped regulatory frameworks benefit from diversification. Moreover, Aquino (2003) finds that diversification effects for Philippine firms behave in an inverted-U manner; that is, diversifying via subsidiaries or internal divisions appear to add firm value but any further diversification only reduces value.

In this study, empirical analysis is used to investigate the underlying effect of diversification, particularly that which is characterized by family control, on the overall firm value of Philippine publicly traded firms. Furthermore, total corporate diversification is decomposed into its unrelated and related forms, in order to determine which form better accounts for diversification performance in family-controlled firms. Although separation of ownership and control is a rarity in East Asian conglomerates (Claessens et al., 2000), we create a distinction between the two and refer to family firms as family-controlled. Control is distinguished from ownership by at least a 20% threshold of direct or indirect voting rights in the firm, as (i) said cutoff is sufficient to provide effective control in a firm (La Porta et al., 1999); (ii) most countries usually mandate a disclosure of ownership stakes from 10% to 20% (La Porta et al., 1999); and (iii) the International Accounting Standards Committee (IASC) labels a control                                                                                                                2   See   Gutierrez   and   Rodriguez   (2013),   Aquino   (2003),   and   Del  Mundo  et  al.  (2007).  

minimum of 20% as ‘significant influence’ (Del Mundo et al., 2007). Therefore, we consider a conglomerate as family-controlled when members from a single family control for at least 20% of voting rights. Furthermore, by adopting the one-share-one-vote rule, which is common in East Asian countries (Claessens et al., 2000), we redefine a family-controlled firm as one wherein a single family owns at least 20% of the firm’s outstanding shares. On the other hand, we hesitate on making use of ‘ownership’ in this particular study since said terminology may imply full ownership of shares by a single family which, in this case, is impossible because the firms we deal with are publicly traded in the Philippine Stock Exchange (PSE).

To our knowledge, this is the first attempt on implementing a systematic study of the interaction between family altruism, diversification decisions, and firm value in the Philippine setting. Moreover, we further explore corporate diversification by decomposing it and analyzing the effects of its two forms upon firm value. We use annual firm-level data on 113 corporations that are listed in the Philippine Stock Exchange during the period 2008 to 2012. Through the necessary data obtained from annual reports filed with the PSE and SEC, we seek to investigate how corporate diversification, most particularly in family conglomerates, impacts firm value. Furthermore, we seek to uncover which type of diversification (unrelated or related) mostly accounts for total corporate diversification performance within the local setting. Also, we aim to identify principal-principal agency problems that may arise from differing motives between the controlling family and other block shareholders, such as banking institutions. Said principal-principal agency problems may arise depending on the depth of family entrenchment; as a shareholder, banks may support or refuse the diversification decisions of family-controlled firms in order to protect their investments in these corporations.

We believe that implications and recommendations arising from the results of this study can help improve corporate governance and aid investors in determining firm value based on the extent of diversification. Furthermore, for firms opting to diversify, this study will provide helpful information that enables them to zero-in on the trade-offs involved in diversification -- distributing diversified business interests among family members as a means of succession, in the face of potential loss of firm value. In the case of outsider block shareholders, the results of this study will help them assess whether or not it is wealth-maximizing to invest in a family-controlled corporation; thus, enabling them to pursue necessary and corrective measures to protect their shareholder value. Moreover, generalizations created in this study may contribute to current corporate literature and provide information as to how firms, which exhibit similar attributes to

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 4 that of Philippine companies, can further enhance their performance.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows: The next section describes the variables and related hypotheses in the framework of Philippine firm-level data, as well as the theory and relevant empirical studies supporting these. Section III discusses the data sample, proxy variables, the econometric models, and the estimation procedure used. Empirical results including summary statistics of variables are developed in Section IV. Lastly, significant findings, conclusions, and relevant recommendations are highlighted in Sections V, VI, and VII, respectively.

II. THEORIES, VARIABLES, AND HYPOTHESES DEVELOPMENT “The parent who leaves his son enormous wealth generally deadens the talents and synergies of the son.”

–Andrew Carnegie (1891)

Figure 2.1 provides a summary of the theoretical framework used in this study, which will be discussed in the succeeding paragraphs. Empirical findings from the literature will be used to substantiate this framework. Figure 2.1. Theoretical Framework

Dependent Variable Firm Value

The total economic value of the company, which is to be allocated to the firm’s shareholders, typically reflects firm value. Measures of firm value often revolve around market and book value pricings. While firm value may be captured

via mere equity or asset values, proxy measures are more commonly used in the literature. Zhan (2007) makes use of accounting measures, such as Return on Assets (ROA), as a proxy for firm value, whereas Berger and Ofek (1995) use Excess Value Added (EVA); however, the latter measure is a noisy proxy for firm value due to unreliability in computing for the weighted cost of capital. In this study, we use Tobin’s Q as a robust measure of firm value. Independent Variables Models A, B, and C: (Dependent Variable: Firm Value) Family Ownership and Control (Family Altruism) on Firm Value

The distinction between family ownership, control and management in family firms is murky, to say the least. This issue arose from the classic study of Berle and Means (1932) which finds that although ownership is widespread among minority shareholders in most U.S. firms, unwavering control still lies in the hands of managers. La Porta et al. (1999) deem this form of “managerialist” culture to be only applicable to large firms in rich countries. Their study contests this view by finding that there, indeed, exists separation of ownership and control in large firms, but the control lies instead in the hands of the shareholders. On the other hand, Claessens et al. (2000) find that ownership is rarely separable from control in East Asian firms. In particular, 60% of these firms are controlled by managers, which come from a single family owner.

Separation of ownership and control may not always be a result of the firm owner’s decision to pursue efficient capital formation3 or to extend firm or share rights to people outside his kinship group. For example, Padilla and Kreptul (2004) find that government interference may also cause such separation in power, in order to protect minority shareholders from the opportunistic behavior possibly exhibited by those in executive positions. Such regulations include taxation and/or rent controls – both of which reduce the incentive of owners to hold on to their rights (Padilla and Kreptul, 2004).

Furthermore, Westhead and Cowling (1996) emphasize the advantages of control and ownership separation by positing that giving control to an outsider CEO, who is not drawn from the kinship group owner of the firm, may bring about fresh ideas and technological advances and use resource networks to help the firm adapt to changes in external stimuli, which will improve firm performance and value. Hillier and

                                                                                                               3   Owners   may   give   control   to   managers   outside   his/her   own  family  group,   in  order  to  allow  for   increased  technical  efficiency  and   skill,   which   only   outsiders   may   possess   (Westhead   and  Cowling,  1996).  

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 5 McColgan (2005) further assert that such separation of power will limit the owner from practicing nepotism and appointing an inexperienced or unskilled kin to the position; thus, preventing the loss of value.

On the other hand, Westhead and Cowling (1996) argue that an outsider CEO may aim to maximize his utility function, instead of pursuing profit-maximization and value-enhancement strategies for the benefit of the firm. Furthermore, Zhu et al. (2010) find a decrease in firm performance in Chinese family-listed firms due to separation of ownership and cash flow rights. Agency costs caused by asymmetric information are also deemed to be negative consequences of such separation in power.

Using a sample of 634 family firms in seven Asian countries, Peng and Jiang (2010) find that the effect of family control on firm value significantly depends upon domestic legal and institutional regulations. In East Asia, particularly in Indonesia and Thailand, Claessens et al. (2000) find evidence of significant family control in more than half of the 2,980 sample firms. For the Philippines, they find that control is significant, with the 10 largest families controlling more than half of the country’s corporate assets. Specifically, by using a 10% control threshold, they report that 42% of Philippine firms are family-controlled. Moreover, they find separation of ownership and control to be low in the sample of Philippine firms, in large companies that are mostly dominated by families. Family Altruism

Consistent with agency theory, owners are assumed to be rational and profit-maximizing individuals who attempt to gain maximum economic benefits from their firms. However, another key assumption in the corporate literature is that, other than economic objectives, owners may also pursue non-economic motives that tend to benefit their family welfare (Karra et al., 2006). Consequently, owners may tend to pursue decisions that might not be optimal for the firm, yet consistent with their goal of maximizing their family’s well-being (Chrisman et al., 2004). As such, agency theory is deemed to be confining since it does not account for non-economic objectives, such as building family cohesion and giving employment to kin (Karra et al., 2006).

From an economic perspective, altruism is represented by a utility function that links the welfare of individuals (Schulze et al., 2003). Lubatkin et al. (2007) define altruism as a “self-other relationship”, which incorporates the interests of others into decision processes. Noe (2012) describes altruism as being “symmetric, limited and harsh” because its effects are too narrow and inclusive, and the consequences cannot be fully internalized by the recipient of such munificent behavior.

Schulze et al. (2003) emphasize the advantages of family altruism – owners extend benevolent behavior to their families, particularly to children, in such a way that families benefit from the munificent act. Moreover, altruism fosters commitment and consideration between parents and their offspring in such a way that the bond between them is sustained (Eshel et al., 1998; Schulze et al., 2003); through this, loyalty towards the family and firm is also established (Ward, 1997). As such, interests of both the parent and the child are aligned in matters concerning the firm – this limits information asymmetry (Karra et al., 2006), reduces agency costs and generates a family-oriented organizational culture that encourages risk-taking behavior, such as delving into international growth opportunities (Schulze et al., 2003). This allows for higher firm returns and increased firm production.

However, altruistic behavior existent within firms gives off a sense of collective ownership among family members which, in turn, creates a ‘self-reinforcing system of incentives’ that encourages members to be “selfless” to one another (Karra et al., 2006). Thus, families tend to appoint kin to firm positions; due to adverse selection or nepotistic behavior, disruptive ripples are generated by hiring inexperienced, unsatisfied or inefficient kin (Dyer, Jr., 2006; Karra et al., 2006; Astrachan et al., 2007). Moreover, this selfless act towards offspring incurs moral hazard losses through incentivizing the latter to manipulate the transfers of the parent in such a way that their own self-serving wants are catered (Lubatkin et al., 2007). This encourages the offspring to freeload (through the consumption of perks) or to shirk from their duties – both of which engender inefficiencies in firm governance and harm firm performance and value (Schulze et al., 2003; Lubatkin et al., 2007; Karra et al., 2006).

On the other hand, Stafford et al. (1999) theorize that families opt to bestow firm employment only upon relatives who are in good terms with the founding family, in order to promote business harmony and positive firm outcomes. Meanwhile, the exchange theory of Ingoldsby et al. (2004) is grounded upon self-interest. It asserts that participation in the family business lasts only for so long as the hired relative can provide economic and social benefits beyond the costs he or she incurs.

In a study concerning a renowned Turkish firm, Karra et al. (2006) find that reciprocated altruism has aligned the goals of the family and has reduced agency and monitoring costs towards heightened firm performance and value. However, as the business continued to expand, agency costs were aggravated due to the tendency of appointed family members to shirk. The effects of such free-riding behavior were magnified when the family-owner refused to sanction his kin. Moreover, the authors find that family altruism extends not only to immediate family members and distant kin, but

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 6 also to unrelated individuals who share the same ethnic culture as the owner. Thus, it can be posited that the effects of altruistic behavior made manifest by owners of family-controlled firms are even more extensive than initially supposed.

On the other hand, the family altruism and succession theory posits that family firm owners are highly incentivized to make prudent decisions that will enhance firm value. This is consistent with their objective of preserving the firm for the sake of succeeding generations. Consistent with this theory, Lien and Li (2013) find a positive relationship between family control and firm value prior to diversification.

However, Schulze et al. (2003) find evidence of an increase in agency costs due to negative altruism effects and a subsequent decline in firm performance using U.S. data. Using data on shipping firms in Norway and Sweden, Randoy and Jenssen (2003) find that the takeover of a CEO descendant causes a negative effect on firm performance, whereas descendant influence of the founder-Chairman contributes an improvement in firm value.4 Economic Entrenchment

Excessive family altruism and control imply

entrenchment of the family within the firm hierarchy. Morck et al. (2005) dub economic entrenchment as a phenomenon where controlling owners appear to possess political and institutional influence relative to their actual wealth. Shleifer and Vishny (1989), on the other hand, model entrenchment in terms of managerial investment – a phenomenon which occurs when the manager excessively invests in assets which are complementary to his personal skill. As such, the manager is made valuable to stockholders because of his unique skill contribution and, thus, entrenches himself within the firm in the process. Furthermore, Morck et al. (1998) define and measure family entrenchment in terms of family board ownership, whereas Tan (2009) links the concept to the reluctance of the incumbent CEO to vacate his position in favor of the heir apparent. Regardless, entrenchment stems from control manifested through a variety of mechanisms.

This firm-level entrenchment phenomenon inherent in family firms involves expanding existing lines of control. For instance, cross-shareholding, as defined by Ogishima and Kobayashi (2002), may take the form of unilateral or mutual shareholdings – the former implies a one-sided form of control

                                                                                                               4   Randoy   and   Jenssen   (2003)   argue   that   descendant   CEOs   limit  the   firm   from   taking   advantage   of   a   competitive   managerial  labour  market;   thus,   the   firm   fails   to  benefit   from   the   skills   and  experience   that   can   be   offered   by   an   outsider   CEO   in   terms   of  strategy   and   decision-­‐making.   On   the   other   hand,   descendant  Chairmen   signify   firm   continuity   and   add   firm   value   due   to  exhibited   aligned   interests   with   the   objectives   of   the  organization.  

extension of Firm A over Firm B via ownership of shares, whereas the latter involves Firm A and Firm B strategically owning each other’s shares. Such a structure allows firms to extend control over another firm (Morck et al., 2005).

On the other hand, superior voting rights involve classes of stock which possess more votes per share than an ordinary common stock; thus, granting the holders superior voting rights, even if they own minimal equity in the firm (Morck et al., 2005). These allow the holder to command a majority of votes in a shareholders’ meeting and, thus, extend his control rights, even while accounting for only minimal ownership.

Moreover, control pyramids depict how magnification of control and wealth by firm owners intensifies through mere structures where the owners diversify and control listed companies, each of which controls several more, and so on. These structures allow a firm to control several more firms, which are collectively worth more than the family’s actual wealth; this is not possible through direct ownership alone. Morck et al. (2005) find that family members are usually appointed to key executive positions throughout the structure.

Consequently, it has been suggested that the aforementioned entrenchment channels and control mechanisms result to poor resource utilization because resources are typically diverted to the controlling family for their use. This implies inefficiencies in resource allocation, which increase value reduction. In a larger scale, economic entrenchment leads to what Morck et al. (2005) refer to as a “sub-optimal political economy equilibrium”, where capital allocation favors the elite families and may, thus, hamper the pace of innovation. Thus, the structure of the industry tips over – that is, entry barriers are erected and development of capital markets are stymied due to the political and corporate power exerted by the controlling families.

Furthermore, ill effects of entrenchment involve political rent-seeking, such as lobbying politicians and bribing judges, which a family firm might delve into due to lack of entrepreneurial skill or management talents of the family CEO (Morck and Yeung, 2003b; Chrisman et al., 2003). This particularly holds true for family firms, which are inherently reluctant to accept skilled outsiders, for fear of losing firm control. Thus, investments from a handful of these political elites may crowd out real investments (Chrisman et al., 2003) and innovation may be stifled if reliance upon the support of these lucrative politicians remains absolute.

