GERMAN, EC AND U.S. MERGER CONTROL - CiteSeerX

111
COORDINATED EFFECTS AND COLLECTIVE DOMINANCE - A COMPARISON OF GERMAN, EC AND U.S. MERGER CONTROL Working Paper Thorsten Kaeseberg, M.A. (Economics) Humboldt-University Berlin email: [email protected] First draft: August 2002 Final version: January 2003

Transcript of GERMAN, EC AND U.S. MERGER CONTROL - CiteSeerX

COORDINATED EFFECTS AND COLLECTIVE DOMINANCE -

A COMPARISON OF

GERMAN, EC AND U.S. MERGER CONTROL

Working Paper

Thorsten Kaeseberg, M.A. (Economics)

Humboldt-University Berlin

email: [email protected]

First draft: August 2002

Final version: January 2003

2

CONTENTS

1 INTRODUCTION ....................................................................................... 81.1 Focus of the paper ............................................................................................. 9

1.2 Reasons for the paper ........................................................................................ 10

2 STATIC OLIGOPOLY THEORIES, UNILATERAL EFFECTS

AND SINGLE DOMINANCE ....................................................................... 112.1 Cournot oligopoly model with homogeneous products

- Merger implications ....................................................................................... 11

2.1.1 Cournot-Nash equilibrium ...................................................................... 11

2.1.2 Consumer surplus ................................................................................... 12

2.1.3 Rationale for efficiency defence ............................................................ 12

2.1.4 Producer surplus and overall welfare ..................................................... 13

2.1.5 Rationale for using the HHI and �HHI .................................................. 13

2.1.6 Rationale for using market shares .......................................................... 14

2.1.7 Distortions in EC merger control? ......................................................... 14

2.1.8 The relationship between unilateral and coordinated effects -

an extension of the Cournot model ........................................................ 15

2.2 Bertrand oligopoly model with differentiated products

- Merger implications ...................................................................................... 16

2.2.1 Pre-merger equilibrium .......................................................................... 16

2.2.2 Post-merger equilibrium ......................................................................... 17

2.3 A two-step approach for assessing unilateral and coordinated effects ............. 17

2.4 Repeated interaction as necessary condition for collusion ............................... 18

3 DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY THEORIES, COORDINATED EFFECTS AND

COLLECTIVE DOMINANCE ...................................................................... 193.1 The theory of repeated games ........................................................................... 20

3.1.1 Finitely repeated oligopoly games ......................................................... 20

3.1.2 Infinitely repeated oligopoly games (supergames)

3

with perfect information ........................................................................ 21

3.1.2.1 The basic model ........................................................................... 21

3.1.2.2 Equilibria ..................................................................................... 22

3.1.2.3 The Folk theorem ......................................................................... 22

3.1.2.4 The coordination problem ............................................................ 23

3.1.2.4.1 Explicit vs. tacit collusion ................................................. 23

3.1.2.4.2 Focal points and cheap talk ............................................... 23

3.1.3 Punishment strategies and renegotiation-proofness ............................... 24

3.2 Merger implications .......................................................................................... 25

3.2.1 Collusive effects of a merger ................................................................. 25

3.2.1.1 Reduction of number of firms ...................................................... 25

3.2.1.1.1 Coordination and monitoring - the "dinner party story" ... 26

3.2.1.1.2 Enforcement ...................................................................... 26

3.2.1.2 More symmetric distribution of assets ......................................... 27

3.2.1.2.1 Coordination and monitoring ............................................ 27

3.2.1.2.2 Enforcement ...................................................................... 28

3.2.1.2.3 A Trade-off ........................................................................ 28

3.2.1.2.4 The case of capacity constraints - the model of

Compte, Jenny and Rey .................................................... 29

3.2.1.2.4.1 The results of the model ......................................... 29

3.2.1.2.4.2 Application to Nestlé / Perrier ................................ 31

3.2.1.2.5 Policy implications ............................................................ 31

3.2.1.3 Loss of a maverick or reducing its incentive to compete ............ 32

3.2.1.3.1 Identifying a maverick ...................................................... 32

3.2.1.3.2 Merger scenarios ............................................................... 33

3.2.2 Comparative institutional analysis ......................................................... 34

3.2.2.1 Merger control and the prohibition of collusion as

(imperfect) substitutes ................................................................ 34

3.2.2.2 Comparative cost-benefit-analysis ............................................... 34

3.3 Other approaches to collusion ........................................................................... 35

3.3.1 Truly dynamic models ............................................................................ 36

3.3.1.1 Tangible industry conditions ....................................................... 37

3.3.1.2 Intangible industry conditions (beliefs) ....................................... 37

4

3.3.2 Evolutionary game theory ...................................................................... 38

3.3.2.1 Tit for tat as evolutionary stable strategy .................................... 38

3.3.2.2 Implications for merger policy .................................................... 39

3.4 Necessary conditions for collusion ................................................................... 40

3.4.1 "Few" firms - is there a "magic" number? ............................................. 40

3.4.1.1 Selten's "four are few and six are many" ..................................... 40

3.4.1.2 Renegotiation-proofness as binding constraint ............................ 42

3.4.2 Barriers to entry/exit and expansion ...................................................... 42

3.4.2.1 Barriers to entry/exit: prevention of hit-and-run competition ..... 43

3.4.2.2 Barriers to expansion: prevention of

competitive pressure by fringe firms ........................................... 43

3.5 Market characteristics corresponding to the necessary conditions ................... 43

3.5.1 No large and lumpy orders ..................................................................... 45

3.5.2 Homogeneous products .......................................................................... 45

3.5.3 Market transparency ............................................................................... 46

3.5.3.1 Supergames with imperfect information ..................................... 46

3.5.3.2 Empiric evidence ......................................................................... 47

3.5.4 Stable demand conditions (low rate of change in market size

and low degree of innovation) ............................................................... 48

3.5.4.1 Market size ........................................................................... 48

3.5.4.2 Innovation ............................................................................ 48

3.5.5 Low buyer power ................................................................................... 49

3.5.6 Low price elasticity in the sub-market composed of

the leading firms' products ..................................................................... 49

3.5.7 Multi-market contact .............................................................................. 50

3.5.8 Excess capacity ...................................................................................... 50

3.6 Facilitating practices and structural links ......................................................... 51

3.6.1 Facilitating practices .............................................................................. 51

3.6.2 Structural links ....................................................................................... 52

3.7 Evidence of current coordination ...................................................................... 52

3.8 Relative importance of the market characteristics ............................................ 54

3.9 Policy implications ........................................................................................... 54

5

4 COLLECTIVE DOMINANCE IN GERMAN MERGER CONTROL ...................... 564.1 GWB (Act against Restraints of Competition) ................................................. 56

4.1.1 The definition of collective dominance .................................................. 57

4.1.2 Legal constructions and economic meanings ......................................... 57

4.2 Guidelines for Merger Control Procedures ("Auslegungsgrundsätze")

4.2.1 Underlying economics ............................................................................ 58

4.2.2 Three-step approach ............................................................................... 59

4.2.2.1 Internal competition

("Wettbewerbsbedingungen - Binnenwettbewerb") .................... 59

4.2.2.2 External competition

("Wettbewerbsbedingungen - Aussenwettbewerb") .................... 59

4.2.2.3 Conduct ("Wettbewerbsgeschehen") ............................................ 60

4.2.3 Checklist and case law ........................................................................... 61

4.2.3.1 Concentration and market shares ................................................. 61

4.2.3.2 Symmetry ..................................................................................... 62

4.2.3.3 Ressources and vertical up- and downstream integration ............ 63

4.2.3.