Using the model of Stulz (1988), Claessens et al. (2002) illustrate a concave relationship between entrenchment and firm value – as managerial control and ownership increase, the negative consequences of entrenchment, which reduce firm value, overwhelm the positive benefits of managerial ownership. On the other hand, Morck et al. (1988)

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 7 report a non-monotonic relationship between entrenchment and firm value for U.S. firms – as entrenchment becomes more evident, firm value increases until the 5% level of ownership, declines sharply until the 25% level of ownership, then increases once more beyond said level. Morck et al. (1988) hypothesize that the increases in firm value may well represent convergence of principal-agent interests and/or the existence of high stocks of intangible assets in such firms5, whereas decreases in value reflect negative entrenchment effects, such as the pursuance of private interests by managers at the expense of minority shareholders.

Gomez-Mejia et al. (2001) study Spanish newspaper firms during the period 1966 to 1993 and report negative entrenchment consequences – that of better firm performances after the dismissal of a family CEO. Thus, Dyer, Jr. (2006) theorize that parent-owners are reluctant to monitor and discipline their kin executives due to altruism. Families tend to entrench their legacy within the firm and wait until firm performance is falling before initiating a change in leadership.6 As such, the unwillingness of family owners to monitor their agents implies adverse selection and shirking, which may impair firm value.

Hiller and McColgan (2005) find evidence in UK-listed companies that higher level of managerial control implies increased entrenchment, which diminishes firm value. Specifically, they report strong and positive responses in stock prices and a significant improvement in firm performance following the departure of a family CEO. Moreover, they find that shareholders accrue higher levels of cash flow streams after the departure of a family CEO and the replacement of a non-family member, which suggest the plausibility of expropriation taking effect prior to the replacement.

However, Burkart et al. (2003) show that entrenchment may reduce agency problems wherever legal protection of minority shareholders is weak. Because agency problems are severe as it is, the founding family must handle both ownership and management in order to avoid further information asymmetry consequences and agency costs. Shleifer and Vishny (1997) verify this in their survey of existing empirical literature by noting the significant role played by the legal environment upon firm structure. They find that in countries where legal protection of investors is not quite substantial, family firms and the entrenchment phenomenon abound which, in turn, protect minority shareholders against expropriation.

                                                                                                               5   According   to  Morck   et   al.   (1988),   family   firms  with   high   firm  value   and   which   possess   huge   amounts   of   intangible   assets  require   greater   management   ownership   “to   ensure   proper  management  of  said  assets”.  Hence,  entrenchment  and  firm  value  may  be  positively  correlated  in  the  case  of  such  firms.  6  This  is  in  line  with  Karra  et  al.’s  (2006)  findings,  which  support  the   increase   in   agency   costs   brought   about   by   excessive   family  altruism  and  entrenchment.  

In East Asian firms, where entrenchment and concentration is found to be high, control is often magnified through the use of control pyramids and cross-shareholding among family firms, where the manager is usually related to the founding owner (Claessens et al., 2002). For a sample of publicly traded firms from eight East Asian countries, Claessens et al. (2002) find that entrenchment effects are negative – that is, increases in control rights by the largest shareholder cause a decline in firm value. In particular, the use of control mechanisms – cross-shareholding and control pyramids – leads to a negative, albeit insignificant, effect on firm value. Therefore, such mechanisms cannot be reliably attributed to value discounts within the region.

In this study, we define a controlling family as one that is composed of firm stockholders who share a common surname and whose total outstanding stockholdings in the firm equate to at least 20% (La Porta et al., 1999). Thus, we describe a family firm as one where there exists a single family who controls at least 20% of firm voting rights or owns at least 20% of outstanding stockholdings. Moreover, we formally define family altruism as the desire of a controlling family to extend its welfare to other family members and we characterize it as the extent of controlling ownership of a family within a firm.

We measure family control (FAMICON) as the total percentage of outstanding shares owned by members of a controlling family. Therefore, we hypothesize that: H1: Higher family control (FAMICON) will lead to higher firm value due to the inclination of family firm owners to make decisions that will contribute to improvements in firm value, in line with their objective to preserve the firm for succeeding generations. However, it can also lead to lower firm value due to negative altruism effects brought about by excessive family entrenchment within the firm. Diversification Decisions

The literature on corporate diversification is quite vast. As a strategy adopted in pursuit of corporate growth and enhanced firm value, diversification is a means by which a firm can expand its core business into other industries and increase profitability (Chandler, 1962; Hall, 1995). Matsusaka (2001) views diversification as a “match-and-search” process, wherein firms seek to invest in businesses that match their capabilities. In East Asia, where inefficient institutions are prevalent, diversification is typically identified in view of its capacity to internalize costs and functions for firms; thus, generating scope advantages and reducing corporate risk (Chakrabarti et al., 2007).

In this study, we adopt Ansoff’s (1957) general definition of corporate diversification as the process of

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 8 venturing into new markets with new products – the production of which may or may not be technologically related to the firm’s original core business. The subsidiary must, however, be connected to the parent firm (e.g. partial ownership of the subsidiary; affiliated with the parent).

Meanwhile, the classic Modigliani-Miller theory assumes that the market value of a firm is not dependent on the capital structure a firm employs, but on the risks underlying assets and on the firm’s earning power; thus, implying that in perfect capital markets, diversification is presumed to not be an influential determinant of firm value (Erdorf et al., 2012). However, the continued prevalence of firms operating in more than one industry cannot be explained by said theorem. Thus, Erdorf et al. (2012) provide reasons for firms’ diversification: Agency Theory

Agency problems are theorized to be rooted from the opportunistic behavior of the agent or management (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Davis et al., 1997; Shleifer and Vishny, 1989). As such, agency theory predicts that firms diversify in order to maximize the agent’s utility at the expense of the firm’s shareholders – the principal (Fama and Jensen, 1983). Such firms are reported to diversify for the purposes of: (i) expanding power, prestige and level of entrenchment (Shleifer and Vishny, 1989; Jensen and Murphy, 1990; Jensen, 1986); (ii) improving a manager’s future career prospects (Aggarwal and Samwick, 2003); and (iii) reducing exposure of personal employment and individual portfolios to risk (Amihud and Lev, 1981). Thus, due to self-serving motives, the agent may tend to over-invest or over-diversify beyond the optimal level, which are posited to diminish firm value (Erdorf et al., 2012).

Aggarwal and Samwick (2003) use companies obtained from Standard & Poor’s dataset and find that diversification decisions are attributed to the marginal utility obtained by agents from diversifying; such decisions incur firm value reductions. Their results are consistent with that of Berger and Ofek (1995) and Lang and Stulz (1994), as both use U.S. firm-level data and find diminished firm value due to diversification. Internal Capital Markets

Internal capital markets, as defined by Maksimovic and Phillips (2013) and Erdorf et al. (2012), are mechanisms in which cash flows from a particular segment of a diversified firm can be used to internally subsidize another segment through firm resources. As such, resources used to finance segments are sourced internally, as opposed to funding by external financial instruments. Arguably, this method can be efficient if it eliminates costs created by financial constraints

in certain segments. However, Maksimovic and Phillips (2013) argue that inefficiency from using such markets may arise due to the rent-seeking behavior of the principal party; that is, the concentrated amount of capital may highly incentivize the owners or management to take advantage of opportunistic behaviors.

Rajan et al. (2000) use a sample of U.S. firms and find that greater diversification entails higher potential of misallocated capital due to “power struggles” existent between segments. Erdorf et al. (2012) further argue that over-investment in divisions with dire prospects may exacerbate inefficiency. However, Stein (1997) argues that executives may be able to efficiently allocate funding through business units through internal capital markets, given that they have insider information pertaining to each firm segment. Co-Insurance Effect Theory

Financial synergies, which occur when operations are

combined – as is the case in diversification where various industries or divisions function under one firm name – dilute the risk throughout the various segments and, thus, reduce the likelihood of insufficient debt service for a particular division. Kim and McConnell (1977) and Erdorf et al. (2012) point to Lewellen (1971) as the original proponent of this theory and explain how the latter argues that the imperfectly correlated earnings from two separate firms would “reduce the risk of default” when they merge. This motivates firms to diversify or to merge due to higher debt capacity potential. Using U.S. firm-level data, Kim and McConnell (1977) find that financial leverage was well-used by firms post-merging than the separate firms did before the merger. Family Altruism and Succession Theory

Lien and Li (2013) suggest that diversification helps to facilitate the process of inter-generational succession through fostering a set of subsidiaries that are self-sustaining. Family-controlled firms – in pursuit of their goal to maximize family well-being through effective management of the firm – tend to create succession plans that entail passing the firm down to the succeeding generations (Sharma et al., 2003), as soon as the current generation retires or steps down. This would motivate family firm owners to delve into diversification, in order to prevent competition and feuds among heirs, by allocating subsidiaries or divisions to each one of them, which would expand the family’s social network and pool of resources as well (Lien and Li, 2013).

Kachaner et al. (2012) note that executives of family-controlled businesses concentrate more on long-term investments to benefit the succeeding generations. Their study uses family firm-data from the U.S. and Europe and shows

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 9 that family businesses focus on resiliency rather than performance; that is, they tend to manage and improve on their downside, which enables them to avoid greater losses in times of crisis. They find that, in order to achieve resiliency, family-run firms exhibit surprising levels of diversification. Diversification is argued to be a key strategy to protect family wealth because if one sector is affected by the economy’s performance, businesses in other sectors can generate funds that can compensate for losses stemming from said sector.

However, such family altruistic behavior inclines family-managed firms to over-entrench themselves within various firm segments and, subsequently, destroy firm value (Lien and Li, 2013). Lien and Li (2013) verify this theory through their findings of a negative relationship between family-influenced diversification and firm value. Unrelated and Related Diversification

Markides (1995), Markides (1997), and Markides and Williamson (1996) classify diversification into two kinds: (i) unrelated or conglomerate diversification; and (ii) related or concentric diversification. The former refers to processes wherein the business branches out to subsidiaries whose products or industries are unrelated to the original business of the firm; conversely, the latter deals with related ones. Related diversification strategies may generate operational advantages for the family firm through the presence of synergies that may be captured through the creation of a portfolio of businesses that is ‘mutually reinforcing’ (Gomez-Mejia, 2007; Seth and Dastidar, 2009). On the other hand, unrelated diversification may reduce risk for the family due to investment in a variety of industries; reduction of risk implies higher operational efficiency and lower transactional costs for the firm (Amit and Wernerfelt, 1990). Thus, as Gomez-Mejia (2007) put so concisely, “related diversification offers scope economies, whereas unrelated diversification offers greater risk reduction.”

Chatterjee and Wernerfelt (1991) claim that firm resources are a focal determinant of the type of diversification strategy that a firm would invest in. If resources tend to be product-specific, then the firm would be constrained to related diversification; the converse holds true when resources are deemed to be flexible. On the other hand, Christensen and Montgomery (1981) suggest that market conditions also influence diversification and the type of strategy to be pursued. Specifically, in markets with ‘low-business opportunities’, firms would be constrained to pursuing related diversification due to lack of available markets to invest in. Moreover, Hall (1995) finds that a firm’s past performance affects its willingness to pursue diversification. Firms with below-par performance tend to diversify more, regardless of whether related or unrelated diversification is pursued, due to

the perception of such an activity as a solution to financial problems.

La Rocca and Stagliano (2012) find that unrelated diversification has a positive impact on firm value for a sample of 229 Italian firms. They attribute this to be a result of firm efficiencies which include lower risk and internalized capital markets. In contrast, Berger and Ofek (1995) find that unrelated diversification is associated with a larger value loss than related diversification for U.S. firm data. On the other hand, Markides and Williamson (1996) use the results of a survey of CEOs of U.S. firms and find that those that diversify towards related industries tend to be profitable, as long as they invest in strategic assets. Furthermore, using a sample of U.S. firms, Christensen and Montgomery (1981) find that related-constrained firms earn high returns and incur low risks because they are allowed to focus on capitalizing on their core strength and to operate within highly concentrated markets. On the other hand, they find that firms with unrelated diversification earn low returns and incur high risks due to firms’ inattention and entry into highly fragmented industries. Conversely, Marinelli (2011) studies U.S. firms and finds that related diversification is associated with lower firm performance, whereas unrelated diversification leads to enhanced firm performance.

In the Philippines, firms such as the Jollibee Food Group and the Sy Group engage in related diversification, whereas Ayala, Aboitiz, Metro Pacific, and the Andrew Tan Group engage in unrelated diversification. Moreover, there are companies, such as the Lopez Group of Companies, Gokongwei, San Miguel and DM Consunji Group, which prefer both diversification strategies (Gutierrez and Rodriguez, 2013).

Furthermore, Gutierrez and Rodriguez (2013) study the diversification strategies of the aforementioned firms and find that a majority of them pursue unrelated diversification, partly due to changes implemented by the government. These changes include, but are not limited to: (i) the deregulation of the Philippine telecommunication industry, which ushered in a flurry of foreign investments; and (ii) the privatization of the water utility business during the 1990s to the 2000s. Moreover, growth opportunities in the firms’ initial core businesses are found to be declining. Said findings imply that firms take into account the institutional context when determining the appropriate diversification strategy to pursue. Impact of Diversification Decisions on Firm Value

Theoretical suppositions argue that diversification can have both value-enhancing and value-reducing effects. Engaging in various lines of business within one firm can increase operational efficiency, whereas cross-subsidies involving misallocation of resources and the increased use of

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 10 such resources to fund unprofitable investments both reduce firm value (Berger and Ofek, 1995). Furthermore, higher business leverage (Lewellen, 1971) provides greater debt capacity to multi-segment firms. However, information asymmetry costs, which are highly prevalent in diversified firms due to wider dispersion of information, leads to lower firm profitability and value (Berger and Ofek, 1995).

Moreover, because the government collects taxes when income is positive but not when it is negative, Majd and Myers (1987) predict that diversified firms pay less tax than its individual segments would have paid separately, as long as one or more subsidiaries incur losses in some years; thus, diversified firms are said to have a tax advantage. However, Jensen (1986) suggests that the presence of increased cash flow in subsidiaries due to diversification induces managers to invest more in negative net present value projects. Meyer et al. (1992) further note that channeling resources into one or more failing subsidiaries generates value losses for multiunit firms.

Markides (1992) also suggests that overinvestment may diminish firm value. As pointed out by Aquino (2003), firm diversification depicts an inverted-U behavior, where diversifying and acquiring subsidiaries initially adds firm value but any further diversification hampers performance. Despite this, firms continue to diversify beyond the optimal level; thus, destroying firm value and shareholders’ wealth (Hoskisson et al., 1993; Martin and Sayrak, 2003; Tallman and Li, 1996).

The behavioral agency model developed by Wiseman and Gomez-Mejia (1998) further suggests that families are averse to losing their socio-emotional wealth (SEW) or the non-financial aspects of a firm, which include family identity and reputation and the perpetuation of the family dynasty. In line with this, Gomez-Mejia et al. (2007) find that family firms may prefer lower levels of diversification, in order to protect their current stock of socio-emotional wealth or value. This behavior implies that diversification may lead to firm value deterioration due to the following reasons (Gomez-Mejia et al., 2007):

(i) The complexity of the diversification process,

which involves delving into new territories using untried methods, may cause greater uncertainty and diminish SEW;

(ii) The necessity of using external financing and talent, which will introduce more external actors into the firm, may drive the firm’s modus operandi away from its objectives and diminish SEW; and

(iii) The inherent characteristic of family firms to exhibit strong inertia may engender resistance from family members when new markets and products are introduced; thus, SEW may diminish.

Empirical evidence on the relationship between firm diversification and firm value is inconclusive. For instance, in their seminal article, Lang and Stulz (1994) use a sample of U.S. firms and show that diversified firms have lower firm value, as opposed to non-diversified firms, although the reason behind said valuation difference has not been clearly explained. Berger and Ofek (1995) further investigate this result using U.S. firm-level data as well and report that inefficient diversification and overinvestment cause multi-segment firms to lose even more value. Denis et al. (2002) account for global diversification and find that firm value for U.S. firms is also reduced – attributing such reductions to agency conflicts and corporate governance problems. Furthermore, Graham et al. (2000) find that diversification reduces firm value due to investments in poorly performing subsidiaries.

For East Asian firms, particularly those operating in Indonesia, Thailand, Japan, Malaysia, South Korea and Singapore, Chakrabarti et al. (2007) note that the effects of diversification are contingent upon the institutional context of the economy. That is, for more developed economies, where the institutional framework is relatively more substantial, diversification leads to lower firm performance, whereas those with underdeveloped institutional environments benefit from diversification, albeit to some extent only. Diversification benefits are limited, however, particularly during the presence of economy-wide shocks (Montgomery, 1994).

On the other hand, Villalonga (2004) and Kuppuswamy and Villalonga (2010) find that diversification increases firm value due to efficiency in investment and to the ability of the firms to source external finances. Moreover, Hall (1995) finds that diversification does lead to increased firm performance, albeit insignificant, for U.S. firm data, and Matsusaka (2001) generates a model which highlights diversification as a value-maximizing strategy. Pandya and Rao (1998), however, report that, using U.S. firm data, low and averagely performing diversified firms do, indeed, exhibit higher firm performance and value than undiversified ones, yet best-performing diversified firms are found to earn lower returns than undiversified firms.

In this study, firm segments are classified according to the nature of each segment’s industry. While detailed segment information can easily be obtained from databases and firm reports, the 2007 North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) provides a streamlined and efficient classification method concerning firm-level industries. Thus, in this study, we consider a subsidiary as industrially-related to the original business if the first two-digits of its four-digit NAICS code are the same as that of the parent firm’s two-digit code; otherwise, it is unrelated.7                                                                                                                7   We   make   use   of   the   NAICS,   as   opposed   to   the   Philippine  Standard   Industrial   Classification   (PSIC)   system,   because   the  

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 11

Various indices for measuring the extent of corporate diversification exist. In this study, we use the Entropy Index for Product Diversification (PDT) proposed by Hart (1971) and the Berry-Herfindahl index used by Montgomery (1982). Not only do both of these measures allow us to determine the extent of total corporate diversification pursued by a firm (DIVERSE), but they also enable us to decompose the extent with which a firm may pursue either unrelated (UNREDIV) or related (RELADIV) diversification.

Thus, we examine the relationship between diversification and firm value (TOBINSQ) and posit that: H2a: Higher total diversification (DIVERSE) will initially lead to higher firm value due to higher debt capacity and gains obtained from growth opportunities, but firms tend to over-diversify and eventually decrease firm value. This accounts for the inverted-U curve relationship (DIVERSE2) between firm value and the extent of total diversification. On the other hand, family firm members are highly inclined to over-entrench themselves within the firm through diversification for the sake of preserving family interests; hence, controlling family ownership will have a negative moderating effect on diversification performance (FAMICONDIVERSE negatively affects firm value). H2b: Growth opportunities inherent in industries outside the firm’s core business generate higher firm value for corporations that diversify to unrelated businesses (UNREDIV). However, firms eventually over-diversify and impair firm value. This phenomenon explains the presence of an inverted-U trend (UNREDIV2) between the extent of unrelated diversification and firm value. On the other hand, family firm owners, who seek to diversify to unrelated industries to prevent family members from competing within the same market, tend to over-entrench themselves within the firm. Such reckless behavior will cause family altruism to have a negative moderating effect on diversification performance (FAMICONUNREDIV negatively affects firm value). H2c: Conversely, related diversification (RELADIV) diminishes firm value by inhibiting the competitiveness of firms against those that are expanding their businesses to other growth-inducing industries. Family firm owners, however, are inclined to adopt more prudent measures to safeguard firm value against related diversification threats, in order to preserve the firm for succeeding generations. Hence, family altruism will have a positive

                                                                                                                                                                                                 former  is  more  universally  recognized  than  the  latter.  Moreover,  there   exists   no   significant   difference   between   the   industry  classification  standards  of  the  two.  

moderating effect on firm value (FAMICONRELADIV positively affects firm value). On the other hand, no theory accounts for a curvilinear trend between firm value and related diversification. Bank Ownership on Firm Value

In recent years, the role and influence of banks has shifted from being mere creditors to corporate block holders. In the literature, various claims as to whether the presence of bank ownership can improve or impede firm value have surfaced. For example, Young et al. (2008) find evidence that institutional investors promote good corporate governance both in developed and developing economies. In contrast, Lin et al. (2009) posit that companies perform worse with bank ownership.

The decision of an investor or institution to participate in firm governance is, in fact, contingent upon the type of investment made. Le et al. (2006) observe that investors have different strategic preferences, depending on their investment choices. For example, mutual funds aim to maximize returns with efficient investments (i.e. low cost and short time); thus, investors are reluctant to participate in governance. Conversely, institutional investors, such as banks, have long-term investments and they are, therefore, willing to participate in corporate governance, in order to ensure that their investments gain profitable returns.

Moreover, the significant role played by institutional investors cannot be underestimated. Claessens and Fan (2003) argue that firms need to pay attention to the demands of such institutions, in order to enhance corporate governance. When agency problems are present, it is possible for the role of institutional investors to come into play, as their equity participation allows the firm to benefit from their established reputation; hence, enhancing the company’s credibility to its minor shareholders. In addition, even if Sarkar and Sarkar (2000) find no evidence that mutual funds are active in corporate governance, they were able to obtain information pertaining to a positive relationship between firm value and ownership by directors, foreigners, and lending institutions.

However, Gorton and Schmid (1996) argue that the Opposed Interests Hypothesis posits the existence of two kinds of conflicts-of-interest that may negatively affect firm value: First, the objectives of a bank shareholder may be in conflict with those of other shareholders. Such is the case when banks obtain information that can be used to their own benefit. Since banks can manage access to external capital, it may take advantage of the control it imposes over firms; thus, requiring firms to pay higher interest rates on loans. Secondly, conflicts-of-interest may arise due to proxy voting. Small blockholders, as compared to large non-bank blockholders, are less likely to prevent banks from engaging in activities that are

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 12 contrary to firm value maximization. Such conflict occurs when banks vote upon the shares of minor blockholders; hence, fulfilling bank interests rather than that of the firm’s.

The contradicting motives between bank and firm also affect the latter’s diversification decisions. Filatotchev and Toms (2006) observe that succession plans, which aim to entrench family control, tend to contradict the interests of other shareholders. In the event that a bank is active in corporate governance, the entrenchment and diversification motives of the controlling family will be minimized, so as to prevent value-reducing actions. However, empirical findings pertaining to effects of bank ownership on firm value are ambiguous. In their study of German banks and firms, Gorton and Schmid (1996) find that bank control varies from time to time. Evidence shows that during 1974, German bank ownership was exceedingly extensive such that banks already held the equity of firms. They also report that bank ownership positively affected firm performance and value. Conversely, in 1985, findings show that the power and extent of bank blockholdings have been reduced due to the development of security markets, although German bank ownership still enhanced the performance of firms.

Sarkar and Sarkar (2000) investigate the relationship between firm value and the extent of equity held by different types of blockholders (i.e. foreign, corporate, and financial holdings) for a sample of Indian firms. Their results show that financial institutions possessing low concentrations of equity holdings are passive; thus, there exists no significant relationship between the holdings of an institutional investor and firm value. Moreover, their findings are consistent with that of the German or Japanese bank-based form of governance wherein financial institutions start monitoring the company once they have considerable debt and equity holdings. This, in turn, results to improved firm value.

On the other hand, Lin et al. (2009) find that, in their study of Chinese-listed firms, bank ownership and investments weaken firm performance and value when the bank is a major shareholder. Moreover, Claessens and Fan (2003) review ownership structures and their effects on Asian markets including Japan, Indonesia, Thailand, Korea, and China. Their findings indicate that financing from internal markets often face misallocated capital issues due to agency problems. Likewise, external financial markets did not provide much discipline, as conflicts-of-interest continue to persist and rents brought by financial and political connections exist.

We define bank ownership as the act with which banks hold major portions of shares in a firm sufficient to merit voting power. We measure bank ownership (BANKOWN) as the percentage of outstanding shares owned by a bank. Thus, we hypothesize that:

H3: Higher bank ownership (BANKOWN) leads to a positive effect on firm value – firm value will improve due to the concern and interest exhibited by bank shareholders on firm performance. However, the Opposed Interests Hypothesis posits that increased levels of bank ownership leads to a decline in firm value due to conflicts-of-interest that may exist between bank shareholders and other blockholders. Hence, the relationship between bank ownership and firm value is ambiguous. Firm Size, Firm Age, and Nature of Industry on Firm Value Control variables deemed to possibly affect a firm’s diversification activities include firm age (FIRMAGE) and firm size (FRMSIZE). Similar to Lien and Li (2013), our measure of firm age is the number of firm-years since incorporation. On the other hand, firm size is an experience indicator gained by the firm from inception. Lien and Li (2013) use the scale of total capital measured as the sum of all long-term debt and equity to represent firm size. Alternatively, it is measured by Gomez-Mejia et al. (2007) as the natural logarithm of a firm’s total number of employees, and by Gomez-Mejia et al. (2003) as the natural logarithm of the average value of a firm’s sales. Market value of equity is another popular measure of firm size. In this study, we use market capitalization in its natural logarithmic form to account for firm size.

The quest for organizational immortality has long since garnered attention, yet literature has not tackled much of the subject. Firm age is widely posited to be positively-correlated with firm profitability and value due to firms’ tendency to learn as they age; through investing in R&D, hiring more labor and capital resources, and discovering a particular field of specialization, older firms enjoy higher profitability and value (Loderer and Waelchli, 2010). Another stream of research claims, however, that older firms are more prone to inertia and are less quick to adapt to changes in bureaucratic conditions; thus, incurring firm value losses (Majumdar, 1997). Therefore, the effect of firm age on firm performance is equivocal.

On the other hand, Gibrat’s Law of Proportionate Effects states that firm growth or firm performance, as the literature interchangeably uses, is independent from firm size. However, extant literature has disproved this law (Hall, 1987; Mansfield, 1962; Singh and Whittington, 1975). Larger firms are found to enjoy higher growth and firm value due to their ability to exploit scale economies and to easily access credit; possessing a broader pool of resources also allows them to benefit from increased production (Mansfield, 1962). However, small firms are also found to suffer less from agency problems and are more flexible in their organizational framework, which allows them to easily adapt to changing

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 13 conditions (Yang and Chen, 2009). Surviving smaller firms are also found to have higher growth rates than larger firms (Mansfield, 1962). Thus, the effect of firm size on firm performance is ambiguous.

Using the previously defined measures for firm age (FIRMAGE) and firm size (FRMSIZE), we hypothesize that: H4: Firm age (FIRMAGE) has an ambiguous effect on firm value. H5: Firm size (FRMSIZE) has an ambiguous effect on firm value.

Moreover, the food consumer and production industry has been continuously innovating and raking in sales increases. The continual increase in purchase expectations, which is brought about by the iterative development of consumer products, is expected to further boost profitability in the food industry. For instance, almost half of Pepsi Co.’s

2009 revenues were generated outside the U.S., and Unilever’s ice cream brands have consolidated sales revenues from almost 16 countries (Chatterjee et al., 2011); thus, contributing to increases in industry revenues and value. Furthermore, Pils (2009) asserts that businesses, whose specialization lies in the area of food and consumer services, are highly likely to gain firm value improvements through diversification, particularly to related industries. This is because diversification is theorized to maximize internal synergies by allowing the firm to fully utilize the potential of existing technologies and marketing systems that are prevalent in food-specializing businesses, nowadays. As such, we posit that: H6: Firms in the food consumer and production industry (CONSUMR) enjoy increased firm value.

Table 2.1 summarizes our hypotheses, in line with

the relevant theories that substantiate them.

Table 2.1. Summary of Hypotheses and A Priori Expectations

Variable Name Theory Justification

Family

Altruism and Succession

Theory

Agency Theory

Other Theories / Empirical

Results

Models A, B, and C (Dependent Variable: Firm Value – TOBINSQ)

FAMICON (+) (-) --

Family firms aim to preserve the firm for the sake of succeeding generations; hence, they will make decisions that will enhance firm value. However, agency theory posits that the excessive entrenchment of family members within the firm may induce these owners to expropriate from minority shareholders; hence, reducing firm value.

DIVERSE -- --

(+) Empirical Basis;

Co-Insurance Effect Theory

Diversification will initially increase firm value due to the ability of the firm to source external finances. The gains enjoyed by the firm from investing in growth opportunities outside the core industry also improve diversification performance (Villalonga, 2004). Moreover, financial synergies existent within various firm segments dilute risk across industries and increase the firm’s debt capacity.

DIVERSE2 -- (-)

(-) Empirical Basis

While diversification can have value-enhancing effects (firm expansion and growth), value-reducing consequences also result from increased tendencies of firm owners to over-diversify (Aquino, 2003). Moreover, the risks involved in the diversification process, as well as the necessity of introducing external talent and actors into the firm, may engender firm value. Likewise, self-serving motives may induce agents to eventually over-diversify and, consequently, expropriate minority shareholder wealth; thus, agency theory posits a negative curvilinear trend between diversification and firm value as well.

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 14

FAMICONDIVERSE (-) (-)

(-) Behavioral

Agency Model

Family control is manifested through family altruism, which, in turn, entrenches the family within the firm through the creation of succession plans for the next generation of family firm members. Because such family firms tend to over-entrench themselves by diversifying over the optimal level (Aquino, 2003; Martin and Sayrak, 2003), diversification performance is impaired. Likewise, agency theory posits that through over-entrenchment, excessive family control leads to expropriation of shareholder wealth at the behest of the self-serving agent. Thus, firm value deteriorates. Moreover, the behavioral agency model proposed by Wiseman and Gomez-Mejia (1998) theorizes that family firms exhibit strong resistance when new markets and products are introduced through diversification; the diversification process also proposes new and untried approaches, which the firm is not yet familiar with. Hence, it is very likely that firm value will diminish.

UNREDIV -- --

(+) Empirical Basis

Gutierrez and Rodriguez (2013) find unrelated diversification pursuits to be prevalent in the Philippine setting due to the abundance of growth opportunities outside a firm’s core industry. Moreover, Amit and Wernerfelt (1990) find that unrelated diversification pursuits reduce risk for the firm.

UNREDIV2 -- (-)

(-) Empirical Basis

Excessive investments and diversification towards unrelated industries may eventually erode firm value due to risks entailed whenever the firm delves into new industries and markets (Aquino, 2003). Moreover, eventual firm value deterioration is attributed to the likelihood of firm agents to over-entrench themselves within the firm, as manifested in over-diversification tendencies. This induces agents to expropriate from shareholders; thus, destroying firm value.

FAMICONUNREDIV (-) (-)

(-) Behavioral

Agency Model

Family firm owners seek to prevent family members from competing within the same market; thus, they diversify to unrelated industries. However, they tend to over-entrench themselves within the firm which, in turn, inclines them to expropriate from shareholders and to try new and untested diversification approaches (behavioral agency model). Thus, diversification performance is negatively moderated by the presence of family altruism.

RELADIV -- --

(-) Empirical Basis

Firms are reluctant to invest in segments that are aligned with the firm’s original industry because it inhibits their level of competitiveness against other firms, which are already expanding and raking in higher profits due to the gains harnessed from entering dynamic industries (Gutierrez and Rodriguez, 2013). Hence, firm value declines whenever firms are unable to compete.

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 15

RELADIV2 -- -- --

The relationship between firm value and the extent of related diversification is hypothesized to be linear. It does not follow the curvilinear supposition on total diversification because it is posited that related diversification does not significantly influence the extent of total diversification (Gutierrez and Rodriguez, 2013).

FAMICONRELADIV (+) -- --

Family firm owners, on the other hand, are theorized to be more watchful when firm value is inhibited due to repercussions brought about by lack of competitiveness that is posed by related diversification pursuits. Because they are more pressed to increase firm value due to family firm perpetuation purposes, they are asserted to find prudent ways to positively moderate the negative effects of related diversification on firm value.

BANKOWN (+) (+)

(-) Opposed Interests

Hypothesis

Banks, who have significant investments in the firm, seek to maximize returns by protecting firm value. As such, these institutions will oppose firm actions that will further entrench the family within the firm – such as over-diversification – which, in turn, will destroy firm value. Moreover, banks will ensure that shareholder wealth is not engendered by self-serving agents who seek to maximize personal utility; thus, effectively avoiding reductions in firm value. However, the Opposed Interests Hypothesis argues that higher levels of bank ownership may be detrimental to firm value due to conflicts-of-interest that may arise between bank shareholders and other blockholders.

FRMSIZE -- --

(+/-) Empirical Basis

Larger firms tend to have a broader pool of available resources at hand that enable them to exploit scope economies and growth opportunities – both of which add to firm value. On the other hand, smaller firms tend to be more flexible and adaptable (Mansfield, 1962; Yang and Chen, 2009); thus, allowing them to easily take advantage of value-enhancing conditions.

FIRMAGE -- --

(+/-) Empirical Basis

Because older firms tend to learn more as they age (discovering a particular field of specialization, gaining more productive resources, etc.), they earn higher profits and enjoy higher firm value (Loderer and Waelchli, 2010). On the other hand, younger firms are more flexible and are quick to adapt to value-enhancing conditions, as opposed to their older counterparts. (Majumdar, 1997).

CONSUMR -- --

(+) Internal Capital

Markets

Technological synergies prevalent within firms in the consumer (food) industry can be aptly maximized whenever firms diversify to related industries; hence, increasing firm value through gains obtained from economies of scope (Pils, 2009).

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 16 III. METHODOLOGY AND ECONOMETRIC MODELING Sample and Data Collection

We use a panel dataset that includes relevant firm-specific characteristics of publicly listed firms in the Philippine Stock Exchange (PSE). We construct and examine the financial information from secondary sources; that is, annual reports of our sample firms over the five-year period from 2008 to 2012. These are available through the Disclosure Department of the Philippine Stock Exchange. Specific criteria in determining the sample are indicated in Table 3.1. Table 3.1. Sample Data Reduction

Potential firms 280

Financial institutions (31)

Firms with IPO’s from 2008 onwards (22)

Firms that were delisted from 2008 to 2012 (39)

Firms with financial statement figures denominated in currencies other than the Philippine peso

(7)

Firms with missing data (68)

Remaining firms 113

Number of years x 5

Remaining firm-years 565

From all firms listed in the Philippine Stock

Exchange, we exclude firms classified by the NAICS as financial and insurance firms. Specifically, the two-digit core code of these firms starts with the digits “52”. Such firms are highly regulated and exhibit high levels of information asymmetry (Levine, 2004); thus, their governance structure differs from that of non-financial firms and, consequently, requires a separate study. Next, we select only those with initial public offerings conducted before January 1, 2008. From this subset, we exclude firms that have been delisted any time from 2008 to 2012. We also exclude firms with financial statement figures denominated in currencies other than that of the Philippine peso, as their methods of accounting for figures may differ from that of Philippine reporting standards. It may also introduce an exchange rate component to our study. Lastly, we eliminate firms with missing data, in order to end up with a balanced data set consisting of 113 firms or 565 firm-years.

Dependent Variable Proxy Measure of Firm Value

We use Tobin’s Q (market price to book value) as a proxy to measure firm value. It is a forward-looking measure, which provides information about firm performance with a simultaneous concern for investors’ valuations of both tangible and intangible assets (Lien and Li, 2013). It is also a robust indicator when comparing firms since it represents the present value of future cash flows divided by the replacement cost of the tangible assets. Tobin’s Q is as follows:

𝑇𝑂𝐵𝐼𝑁𝑆𝑄 =𝑀𝑉𝐶𝑆 + 𝐵𝑉𝑃𝑆 + 𝐵𝑉𝐿𝑇𝐷

𝐵𝑉𝐴

where MVCS is the market value of common stock, BVPS is the book value of preferred shares, BVLTD is the book value of long-term debt, and BVA is the book value of assets for a particular firm at a particular year.8 Independent Variables Determining Form of Corporate Diversification Corporate diversification pertains to the decisive strategy of a firm to branch out to subsidiaries that are either industrially related or unrelated to the firm’s core business. Based on Gutierrez and Rodriguez’ (2013) findings, we expect unrelated diversification to account for a significant portion of total corporate diversification; that is, firms in the Philippines are expected to have higher instances of unrelated corporate diversification and lower instances of related diversification. Determining Segments of a Firm An integral part of the methodology is identifying the number of industrial segments a firm operates in. The North American Industrial Classification Standard (NAICS) is one of the standards that can be used by statistical agencies in classifying business establishments according to the industrial segment in which they operate. It was jointly developed by the U.S. Economic Classification Policy Committee (ECPC), Statistics Canada, and Mexico’s Instituto Nacional de

                                                                                                               8   Lien   and   Li   (2013)   utilize   a   different  measure   of   Tobin’s   Q   to  account   for   firm   value   –   that   of   dividing   the   market   value   of  common  shares  (sum  of  beginning  and  ending  market  prices  per  share)   by   the   book   value   of   the   firm.   It   is   regarded   by   Lee   and  Tompkins   (1999)  and  by  Chung  and  Pruitt   (1994)  as   simplistic;  instead,  they  proposed  the  measure  used  in  this  paper  due  to  its  high  correlation  with  the  traditional  Tobin’s  Q  measure  employed  in  the  Lindenberg  and  Ross  (1981)  paper.  Moreover,  the  measure  employed  in  this  study  is  less  cumbersome  and  calls  for  easy  data  requirements  and  simple  computational  effort.  

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 17 Estadistica y Geografiya as a replacement for the previously used Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) system. This classification is similar to the Philippine Standard Industrial Classification (PSIC) system. However,

we proceed with the classification used by the Osiris database, which is the NAICS. The NAICS ranges from two digits at its broadest level to six digits at its most specific level. Listed below is a directory of the NAICS at the two-digit level.

Table 3.2. NAICS Core Industry Codes Sector Description

11 Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing and Hunting 21 Mining, Quarrying, and Oil and Gas Extraction 22 Utilities 23 Construction

31-33 Manufacturing 42 Wholesale Trade

44-45 Retail Trade 48-49 Transportation and Warehousing

51 Information 52 Finance and Insurance 53 Real Estate and Rental and Leasing 54 Professional, Scientific, and Technical Services 55 Management of Companies and Enterprises 56 Administrative and Support and Waste Management and Remediation Services 61 Educational Services 62 Health Care and Social Assistance 71 Arts, Entertainment, and Recreation 72 Accommodation and Food Services 81 Other Services (except Public Administration) 92 Public Administration

Proxy Measures of Corporate Diversification

We define corporate diversification as the process of

venturing into new markets using new products, whereby production may or may not be industrially related to the original core business of a firm. Product diversification is a suitable proxy for corporate diversification, as it is comprised of individual segments classified at the four or two-digit NAICS core code level – meaning products grouped in each code (e.g. 3115 – Dairy Product Manufacturing) are supposed to cater to a specific function directed at a specific market. Products with different brands but serving the same purpose (e.g. Piattos and Chippy) are classified under the same NAICS code and will, therefore, be treated as belonging to the same segment. New services created to penetrate new markets are assumed to be “products”. These services are included in calculating product diversification, provided that they satisfy the mentioned criteria regarding the NAICS code.

Sales from a holding or parent firm are included under the main business segment. Segments classified under “international” in annual reports are grouped with their NAICS-determined segment, if it can be determined. If not, it

is classified as “others”. If a segment receives dividends but does not generate sales, the income is classified under NAICS core code 55 [see Table 3.2]9. This usually happens in holding firms.

We use two proxy variables to measure the extent of corporate diversification. The first proxy is the entropy of product diversification, otherwise known as the Jacquelin-Berry index, used by Lien and Li (2013). It is specified as follows:

1

1( ) lnn

jj j

PDT PP=

⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞= ⋅⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟⎢ ⎥⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦∑

where 𝑃! is the proportion of sales for segment j,

ln(1/𝑃!) is the segment weight, j is the segment of product/industry at the four or two-digit NAICS core code level, and n is the total number of segments. PDT is zero when

                                                                                                               9  Whenever  segment  sales  of  a  firm  do  not  meet  the  quantitative  threshold  of  10%  of  total  sales,  firms  are  not  required  to  disclose  said  segment  sales   in  a  standalone  basis,   in  accordance  with  the  International  Financial  Reporting  Standards  (IFRS)  8.  

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 18 a firm is not diversified and increases as the firm becomes diversified. The second proxy is the modified Berry-Herfindahl (BH) index of diversification used by Montgomery (1982), which is specified as follows:

where 𝑃! is the proportion of sales in the firm’s jth

segment, j is the firm segment at the four or two-digit NAICS core code level, and n is the total number of firm segments. BH is also zero when the firm is not diversified and approaches 1 as total sales is equally divided among the segments (Kranenburg et al., 2004).10 Determinants of Family-Controlled Firms

Following the methodology used by Unite et al. (2008), we use 20% of total ownership of outstanding shares as the benchmark in classifying whether a firm is family-controlled or not. On the other hand, FAMICON takes into account the total percentage of outstanding shares owned by the controlling family. Identifying Family-Altruistic Shareholders Lien and Li (2013) identify family members of firms by summing up the shares of the stockholders who have the same surname as the individual with the largest portion of shares.

While this may be effective for some firms, others have privately held companies as the largest shareholder – some of which are either wholly owned or controlled by a dominating family. For example, the privately held firms of the Ayala family and the Aboitiz family are Mermac Inc. and Aboitiz & Co., respectively – both of which own around half of their publicly held counterparts: Ayala Corporation and Aboitiz Equity Ventures, Inc., respectively. It is difficult to obtain ownership data for privately held firms.

In the event that the individual stockholders cannot be identified as family members and in their place, privately held firms are found, we verify if a firm is either wholly                                                                                                                10  Aquino   (2003)   utilizes   a   crude  proxy  measure   to   account   for  corporate   diversification   –   merely   that   of   dummy   variables  representing  0  for  firms  that  did  not  diversify  and  1  for  those  that  did   diversify,   depending   upon   the   number   of   each   firm’s  unrelated   segments.   Contrastingly,   this   study   made   use   of  existing   proxy   measures   that   have   been   formulated   to   capture  the  extent  of  a  firm’s  diversification  with  higher  accuracy.  

owned or controlled by a particular family. We refer to the publicly held firm’s annual reports or through other sources to check. Once confirmed, we treat the privately held firm as if the controlling family wholly owns it and add it to any individual family members found in the Top 20 Shareholders portion of the annual report. We assume that holding at least a majority number of shares in a privately held firm is enough to merit altruistic behavior from the controlling family. Thus, its behavior in handling the firm is the same as if it wholly owns the company. Determining Bank Ownership We sum up the shareholdings of banks per firm-year, as indicated in their annual reports. It must be noted that securities under the investment arm of the respective banks are not included under bank ownership, as these are only short-term investments that have no influence on corporate governance. Control Variables

We also control for other variables that have been found in the literature to affect firm value: firm-specific characteristics, such as FRMSIZE, FIRMAGE, and CONSUMR.

2

12

1

1

n

jj

n

jj

PBH

P

=

=

= −⎛ ⎞⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 19 Table 3.3. Description of Variables

Variables (Code) Description Measurement/s

Dependent Variable

TOBINSQ Tobin’s Q – Measure of a firm’s value

where: MVCS = Market value of common stock = End-of-year stock price times shares outstanding BVPS = Book value of preferred stock BVLTD = Book value of long-term debts; and BVA = Book value of total assets

Independent Variables

Diversification Extent

DIVERSE Entropy measure of total diversification using the 4-digit NAICS codes

PDT – Product Diversification (Total Diversification)

where: 𝑃!  = proportion of sales in each four-digit NAICS industry j = business segment based on the four-digit NAICS codes n = number of business segments of the firm based on the four-digit NAICS codes

BH - Berry-Herfindahl Index (Total Diversification)

where: Pj = proportion of sales in each four-digit NAICS industry j = business segment based on the four-digit NAICS codes n = number of business segments of the firm based on the four-digit NAICS codes

UNREDIV

Entropy measure of unrelated diversification using the 2-digit NAICS codes

PDT (Unrelated Diversification)

where: 𝑃!  = proportion of sales in each two-digit NAICS industry i = business segment based on the two-digit NAICS codes x = number of business segments of the firm based on the two-digit NAICS codes

MVCS BVPS BVLTDTOBINSQBVA

+ +=

1

1lnn

jj j

DIVERSEPDT PP=

⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞= ⋅⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟⎢ ⎥⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦∑

2

12

1

1

n

jj

n

jj

PDIVERSEBH

P

=

=

= −⎛ ⎞⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠

1

1lnx

ii i

UNREDIVPDT PP=

⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞= ⋅⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦∑

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 20

BH (Unrelated Diversification)

where: Pi = proportion of sales in each two-digit NAICS industry i = business segment based on the two-digit NAICS codes x = number of business segments of the firm based on the two-digit NAICS codes

RELADIV Entropy measure of related diversification

PDT (Related Diversification)

RELADIVPDT = DIVERSEPDT – UNREDIVPDT

where: 𝑃!  = proportion of sales in each four-digit NAICS industry 𝑃!  = proportion of sales in each two-digit NAICS industry j = business segment based on the four-digit NAICS codes i = business segment based on the two-digit NAICS codes n = number of business segments of the firm based on the four-digit NAICS codes x = number of business segments of the firm based on the two-digit NAICS codes

BH (Related Diversification)

RELADIVBH = DIVERSEBH – UNREDIVBH

where: Pj = proportion of sales in each four-digit NAICS industry Pi = proportion of sales in each two-digit NAICS industry j = business segment based on the four-digit NAICS codes i = business segment based on the two-digit NAICS codes n = number of business segments of the firm based on the four-digit NAICS codes x = number of business segments of the firm based on the two-digit NAICS codes

Ownership Characteristics

FAMICON Presence of dominant family control in firm (family altruism)

Percentage of total outstanding shares owned by members of the controlling family

BANKOWN Bank ownership in firm Percentage of total outstanding shares owned by banks

2

12

1

1

x

ii

x

ii

PUNREDIVBH

P

=

=

= −⎛ ⎞⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠

1 1

1 1ln lnn x

j ij ij i

RELADIVPDT P PP P= =

⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞ ⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞= ⋅ − ⋅⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟ ⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟⎢ ⎥ ⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦∑ ∑

2 2

1 12 2

11

1 1

n x

j ij i

xn

ijij

P PRELADIVBH

PP

= =

==

⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥= − − −⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦

∑ ∑

∑∑

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 21 Control Variables

FIRMAGE Firm age ln(number of years passed since incorporation of the firm)

FRMSIZE Firm size

ln(market capitalization)

where market capitalization = stock price times shares outstanding, at year end;

CONSUMR Nature of industry (Food) Dummy variable equal to 1 if the core business of the firm lies within the food industry; 0 otherwise

Investigating the Link between Total Diversification and Firm Value (Model A)

We measure the effect of block shareholders’ control level on firm value. The extent of total diversification of the firm, which is a continuous variable with a value of zero for completely undiversified firms, will be used as an exogenous variable, whereas the endogenous variable is 𝑇𝑂𝐵𝐼𝑁𝑆𝑄!", which is the proxy measure for firm performance. As such, we use a panel data approach specified as Model (A):

where 𝐹𝐴𝑀𝐼𝐶𝑂𝑁!" is the total ownership of

outstanding shares by family firm members, and 𝐵𝐴𝑁𝐾𝑂𝑊𝑁!" is the total ownership of outstanding shares by banks in the firm. 𝐷𝐼𝑉𝐸𝑅𝑆𝐸!" is added to measure the effect of diversification on firm value. 𝐷𝐼𝑉𝐸𝑅𝑆𝐸!"! is also added to capture any curvilinear effects exerted by diversification upon firm value.

κ' is the vector of coefficients of the control variables, such that:

κ'= [κ!          κ!          κ!  ]

and

𝐶𝑂𝑁𝑇𝑅𝑂𝐿 =𝐹𝐼𝑅𝑀𝐴𝐺𝐸!"𝐹𝑅𝑀𝑆𝐼𝑍𝐸!"𝐶𝑂𝑁𝑆𝑈𝑀𝑅!"

Two proxy variables for total corporate

diversification (DIVERSE) – namely, the Product Diversification entropy (PDT) index and the Berry-Herfindahl (BH) index – will be used to measure the extent of total

diversification at the four-digit NAICS core code level for each segment of each firm.

In order to test whether family control is significant enough to moderate the impact of diversification upon firm value, the following model is formulated:

where an interaction variable between controlling family ownership and total diversification extent is added as a regressor. This measures how controlling family ownership tempers diversification performance. Investigating the Link between Unrelated and Related Diversification and Firm Value (Models B and C) In order to account for the effects of the individual components of total diversification upon firm value, and so as to assess which component accounts for a significant portion of total diversification, we examine the relationship between firm value and the extent of a firm’s type of diversification. In the case of unrelated diversification, we use the two-digit NAICS to differentiate each segment. Through this, it is assured that only segments that are not industrially related are treated as separate segments, as opposed to using the more specific four-digit NAICS wherein segments that are industrially related are treated as separate segments.

Model (B)’s specifications are similar to that of Model (A). Hence, we have:

( A.1) TOBINSQit = β0 +κ 'CONTROLit + β1DIVERSEit

+β2DIVERSEit2 + β3FAMICONit + β4BANKOWNit + uit

( A.2) TOBINSQit = β0 +κ 'CONTROLit + β1DIVERSEit

+β2DIVERSEit2 + β3FAMICONit + β4BANKOWNit

+β5 FAMICONit × DIVERSEit( ) + uit

(B.1) TOBINSQit = β0 +κ 'CONTROLit + β1UNREDIVit

+β2UNREDIVit2 + β3FAMICONit + β4BANKOWNit + uit

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 22

where control variables and those that account for ownership characteristics are first regressed against firm value. Afterwards, we add the interaction variable between family control and extent of unrelated diversification, in order to test for the significance of controlling family ownership in moderating unrelated diversification effects upon firm value.

On the other hand, the extent of related

diversification measures the dispersion of a firm’s activities across corporate segments that fall under the same first two digits of the NAICS core code levels – that is, under the same core industry. For ease of computation, several studies have made use of the difference between total and unrelated diversification, in order to capture the extent of a firm’s related diversification (Davis and Duhaime, 1989; Gassenheimer and Keep, 1995).

Model (C) specifications follow that of the models pertaining to total and unrelated diversification. Hence, we have the following models:

where control variables and those that measure block ownership levels are tested against firm value, followed by the addition of the variable characterizing the interaction between family control and the extent of related diversification.

In the six model specifications analyzing the relationship between firm value and diversification extent (total, unrelated, and related diversification), we use alternative proxy variables for corporate diversification – the Product Diversification Entropy index and the Berry-Herfindahl index. Estimation Procedure

Similar to Lien and Li (2013), we make use of a

panel dataset and estimate our models using a random effects

model. Specifically, we make use of the generalized least squares estimation method that takes into account the presence of first-order autocorrelation.11 We also test for the presence of multicollinearity using the Variance Inflation Factor (VIF).12 Results are indicated in Appendix A.

For panel datasets, Greene (2000) argues that either a fixed or random effects model can be considered. Moreover, Verbeek (2000) asserts that the random effects model assumes that the observations are treated as being drawn from a normal distribution, whereas the fixed effects approach assumes that each observation is independent. Hence, we posit that it is more appropriate to use the random effects model to make inferences for the population due to our sample’s characteristics.

In order to verify this, we employ two standardized tests that have been formulated for panel data use. We first make use of the Hausman specification test, which operates under the null hypothesis that the coefficients estimated by the efficient random effects estimator are similar to the ones estimated by the fixed effects estimator. We also employ the Breusch-Pagan Lagrange Multiplier Test, whose null hypothesis posits that there exists no panel effect (significant variances across entities). We fail to reject the null hypothesis for the former test and reject the null hypothesis for the latter and, consequently, affirm the suitability of the random effects model for our sample data. Robustness Tests

For Models (A), (B), and (C), two proxy measures are used to account for corporate diversification. The entropy index (PDT) and the Berry-Herfindahl index (BH) both rely upon the NAICS to identify the level of diversification. Between the two, the Berry-Herfindahl index is not as robust as the entropy index is when identifying specific levels of firm segments (i.e. four-digit NAICS), according to Kranenburg et al. (2004). Both proxy measures are summarized in Table 3.3.

                                                                                                               11   The   presence   of   first-­‐order   autocorrelation   indicates   that   the  null  hypothesis  of  no  autocorrelation  was  rejected  for  Models  (A),  (B),   and   (C);   thus,   prompting   us   to   correct   for   it   using   the  generalized   least   squares   estimation   method   that   accounts   for  the  presence  of  first-­‐order  autocorrelation.  12  We   found   that   there   exists   no   intolerable   level   of   correlation  among   the   regressors   of   each  model,   as   all   concerned   variables  have  VIFs  that  are  well  below  the  threshold  of  10.  See  Appendix  A  for  multicollinearity  diagnostic  results.  

(B.2) TOBINSQit = β0 +κ 'CONTROLit + β1UNREDIVit

+β2UNREDIVit2 + β3FAMICONit + β4BANKOWNit

+β5 FAMICONit ×UNREDIVit( ) + uit

(C.1) TOBINSQit = β0 +κ 'CONTROLit + β1RELADIVit

+β2RELADIVit2 + β3FAMICONit + β4BANKOWNit + uit

(C.2) TOBINSQit = β0 +κ 'CONTROLit + β1RELADIVit

+β2RELADIVit2 + β3FAMICONit + β4BANKOWNit

+β5 FAMICONit × RELADIVit( ) + uit

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 23 IV. DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS AND EMPIRICAL RESULTS Descriptive Statistics

We present descriptive statistics on our measures of family altruism, diversification extent, and firm value, as well as on other corporate governance variables. This is done in

order to provide a preliminary picture of corporate diversification levels in Philippine publicly traded firms, particularly among family-controlled conglomerates, as well as the direction of the relationship between diversification extent and firm value for both forms of diversification.

Table 4.1 presents the annual means of the dependent variable TOBINSQ and selected corporate governance measures.

Table 4.1. Annual Sample Means for Firm Value, Diversification Extent, Family Altruism, and Selected Corporate Governance Measures

Variables 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Overall Average

Dependent Variable

TOBINSQ 1.0502241 1.4458107 1.7024773 1.4562357 1.6607277 1.4630951

Independent Variables

Diversification Extent

DIVERSEPDT 0.3820083 0.4019205 0.4133008 0.4444654 0.4416948 0.4166779

DIVERSEBH 0.2185131 0.2325771 0.2386952 0.2542849 0.2506982 0.2389538

UNREDIVPDT 0.3020199 0.3196632 0.3299703 0.3422080 0.3385615 0.3264846

UNREDIVBH 0.1752622 0.1875620 0.1937544 0.1996477 0.1964590 0.1905371

RELADIVPDT 0.0799884 0.0822573 0.0833304 0.1022573 0.1031334 0.0901933

RELADIVBH 0.043252 0.045015 0.044941 0.054637 0.054239 0.0484168

Ownership Characteristics

FAMICON 41.722211 41.933573 41.700675 40.842245 40.947821 41.429305

BANKOWN 2.4603293 2.4603293 2.4603293 2.4603293 2.4603293 2.4603293

Control Variables

FIRMAGE 38.530973 39.530973 40.530973 41.530973 42.530973 40.530973

FRMSIZE 24,342,549 40,279,239 40,812,097 42,366,301 53,736,814 40,307,400

CONSUMR 16 16 16 16 16 16

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 24

Figure 4.1 shows that, on average, the level of total diversification decreased from 2008 to 2010. It increased in 2011, and then further decreased in 2012. It seems that family firms have diversified more relative to their non-family counterparts in 2008, 2009, and 2011, whereas family firms have diversified less relative to non-family firms in 2010 and 2012. The statistics are consistent between the diversification proxies: entropy index (PDT), and modified Berry-Herfindahl index (BH). Table B1 in Appendix B shows the data used. Figure 4.1. Extent of Total Diversification

Figure 4.2 shows the extent of unrelated

diversification between family and non-family firms. Unrelated diversification extent declined from 2008 to 2009, increased until 2011, then further decreased in 2012. In addition, it seems that from 2008 to 2011, family firms have higher levels of unrelated diversification relative to their non-family counterparts. The converse is true for 2012. The PDT and BH indices show consistent results. Table B2 in Appendix B shows the data used. Figure 4.2. Extent of Unrelated Diversification

Figure 4.3 illustrates the level of related diversification from 2008 to 2012. On average, related diversification increased in 2009, decreased in 2010, increased once more in 2011, and then declined again in 2012. In 2008, 2010, and 2012, non-family firms have higher related diversification levels compared to family firms while they have lower related diversification levels in 2009 and 2011. The PDT and BH indices show consistent results. Table B3 in Appendix B shows the data used. Figure 4.3. Extent of Related Diversification

We classify firm value of non-family and family

firms according to increasing quintiles of the different forms of diversification in the succeeding illustrations. Figure 4.4-A shows that, through the use of the entropy index (PDT) and considering all firms, value peaks at the second quintile. It starts to decline until the fourth quintile, but increases once more in the last quintile. We see that the behavior of family firms alone follow a similar pattern. On the other hand, non-family firm value seems to peak at the middle quintile. In addition to this, we observe that non-family firms have higher value relative to family firms only in the second and third quintiles. We see a consistent pattern when using the modified Berry-Herfindahl index as the diversification proxy, as exhibited in Figure 4.4-B. Actual data is found in Table B4 in Appendix B.

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

Tota

l Dive

rsific

atio

n Le

vel

Year

Non-Family (PDT) All Firms (PDT) Family (PDT) Non-Family (BH) All Firms (BH) Family (BH)

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Unre

lated

Dive

rsific

atio

n Le

vel

Year

Non-Family (PDT) All Firms (PDT) Family (PDT) Non-Family (BH) All Firms (BH) Family (BH)

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

Relat

ed D

ivers

ificat

ion

Leve

l Year

Non-Family (PDT) All Firms (PDT) Family (PDT) Non-Family (BH) All Firms (BH) Family (BH)

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 25 Figure 4.4-A. Mean Firm Value in Increasing Quintiles of Total Diversification using PDT Index for Non-Family, All, and Family Firms

Figure 4.4-B. Mean Firm Value in Increasing Quintiles of Total Diversification using BH Index for Non-Family, All, and Family Firms

Figure 4.5-A shows mean firm value in increasing quintiles of unrelated diversification using the entropy index (PDT). Considering all firms, firm value is shown to increase from the first quintile up to the third quintile where it is highest, after which it decreases until the last quintile. Restricting the sample to non-family firms alone, we see that firm value sharply increases in the second quintile, and then starts to decrease from the third quintile to the fifth quintile. The case is different for family firms wherein value continually increases from the first to the last quintile. Figure 4.5-B illustrates the same phenomenon using the modified Berry-Herfindahl index (BH) as diversification proxy.

Observations between both figures are generally similar; the only difference can be observed in the fifth quintile wherein, upon considering all firms, firm value is seen to increase once more in Figure 4.5-B. Actual data is found in Table B5 in Appendix B.

Figure 4.5-A. Mean Firm Value in Increasing Quintiles of Unrelated Diversification using PDT Index for Non-Family, All, and Family Firms

Figure 4.5-B. Mean Firm Value in Increasing Quintiles of Unrelated Diversification using BH Index for Non-Family, All, and Family Firms

Figure 4.6-A illustrates mean firm value in increasing quintiles of related diversification using the PDT index. Considering all firms, firm value appears to decline in the second quintile, increases up to the fourth quintile, and then decreases again in the last quintile. Family firms follow a similar behavior whereas non-family firms do not. Non-family firms continually increase in value from the first quintile up to the fourth quintile, and then value sharply declines in the last

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

1 2 3 4 5

Firm

Valu

e

Total Diversification Quintile (PDT)

Non-Family All Firms Family

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

1 2 3 4 5

Firm

Valu

e

Total Diversification Quintile (BH)

Non-Family All Firms Family

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

1 2 3 4 5 Fir

m V

alue

Unrelated Diversification Quintile (PDT)

Non-Family All Firms Family

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

1 2 3 4 5

Firm

Valu

e

Unrelated Diversification Quintile (BH)

Non-Family All Firms Family

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 26 quintile. Figure 4.6-B shows a consistent pattern using the BH index. Actual data is found in Table B6 in Appendix B. Figure 4.6-A. Mean Firm Value in Increasing Quintiles of Related Diversification using PDT Index for Non-Family, All, and Family Firms

Figure 4.6-B. Mean Firm Value in Increasing Quintiles of Related Diversification using PDT Index for Non-Family, All, and Family Firms

Figure 4.7 shows that, on average, banks have limited ownership of less than 2.5% in Philippine publicly listed firms. This result is also accompanied by negligible variability in bank ownership levels throughout the sample period.

Figure 4.7. Bank Ownership

Estimation Results Extent of Total, Unrelated, and Related Corporate Diversification and Firm Value

Our precursory examination of descriptive statistics points to the prevalence of unrelated diversification, as opposed to related diversification, in the Philippine corporate setting, as evidenced by the similarity of results in both total and unrelated diversification cases. Moreover, the relationship between total and unrelated diversification and firm value appears to be of an inverted-U shape, which lends support to the findings of Aquino (2003) and of Lien and Li (2013). On the other hand, the descriptive statistics also suggest a non-monotonic relationship between firm value and the extent of related diversification. Also, banks are seen to have only minimal presence in publicly listed firms. In order to formally verify these results, we now estimate Models (A), (B), and (C). Table 4.2 presents the estimation results where PDT is used as a proxy for the extent of diversification.

Panel A of Table 4.2 shows the results of estimating Model A.1 (column 1) and Model A.2 (column 2) where we examine the effects of total diversification extent on firm value using the PDT entropy index. Column 1 does not control for family altruism effects on diversification performance (FAMICONDIVERSEPDT), whereas column 2 does. As ventured by the family altruism and succession theory, the interaction between family altruism and total diversification extent allows us to observe the over-entrenchment tendencies of family firm owners which, in turn, lead to firm value deterioration.

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

1 2 3 4 5

Firm

Valu

e

Related Diversification Quintile (PDT)

Non-Family All Firms Family

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

1 2 3 4 5

Firm

Valu

e

Related Diversification Quintile (BH)

Non-Family All Firms Family

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

Perc

enta

ge o

f Ban

k Ow

ners

hip

Year

Bank Ownership

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 27

Column 1 of Panel A indicates that firm age (FIRMAGE) is insignificant to firm value; however, firm size (FRMSIZE) is significant in improving firm value. Consistent with the findings of Mansfield (1962), large firms are able to enjoy improvements in firm value due to their ability to exploit scope economies through using a wider pool of resources. The statistically significant positive coefficient of CONSUMR suggests that firms in the consumer (food) industry tend to have higher firm value, particularly since

technological synergies inherent in such firms are maximized through diversification.13

                                                                                                               13   We   attempted   to   test   the   significance   of   electronics-­‐based  firms   on   firm   value.   However,   only   one   out   of   our   working  sample   of   113   firms   is   primarily   engaged   in   the   electronics  business;   hence,   prompting   us   to   disregard   the   electronics  market   as   a   potential   regressor   due   to   the   lack   of   sample   data  variability.  

Table 4.2. Results of Models (A), (B), and (C) using the Product Diversification (PDT) Entropy index

Random Effects Panel Data Estimation of Diversification Effects on Firm Value

Panel A (DIVERSE) Panel B (UNREDIV) Panel C (RELADIV)

Control Variables

FIRMAGE -0.0230 (0.0500)

-0.0200 (0.0516)

-0.0246 (0.0447)

-0.0249 (0.0534)

0.00661 (0.0471)

0.00984 (0.0477)

FRMSIZE 0.220 *** (0.0182)

0.216 *** (0.0184)

0.213 *** (0.0168)

0.211 *** (0.0180)

0.215 *** (0.0180)

0.215 *** (0.0179)

CONSUMR 0.176 * (0.105)

0.174 * (0.101)

0.162 (0.105)

0.170 (0.107)

0.220 ** (0.0984)

0.208 ** (0.0964)

Ownership Characteristics

FAMICON 0.00177 (0.00119)

0.00409 *** (0.00149)

0.00181 (0.00111)

0.00395 *** (0.00151)

0.00160 (0.00111)

0.00120 (0.00121)

BANKOWN -9.35e-05 (0.00290)

0.00131 (0.00307)

0.000781 (0.00255)

0.00199 (0.00301)

0.00188 (0.00282)

0.00140 (0.00318)

Diversification Extent

DIVERSEPDT -0.163 (0.191)

0.405 * (0.229)

DIVERSEPDT2 -0.135 (0.163)

-0.327 ** (0.164)

FAMICONDIVERSEPDT -0.00804 *** (0.00232)

UNREDIVPDT -0.205 * (0.108)

0.376 ** (0.162)

UNREDIVPDT2 -0.0831 (0.0917)

-0.229 ** (0.106)

FAMICONUNREDIVPDT -0.0114 *** (0.00250)

RELADIVPDT -0.341 ** (0.158)

-0.601 ** (0.247)

RELADIVPDT2 -0.00644 (0.176)

-0.0296 (0.187)

FAMICONRELADIVPDT 0.00739 * (0.00461)

Number of Observations: 565

Number of Firms: 113

Overall Wald’s Test: 265.22 *** 218.14 *** 346.70 *** 225.84 *** 228.78 *** 198.81 ***

AR(1) 7.055 *** 9.778 *** 6.870 ** 8.354 *** 6.024 ** 6.015 **

Coefficient estimates are in bold; standard errors are in parentheses; the estimates are corrected for serial correlation * significant at 0.10 level ** significant at 0.05 level *** significant at 0.01 level

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 28 However, without the interaction variable, column 1 of Panel A suggests that family altruism (FAMICON) does not significantly affect firm value. Moreover, results do not indicate a significant inverted-U trend between the extent of total diversification and firm value. With the inclusion of the interaction variable in column 2 of Panel A, results likewise suggest that firm size and those belonging to the consumer (food) industry improve firm value, whereas firm age remains an insignificant determinant of firm value. Contrary to column 1, however, results strongly suggest that diversification and firm value behave in an inverted-U manner; that is, diversification pursuits initially improve firm value (DIVERSEPDT is positive), whereas any further diversification only diminishes returns (the squared term DIVERSEPDT2 is negative). This is consistent with extant literature (Aquino, 2003; Lien and Li, 2013).

Because the inclusion of the interaction variable in column 2 generates results that lead to a significant inverted-U behavior between diversification and firm value, results, thus, suggest that the eventual decrease of firm value is driven by the statistically significant negative coefficient of the interaction variable FAMICONDIVERSEPDT. That is, the presence of controlling family ownership negatively moderates diversification performance due to over-entrenchment of the family within the firm, in line with the family altruism and succession theory. Hence, this also leads us to imply that family altruism plays an essential role in tempering diversification effects on firm value.

Moreover, with the inclusion of the interaction variable, we note how diversification pursuits affect firm value in family-controlled firms. Results in column 2 of Panel A point to a significant and positive relationship between family altruism and firm value (FAMICON is significant and has a positive coefficient). However, when family firms diversify, firm value declines (FAMICONDIVERSEPDT is significant and has a negative coefficient). This implies that prior to diversification, family altruism brings about positive firm value effects; post-diversification, however, it reduces firm value. Again, this is because family firm owners tend to over-entrench themselves within the firm and, subsequently, impair firm value, as posited by the family altruism and succession theory.

Panel B of Table 4.1 shows the results of estimating Model B.1 (column 1) and Model B.2 (column 2), which investigate the effect of unrelated diversification extent on firm value using the PDT entropy index. As before, column 1 does not account for family altruism effects on unrelated diversification performance (FAMICONUNREDIVPDT), whereas column 2 does. The family altruism and succession theory emphasizes the role played by family altruism in tempering unrelated diversification performance due to the reckless behavior of family firm owners.

Similar to Panel A results, column 1 of Panel B indicates an insignificant relationship between firm age and firm value. However, in the case of unrelated diversification, our results show that firms in the consumer industry do not significantly impact firm value. This is expected since technological synergies cannot be fully maximized when the firm engages in unrelated diversification (Pils, 2009). On the other hand, there is strong evidence that firm size significantly improves firm value, consistent with Mansfield’s (1962) findings.

Moreover, without the interaction variable, column 1 of Panel B shows only weak evidence that unrelated diversification (UNREDIVPDT) negatively impacts firm value. There is also no significant evidence of an inverted-U trend between unrelated diversification extent and firm value. Other variables are rendered insignificant to firm value as well.

However, the inclusion of the interaction variable in column 2 of Panel B provides more intuitive results. Results still suggest that both firm age and firms in the consumer (food) industry are insignificant to firm value, and that firm size improves firm value. However, contrary to column 1 results, there is strong evidence of an inverted-U behavior between the extent of unrelated diversification and firm value (UNREDIVPDT is positive; the squared term UNREDIVPDT2 is negative).

Similar to Panel A results, the inclusion of the interaction variable (FAMICONUNREDIVPDT) generates a significant inverted-U relationship between unrelated diversification extent and firm value. Hence, the statistically significant negative coefficient of the interaction variable suggests that the presence of family altruism negatively moderates unrelated diversification performance due to over-entrenchment tendencies of the family within the firm.

Moreover, we again note that the inclusion of the interaction variable allows us to observe unrelated diversification effects on firm value in family firms. Column 2 results suggest that family control improves firm value (FAMICON is significant and has a positive coefficient), but when these family firms diversify to unrelated industries, firm value declines (FAMICONUNREDIVPDT is significant and has a negative coefficient). These results are consistent with the family altruism and succession theory – because unrelated diversification prevents family firm members from competing within the same market, family firm owners tend to be reckless and to override the optimal scope of firm segments to diversify into; hence, over-entrenching themselves within the firm and impairing firm value.

Finally, Panel C of Table 4.2 shows the results of estimating Model C.1 (column 1) and Model C.2 (column 2), which investigate related diversification effects on firm value using the PDT entropy index. Similar to Panel A and Panel B, column 1 does not take into account family altruism effects on

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 29 related diversification performance (FAMICONRELADIVPDT), whereas column 2 does. As proposed by the family altruism and succession theory, the interaction between family altruism and related diversification extent allows us to verify whether or not family firm owners tend to positively moderate firm value when diversifying to related industries due to their prudent behavior aimed at protecting the firm as a family legacy.

Column 1 of Panel C results suggests that firms in the consumer (food) industry have significantly higher firm value. The variable CONSUMR’s strong statistical significance and positive coefficient is indicative of synergies that can only be utilized within the food industry. Similar to the results in Panels A and B, larger firms have significantly higher firm value, whereas firm value is not significantly affected by firm age. There is also strong evidence that the extent of related diversification decreases firm value (RELADIVPDT is negative), which is consistent with our a priori expectations wherein it is posited that firm value deteriorates when diversifying to related industries due to inhibition of competitiveness and firm growth.

Column 2 of Panel C results also show the positive and significant effects of firm size and of the consumer (food) industry on firm value, as well as the insignificance of firm age as a determinant of firm value. Similar to column 1 results, there is strong evidence that related diversification impairs firm value. However, the inclusion of the interaction variable (FAMICONRELADIVPDT) suggests some evidence that, albeit weak, family firms tend to positively moderate the negative effects of related diversification on firm value. This is consistent with the family altruism and succession theory – whenever firm value is threatened by growth constraints inherent in related diversification pursuits, family firm owners are more pressed than their non-family counterparts to preserve firm value, in line with their succession plan.

Column 2 results also suggest that there is no significant curvilinear trend between related diversification and firm value, consistent with our a priori expectations. Furthermore, unlike results in column 2 of both Panels A and B, family control does not seem to influence firm value whenever related diversification pursuits are concerned.

Finally, the results in Table 4.2 suggest that bank ownership (BANKOWN) does not significantly affect firm value, regardless whether we are examining total, unrelated, or related diversification. This is most likely due to the limited presence of banks in ownership of Philippine firms.14 This

                                                                                                               14  We  also  attempted  to  investigate  the  effects  of  the  interaction  between   bank   control   and   diversification   extent   on   firm   value.  Results   indicate   the   insignificance   of   bank   ownership   on   firm  diversification   performance   –   regardless   of   the   form   of  diversification   undertaken.   Hence,   in   the   Philippine   corporate  scenario,   banks   do   not   play   a   significant   role   in   firm-­‐level  decisions   because   of   their   limited   or   passive   presence   in   such  firms.  This  finding  is  consistent  with  Claessens  and  Fan’s  (2003)  

result is contrary to the findings of Lien and Li (2013). It is important to note, however, that in the Taiwanese case, most banks are either owned or largely affiliated with the government; thus, allowing the firm to penetrate markets that cannot be entered under ordinary circumstances (i.e. no affiliation with the government). On the other hand, the largest banks in the Philippines are privately owned and have minimal, if any, participation in corporate governance.

Overall, the results for the cases of total and unrelated diversification (Panels A and B) are similar. This implies that the family altruism and succession theory, for which total diversification (Panel A) results are consistent with, is more prominently manifested in unrelated diversification (Panel B), as opposed to its related form (Panel C).

Table 4.3 presents the results of the effects of diversification on firm value using the Berry-Herfindahl (BH) measure of the extent of diversification. The results in Table 4.3 are qualitatively similar to those of Table 4.2, but display stronger statistical evidence on the curvilinear relationship between total and unrelated diversification and firm value whenever the interaction variable capturing the role of family altruism is included.

                                                                                                                                                                                                 survey   of   extant   literature   wherein   it   is   found   that   control   by  financial   institutions   is   less   common  among   firms   in  developing  Asia   due   to   the   presence   of   underdeveloped   regulatory  frameworks   that   leave   the   actions   of   family   firm   agents  unchecked;   hence,   discouraging   banks   to   take   an   active   role   in  firm  governance.  

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 30 Table 4.3. Results of Models (A), (B), and (C) using the Berry-Herfindahl (BH) index

Overall, our empirical results suggest that: (i) Larger firms have higher firm value; (ii) Firms in the consumer (food) industry have higher

firm value, but only when they diversify to related industries;

(iii) Whenever the interaction variable capturing the role of family altruism in both total and unrelated diversification performance is included, we find said interaction variable to be significantly negative. We also find an inverted-U relationship

between total and unrelated diversification extent and firm value, and a significant and positive effect of family ownership on firm value. Moreover, when the interaction variable is excluded, we find that both total and unrelated diversification do not affect firm value. Altogether, these results imply that, consistent with the family altruism and succession theory, family-controlled firms have higher firm value before pursuing total and unrelated

Random Effects Panel Data Estimation of Diversification Effects on Firm Value

Panel A (DIVERSE) Panel B (UNREDIV) Panel C (RELADIV)

Control Variables

FIRMAGE -0.0362 (0.0495)

-0.0287 (0.0509)

-0.0252 (0.0439)

-0.0257 (0.0516)

0.00473 (0.0477)

0.00997 (0.0477)

FRMSIZE 0.214 *** (0.0181)

0.208 *** (0.0182)

0.213 *** (0.0169)

0.209 *** (0.0176)

0.212 *** (0.0182)

0.213 *** (0.0180)

CONSUMR 0.164 (0.102)

0.170 * (0.102)

0.148 (0.103)

0.152 (0.105)

0.221 ** (0.0992)

0.212 ** (0.0964)

Ownership Characteristics

FAMICON 0.00173 (0.00120)

0.00412 *** (0.00146)

0.00189 * (0.00111)

0.00396 *** (0.00145)

0.00174 (0.00113)

0.00127 (0.00121)

BANKOWN 0.000316 (0.00276)

0.00238 (0.00279)

0.000696 (0.00247)

0.00207 (0.00283)

0.00212 (0.00291)

0.00149 (0.00321)

Diversification Extent

DIVERSEBH 0.158 (0.393)

1.360 *** (0.466)

DIVERSEBH2 -1.122 * (0.622)

-1.997 *** (0.647)

FAMICONDIVERSEBH -0.0149 *** (0.00375)

UNREDIVBH -0.247 (0.168)

0.718 *** (0.247)

UNREDIVBH2 -0.351 (0.265)

-0.828 *** (0.301)

FAMICONUNREDIVBH -0.0189 *** (0.00369)

RELADIVBH -0.469 * (0.261)

-1.005 ** (0.419)

RELADIVBH2 -0.308 (0.494)

-0.397 (0.490)

FAMICONRELADIVBH 0.0148 * (0.00825)

Number of Observations: 565

Number of Firms: 113

Overall Wald’s Test: 264.50 *** 237.43 *** 335.18 *** 243.60 *** 214.13 *** 194.59 ***

AR(1) 8.716 *** 15.040 *** 6.541 ** 7.986 *** 6.325 ** 6.316 **

Coefficient estimates are in bold; standard errors are in parentheses; the estimates are corrected for serial correlation

* significant at 0.10 level ** significant at 0.05 level *** significant at 0.01 level

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 31

diversification, but they experience a reduction in firm value after diversifying. Results also suggest that this firm value decline is attributed to the presence of controlling family ownership, which negatively moderates diversification performance due to excessive family entrenchment within the firm;

(iv) Whether or not the interaction variable capturing the level of family altruism in related diversification is included, family ownership does not significantly affect firm value. We also find that an inverted-U relationship between related diversification extent and firm value does not exist, and that related diversification reduces firm value. In the case when the interaction variable is included, we find it to be significantly positive. Altogether, these results are consistent with the family altruism and succession theory – family-controlled firms are found to positively moderate harmful related diversification effects on firm value due to their prudent measures that seek to preserve the firm, in line with their succession plan;

(v) Bank ownership does not significantly influence firm value in the Philippine corporate setting;

(vi) It appears that the observed effect of total diversification on firm value is driven by unrelated diversification, rather than related diversification15;

(vii) The family altruism and succession theory is particularly manifested in the unrelated form of corporate diversification; and

(viii) The internal capital markets theory is seen in the effect of related diversification on firm value.

V. CONCLUSION

In this study, we endeavor to investigate the link between family altruism and diversification performance of publicly traded Philippine firms and to provide a framework to capture this relationship. We make use of two corporate governance theories that corroborate each other – the agency theory and the family altruism and succession theory. Overall, our results are consistent with the family altruism and succession theory, which emphasize family firm inclinations to preserve the firm for future generations and the consequent

                                                                                                               15   This   finding   is   particularly   notable,   as   we   have   successfully  traced   total   diversification   effects   to   that   of   its   unrelated   form.  Most   corporate   diversification   studies   (Lang   and   Stulz,   1994;  Aquino,  2003;  Lien  and  Li,  2013)  employ  total  diversification,   in  general,  as  a  variable  of  interest  without  having  identified  which  diversification  form  is  more  prevalent.    

effects of such decisions, depending upon the form of diversification undertaken.

We find evidence that family-controlled firms are associated with relatively higher firm value prior to diversification. The internal know-how and resources that have long been passed down from father to son give family conglomerates a competitive advantage against non-family firms. Moreover, family firm owners are inclined to improve performance, in order to preserve the business as a symbol of family wealth and to ensure that it will be bequeathed in good condition to succeeding generations. Without diversification as a means towards family entrenchment, family controlled firms avoid compromising shareholder wealth by reducing firm value. However, these firms also forgo the opportunity to harness growth opportunities existent in other industries.

We also find evidence of the negative effects of corporate diversification in our study. We note that increased diversification to unrelated industries initially improves firm value, possibly due to growth opportunities that abound outside the firm’s core industry. However, because family firm owners also seek to prevent their kin from competing with each other in the same market, they are inclined to over-entrench themselves within various firm segments. Such reckless behavior impairs diversification performance. Thus, we imply that family firms that diversify to unrelated industries tend to have lower firm value than their non-family counterparts. This is consistent with the family altruism and succession theory; in addition, the agency theory corroborates the family entrenchment phenomenon and attributes firm value reductions to the tendency of family firm owners to expropriate from minority shareholders.

On the other hand, our results also suggest that diversifying to related industries generally reduces firm value, possibly due to growth and competitiveness constraints. Family firm owners may be inclined to be more watchful and to adopt prudent measures that will safeguard firm value against threats posed by related diversification. They seek to moderate the negative effects of related diversification on firm value for the purpose of preserving the firm for succeeding generations. As such, family firms that diversify to related industries tend to have higher firm value than their non-family counterparts.

Moreover, we find that the inverted-U relationship between firm value and total and unrelated diversification extent may be due to family firm owners who tend to over-entrench themselves within the firm. Hence, it seems that family altruism plays a significant role in diversification performance through its negative moderation of total and unrelated diversification effects on firm value.

Finally, results seem to suggest that the total diversification phenomenon primarily reflects the behavior of unrelated diversification. Thus, it appears that the observable

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 32 tenets of the family altruism and succession theory are particularly manifested in the unrelated form of diversification, as opposed to the related form.

With the high number of corporate family groups that abound within the Philippines, the behavior of diversifying firms affiliated with such groups is worth examining. The prevalence of the unrelated form of diversification over its related counterpart supports agency problem concerns – that of using diversification as a mechanism to further entrench one’s kin within the firm and, consequently, reduce firm value through inclinations towards shareholder expropriation. Our findings imply that diversification in family firms may commonly lead to reductions in shareholder wealth. Hence, diversification should not be construed as an immediate solution towards improving firm performance; delving into it without considering corporate facets that may affect its performance is imprudent. For instance, firms exhibiting high levels of information asymmetry and are governed by weak regulatory standards will be highly subject to agency problems when diversification is pursued – lax monitoring policies may encourage firm members to shirk from their duties and, subsequently, incur moral hazard costs. Diversification may generate corporate gains but it is not without its costs.

Furthermore, our results suggest that there is no significant principal-principal conflict existent among Philippine publicly traded firms. There is no ascertained conflict between family and bank blockholders in terms of firm control; banks’ participation in corporate governance is minimal, if any. Hence, outsider monitoring is inhibited and further tempts family firm owners to commit self-serving acts16. While family over-entrenchment can be potentially tempered by the influence of these bank groups, had they been prevalent enough in firms, it does not signify that diversification is a guaranteed strategy that will enable the business to continuously expand prospects towards improving firm value. More often than not, this induces the diversifying family-controlled firm to blindly take advantage of unmet needs in emerging markets to the point of firm value deterioration. VI. POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS Because we see the impact of the extent of family-influenced unrelated diversification on firm value, we now

                                                                                                               16  The  extent  of  outsider  monitoring   in   firms   can  be  adequately  captured  by  examining  their  board  composition  –  whether  or  not  board   independence   is  prevalent   in   the  organizational   structure  of   such   firms.   However,  we   find   that   board   composition,  which  involves  board  independence  (the  percentage  of  board  members  comprised   of   independent   directors)   and   the   lack   of   it   (the  percentage   of   board   members   comprised   of   family   firm  members),   is   an   insignificant   determinant   of   firm   value   in   the  local  corporate  setting.  

abstract several recommendations to protect the wealth of minority shareholders in family-controlled firms. The results suggest that diversification initially adds firm value, then eventually reduces firm value. Also, diversified family-controlled firms appear to hamper firm value relative to their non-family counterparts, possibly due to over-entrenchment. Hence, minority shareholders must be aware of this phenomenon. Firms can also opt to conduct annual assessments concerning the effect of diversification efforts on firm value. For instance, the Aboitiz Group consulted the Monitor Study in 1997 and found out that the conglomerate had too many diversified business interests and lacked focus. They then divested their non-core businesses and focused on areas with proven competencies and good growth prospects. With the knowledge that these factors affect firm value, investment managers should also take into account family ownership level and extent of diversification when determining their portfolio of stocks. The results of the effect of diversification extent on firm value should be of interest to majority and minority shareholders alike, investors, directors, and other individuals and institutions involved in corporate governance in the Philippines. It helps them set their direction on the level of diversification they should pursue. It shows that family ownership, however altruistic, can prove to be detrimental to firm value especially when engaging in unrelated diversification. It suggests that all types of shareholders – major or minor – should actively participate in corporate governance because even the most invested shareholders in the firm (i.e. family members) can turn out to be irrational decision-makers whose decisions may hamper firm value. VII. RECOMMENDATIONS FOR FURTHER STUDIES

This study focuses mainly on the interaction between family altruism and its subsequent effects on diversification performance in both forms of diversification. However, the impact of family entrenchment does not end in firm value alone. Its effects go beyond firm performance and affect segment artifacts involving diversification premiums and discounts. Literature regarding the latter has yet to be extended. Due to time constraints, we were no longer able to account for the presence of diversification premiums and discounts in the Philippine corporate setting.

Rajan et al. (2004) investigate the reason why shares of diversified firms are traded at a discount. They find that, ideally, firms are to take advantage of cooperative investments; that is, firm divisions invest funds in the segment that is performing well, in order to maximize profitability. However, due to the presence of managers with self-serving interests, segments that are no longer performing well are still retained; thus, dragging down the entire business. Similarly,

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 33 Graham et al. (2002) posit that firm segments acquired through mergers are considered as discounted units; therefore, they decrease the firm’s total value.

There exist only a limited number of studies that assess whether or not corporate diversification generates discounts or premiums in the Philippines. The impact of these diversification constructs on firm value has also not yet been accounted for in the local setting. In order to enrich the existing literature on corporate diversification in the Philippines, further studies may also focus on the interaction between family altruism and such diversification artifacts.

Furthermore, future studies may opt to discern the optimal level of diversification for Philippine firms,

particularly for family-controlled conglomerates. The prevalence of the inverted-U behavior between diversification extent and firm value in the Philippine setting implies the presence of an average optimal diversification level for all sample firms, beyond which firm value will begin to decline.

Also, fertile fields of research include making use of a larger dataset to extensively analyze family altruism effects on diversification performance over a longer time period. Moreover, such a dataset may provide stronger evidence concerning firm hierarchical and structural influences upon firm value, especially since transitions that occur within a firm’s management may be captured using additional variables of interest (e.g. board characteristics).

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 34 VIII. REFERENCES Aggarwal, R.K. & Samwick, A.A. (2003). Why do managers

diversify their firms? Agency reconsidered. Journal of Finance, 58(1), pp. 71-118.

Amihud, Y. & Lev, B. (1981). Risk reduction as a managerial

motive for conglomerate mergers. The Bell Journal of Economics, 12(2), pp. 605-617

Amit, R. & Villalonga, B. (2006). How do family ownership,

management and control affect firm value? Journal of Financial Economics, 80, pp. 385-417.

Amit, R. & Wernerfelt, B. (1990). Why do firms reduce

business risk? The Academy of Management Journal, 33(3), pp. 520-533.

Anderson, R. & Reeb, D. (2003). Founding-family ownership

and firm performance: Evidence from the S&P 500. The Journal of Finance, 58(3), pp. 1301-1328.

Ansoff, I (1957). Strategies for Diversification. Harvard

Business Review, 35(5), pp. 113-124. Astrachan, J., Keyt, A., & Blumentritt, T. (2007). Creating an

environment for successful nonfamily CEOs: An exploratory study of good principals. Family Business Review, 20(4), pp. 321-335.

Austria, J. (2013). Aboitiz ventures into water. Manila

Standard Today. Aquino, R. (2003). Corporate diversification and firm value.

Philippine Review of Economics, 40(2). Berger, P.G. & Ofek, E. (1995). Diversification’s effect on

firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 37(1), pp. 39-65.

Berle, A.A. & Means, G.C. (1932). The modern corporation

and private property. New York: Harcourt, Brace and World.

Burkart, M. & Panunzi, F. (2003). Agency conflicts,

ownership, concentration, and legal shareholder protection. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 15, pp. 1-31.

Chakrabarti, A., Singh, K., & Mahmood, I. (2007).

Diversification and performance: Evidence from East Asian firms. Strategic Management Journal, 28, pp. 101-120.

Chandler, A. (1962). Strategy and structure. In Foss, N.,

Resources, Firms and Strategies: A Reader in the Resource-Based Perspective (pp. 40-51). New York: Oxford University Press.

Chatterjee, S. & Wernerfelt, B. (1991). The link between resources and the type of diversification: Theory and evidence. Strategic Management Journal, 12(1), pp. 33-48.

Chatterjee, I., Kupper, J., Mariager, C., Moore, P. & Reis, S.

(2011). The decade ahead: Trends that will shape the consumer goods industry. McKinsey & Company

Chrisman, J., Chua, J., & Sharma, P. (2003). Current trends

and future decisions in family business management studies: Toward a theory of the family firm. Coleman White Paper Series.

Chrisman, J., Chua, J., & Kellermanns, F. (2004). A

comparative analysis of organizational capabilities of family and non-family firms. Proceedings of the Southern Management Association 2004Meeting.

Christensen, H. & Montgomery, C. (1981). Corporate

economic performance: Diversification strategy versus market structure. Strategic Management Journal. 2(4), pp. 327-343.

Chung, K., & Pruitt, S. (1994). A simple approximation of

Tobin’s q. Financial Management, 23(3), pp. 70-74. Claessens, S. & Fan, J. (2003). Corporate governance in Asia:

A survey. International Review of Finance, 3(2), pp. 71-103.

Claessens, S., Djankov, S., & Lang, L. (2000). The separation

of ownership and control in East Asian corporations. Journal of Financial Economics, 58, pp. 81–112.

Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Fan, J., & Lang, L. (2002).

Disentangling the incentive and entrenchment effects of large shareholdings. The Journal of Finance, 57(6), pp. 2741-2772.

Davis, J., Schoorman, F., & Donaldson, L. (1997). Toward a

stewardship theory of management. Academy of Management Review, 22(1), pp. 20-47.

Davis, R., & Duhaime, R. (1989). Business level data

disclosed under FASB No.14: Effective use in strategic management research. In Academy of Management Proceedings, Ed. F. Hoy. Washington: Academy of Management.

De Dios, E. S. and P. D. Hutchcroft (2003). Political

Economy. in A. S. Balisacan and H. Hill, eds, The Philippine Economy: Development, Policies, and Challenges, Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila Press.

Del Mundo, D., Kho, E., Limlingan, R., & See, J. (2007). Firm

value effects of family corporate group affiliation in the Philippines. De La Salle University, Manila, Philippines.

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 35 Denis, D.J., Denis, D.K. & Yost, K. (2002). Global

diversification, industrial diversification, and firm value. Journal of Finance, 57(5), pp. 1951-1979.

Dumlao, D. (2012). Gokongweis sell P3.2B worth of JG

Summit shares. The Philippine Daily Inquirer. Dyer, J. (2006). Examining the “family effect” on firm

performance. Family Business Review, 19(4), pp. 253-273.

Erdorf, S., Hartmann-Wendels, T., Heinrichs, N. & Matz, M.

(2012). Corporate diversification and firm value: A survey of recent literature. SSRN Working Paper.

Eshel, I., Samuelson, L., & Shaked, A. (1998). Altruists,

egoists, and hooligans in a local interaction model. The American Economic Review, 88(1), pp. 157-179.

Fama, E. & Jensen, M. (1983). Separation of ownership and

control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26(2), pp. 301-325.

Filatotchev, I., & Toms, S. (2006). Corporate governance and

financial constraints on strategic turnarounds. Journal of Management Studies, 43(3), pp. 407–433.

Gassenheimer, J., & Keep, W. (1995). The effect of

diversification on manufacturers, wholesalers, and retailers. Journal of Managerial Issues, 7(1).

Gomez-Mejia, L., Nunez-Nickel, M., & Gutierrez, I. (2001).

The role of family ties in agency contracts. Academy of Management Journal, 44(1), pp. 81-95.

Gomez-Mejia, L., Larraza-Kitana, M., & Makri, M. (2003).

The determinants of executive compensation in family-controlled public corporations. Academy of Management, 46(2), pp, 226-237.

Gomez-Mejia, L.R., Makri, M. & Kintana, M.L. (2007).

Diversification decisions in family-controlled firms. Journal of Management Studies, 47 (2), pp. 223-252.

Gorton, G. & Schmid, F. (1996). Universal banking and the

performance of German firms. NBER Working Paper. Graham, J., Lemmon, M., & Wolf, J. (2002). Does corporate

diversification destroy value?. The Journal of Finance, 57(2), pp. 695-720.

Greene, W. H. (2000). Econometric analysis (4th ed.)Upper Saddle River. NJ: Prentice Hall.

Gutierrez, B. & Rodriguez, R. (2013). Diversification

strategies of large business groups in the Philippines. Philippine Management Review, 20, pp. 65-82.

Hall, B. (1987). The relationship between firm size and firm growth in the US manufacturing sector. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), pp. 583-606.

Hall, E. (1995). Corporate diversification and performance:

An investigation of causality. Australian Journal of Management, 20(1), pp. 25-42.

Hart, P.E. (1971). Entropy and Other Measures of

Concentration. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society,134, pp. 73-85.

Hillier, D. & McColgan, P. (2005). Firm Performance,

entrenchment and managerial succession in family firms. University of Aberdeen Working Paper.

Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Johnson, R. A., & Moesel,D. D.

(1993). Construct validity of an objective (entropy) categorical measure of diversification strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 14(3), pp. 215–235.

Ingoldsby, B., Smith, S. & Miller, J.E. (2004). Exploring

family theories. Los Angeles, CA: Roxbury. Jensen, M. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate

finance, and takeovers. American Economic Review, 76(2), pp. 323-329.

Jensen, M. & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm:

Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), pp. 305-360.

Jensen, M. & Murphy, K. (1990). Performance pay and top-

management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2), pp. 225-264.

Kachaner, N., Stalk, G., & Bloch, A. (2012). What you can

learn from family business. Harvard Business Review. pp. 103-106

Karra, N., Tracey, P. & Phillips, N. (2006). Altruism and

agency in the family firm: Exploring the role of family, kinship, and ethnicity. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 30 (6), pp. 861-877.

Kim, E. & McConnel, J. (1977). Corporate mergers and the

co-insurance of corporate debt. The Journal of Finance, 32(2), pp. 349-365.

Kranenburg, H., Hagedoorn, J., & Pennings, J. (2004).

Measurement of international and product diversification in the publishing industry. The Journal of Media Economics, 17(2), pp. 87-104.

Kuppuswamy, V. & Villalonga, B. (2010). Does

diversification create value in the presence of external financing constraints? Evidence from the 2007-2009 financial crisis. Working Paper, Harvard Business School Finance.

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 36 La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (1999).

Corporate ownership around the world. The Journal of Finance, 54(2), pp. 471-517.

La Rocca, M. & Stagliano, R. (2012). Unrelated

diversification and firm performance: 1980-2007 evidence from Italy. Australian Accounting Business and Finance Journal, 6(1), pp. 75-82.

Lang, L. & Stulz, R. (1994). Tobin’s q, corporate

diversification and firm performance. Journal of Political Economy, 102, pp. 1248-80.

Le, S. A., Walters, B., & Kroll, M. (2006). The moderating

effects of external monitors on the relationship between R&D spending and firm performance. Journal of Business Research, 59(2), pp. 278–287.

Lee, D., & Tompkins, J. (1999). A modified version of the

Lewellen and Badrinath measure of Tobin’s q. Financial Management, 28(1), pp.20-31.

Levine, R. (2004). The corporate governance of banks: A

concise discussion of concepts and evidence. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series (3404).

Lewellen, W. (1971). A pure financial rationale for the

conglomerate merger. American Finance Association, 26(2), pp. 521-537.

Lien, Y.C., & Li, S. (2013). Does diversification add firm

value in emerging economies? Effect of corporate governance. Journal of Business Research, 6, pp. 2425-2430.

Lin, X., Zhang, Y., & Zhu, N. (2009). Does bank ownership

increase firm value? Evidence from China. Journal of International Money and Finance, 28(4), pp. 720-737.

Lindenberg, E., & Ross, S. (1981). Tobin’s q ratio and

industrial organization. The Journal of Business, 54(1), pp. 1-32.

Loderer, C. & Waelchli, U. (2010). Firm age and performance.

MPRA Working Paper. Lubatkin, M., Durand, R., & Ling, Y. (2007). The missing

lens in family firm governance theory: A self-other typology of parental altruism. Journal of Business Research, 60, pp. 1022-1029.

Majd, S. & Meyers, S. (1987). Tax asymmetries and corporate

income tax reform. University of Chicago Press, pp. 93-96.

Majumdar, S. (1997). The impact of size and age on firm-level

performance: Some evidence from India. Review of Industrial Organization, 12, pp. 231-241.

Maksimovic, V. & Phillips, G. (2013). Conglomerate firms, internal capital markets and the theory of the firm. SSRN Working Paper.

Mansfield, E. (1962). Entry, Gibrat’s law, innovation, and the

growth of firms. The American Economic Review, 52(5), pp. 1023-1051.

Marinelli, F. (2011). The relationship between diversification

and firm’s performance: is there really a causal relatioknship? IESE Business School- University of Navarra Working Paper.

Markides, C. (1992). Consequences of corporate refocusing:

Ex ante evidence. Academy of Management Journal, 33(2), pp. 398-412.

Markides, C. (1995). Diversification, restructuring and

economic performance. Strategic Management Journal, 16(2), pp. 101-118.

Markides, C. (1997). To diversify or not to diversify. Harvard

Business Review, pp. 93-99.

Markides, C. & Williamson, P. (1996). Corporate diversification and organizational structure: A resource-based view. Academy of Management Journal, 39(2), pp. 340-367.

Martin, J. D., & Sayrak, A. (2003). Corporate diversification

and shareholder value: A survey of recent literature. Journal of Corporate Finance, 9(1), pp. 37–57.

Matsusaka, J. (2001). Corporate diversification, value maximization, and organizational capabilities. Journal of Business, 74 (3), pp. 409-431.

Meyer, M., Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1992). Organizational prospects, influence costs, and ownership changes. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 1(1), pp. 9-35.

Montealegre, K. (2013). ‘Danding’ sees fruits of San Miguel

diversification in 5-6 years. Interaksyon News. Montgomery, C. (1982). The measurement of firm

diversification. Academy of Management Journal, 25, pp. 299-307.

Montgomery, C. (1994). Corporate diversification. Journal of

Economic Perspectives, 8(3), pp. 163-178. Morck, R. &Yeung, B. (2003a). Agency problems in large

family business groups. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 27(4), pp. 367-382.

Morck, R. & Yeung, B. (2003b). Family control and rent-

seeking society. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, forthcoming.

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 37 Morck, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1988). Management

ownership and market evaluation: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 20, pp. 293–315.

Morck, R., Stangeland, D., & Yeung, B. (1998). Inherited wealth, corporate control and economic growth. The William Davidson Institute Working Paper

Morck,R., Wolfenzon, D., & Yeung, B. (2005). Corporate

governance, economic entrenchment and growth. Journal of Economic Literature, 43(3), pp. 655-720.

Noe, T. (2012). Blood and money: Kin altruism and the

governance of the family firm. SSRN Working Papers. Ogishima, S. & Kobayashi, T. (2002). Cross-shareholdings

and equity valuation in Japan. The Security Analysts Association of Japan.

Padilla, A. & Kreptul, A. (2004). Government regulation,

unintended consequences, and the rise of omnipotent management. Ludwig Von Mises Institute Working Papers.

Pandya, A. & Rao, V. (1998). Diversification and firm

performance: An empirical evaluation. Journal of Financial and Strategic Decisions, 11(2), pp. 67-81.

Peng, M. & Jiang, Y. (2010). Institutions behind family

ownership and control in large firms. Journal of Management Studies, 47(2), pp. 253-273.

Pils, F. (2009). Diversification, relatedness, and performance

(pp. 11-25). Germany: Gabler. Rajan, R., Servaes, H. & Zingales, L. (2000). The cost of

diversity: The diversification discount and inefficient investment. Journal of Finance, 55(1), pp. 35-80.

Rajan, R., Servaes, H., & Zingales, L. (2004). The cost of

diversity: The diversification discount and inefficient investment. The Journal of Finance, 54(1), pp. 35-80.

Randoy, T., Jenssen, J., & Goel, S. (2003). Family firms and

good corporate governance: Altruism and agency considerations. Agder Maritime Research Foundation.

Saldaña, C. G. (2001). The Philippines. in Z. Zhuang et al.,

eds., Corporate Governance and Finance in East Asia, Vol 2, Manila: Asian Development Bank.

Sarkar, J. & Sarkar, S. (2000). Large shareholder activism in

corporate governance in developing countries: Evidence from India. International Review of Finance, 1(3), pp. 161-194.

Schulze, W.S., Lubatkin, M.H. & Dino, R.N. (2003). Toward

a theory of agency and altruism in family firms. Journal of Business Venturing, 18 (4), pp. 473-491.

Seth, A. & Dastidar, P. (2009). Institutions, the theory of the firm and value creation: Evidence from acquisition activity. Working Paper.

Sharma, P., Chrisman, J. J., & Chua, J. H. (2003). Succession

planning as planned behavior: Some empirical results. Family Business Review, 16(1), pp. 1–15.

Shleifer, A. & Vishny, R.W. (1989). Management

entrenchment: The case of manager-specific investments. Journal of Financial Economics, 25(1), pp. 123-139.

Shleifer, A. &Vishny, R.W. (1997). A survey of corporate

governance. NBER Working Paper. Singh, A. & Whittington, G. (1975). The size and growth of

firms. Oxford University Press, 42(1), pp. 15-26. Stafford, K., Duncan, K., Dane, S. & Winter, M. (1999). A

research model of sustainable family businesses. Family Business Review, 12, pp. 197-208.

Stein, J. (1997). Internal capital markets and the competition

for corporate resources. NBER Working Paper Series. Stulz, R. (1988). Managerial control of voting rights:

Financing policies and the market for corporate control. Journal of Financial Economics, 20, pp. 25-54.

Tallman, S., & Li, J. T. (1996). The effects of international

diversity and product diversity on the performance of multinational firms. Academy of Management Journal, 39(1), pp. 179–196.

Tan, J. (2009). An investigation of corporate leadership

succession planning and implementation: The Malaysian experience. Massey University.

Ungson, G., Steers, R. & Park, S. (1997). Korean enterprise:

The quest for globalization. Boston: Harvard School Press.

Unite, A., Sullivan, M., Brookman, J., Majadillas, M., &

Taningco, A. (2008). Executive pay and firm performance in the Philippines. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 16(5), pp. 606-623.

Verbeek, M. (2000). A guide to modern econometrics. Baffins

Lane, Chichester, West Sussex, England: John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

Villalonga, B. (2004). Diversification discount or premium?

New evidence from the business information tracking series. Journal of Finance, 59(2), 479-506.

Ward, J. (1997). Growing the family business: Special

challenges and best practices. Family Business Review, 10(4), pp. 323-337.

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 38 Westhead, P. & Cowling, M. (1996). Management and

ownership issues in family and non-family companies. Warwick Business School Small and Medium Sized Enterprise Centre Working Papers.

Wiseman, R.M. & Gomez-Mejia, L.R. (1998). A behavioral

agency model of managerial risk-taking. Academy of Management Review, 23, pp. 133-153.

Yang, C. & Chen, K. (2009). Are small firms less efficient?

Small Business Economics, 32, pp. 375-395.

Young, M., Peng, M., Ahlstrom, D., Bruton, G., & Jiang, Y. (2008). Corporate governance in emerging economies: A review of the principal-principal perspective. Journal of Management Studies, 45(1), pp. 196-220.

Zhan, E. (2007). Does property insurance increase firm value.

BI Norwegian School, Oslo, Norway. Zhu, Y., Tian, G., & Zhao, S. (2010). How does the separation

of ownership and control affect corporate performance: The impact of earnings management in China. The 23rd Australian Finance and Banking Conference, pp. 1-34.

Impact of Family Altruism on Corporate Diversification: Does Entrenching on the Legacy Create Firm Value? 39

APPENDIX

A. Multicollinearity Diagnostic Test (Variance Inflation Factor)

Table A1. Variance Inflation Factors of Models (A), (B), and (C) Regressors [Entropy (PDT) index]

Random Effects Panel Data Estimation on the Effects of Total Diversification,

Unrelated Diversification, and Related Diversification on Firm Value

DIVERSE UNREDIV RELADIV

Control Variables

FIRMAGE 1.02 1.02 1.03

FRMSIZE 1.10 1.06 1.12

CONSUMR 1.03 1.04 1.02

Diversification Extent

DIVERSEPDT 1.07

UNREDIVPDT 1.04

RELADIVPDT 1.07

Ownership Characteristics

FAMICON 1.03 1.03 1.03

BANKOWN 1.03 1.03 1.03

Number of Observations: 565

Number of Firms: 113

Table A2. Variance Inflation Factors of Models (A), (B), and (C) Regressors [Berry-Herfindahl (BH index)]

Random Effects Panel Data Estimation on the Effects of Total Diversification, Unrelated Diversification, and Related Diversification on Firm Value

DIVERSE UNREDIV RELADIV Control Variables

FIRMAGE 1.02 1.02 1.03

FRMSIZE 1.09 1.06 1.11

CONSUMR 1.03 1.04 1.02

Diversification Extent

DIVERSEBH 1.06

UNREDIVBH 1.04

RELADIVBH 1.06

Ownership Characteristics

FAMICON 1.03 1.03 1.03

BANKOWN 1.03 1.03 1.03

Number of Observations: 565

Number of Firms: 113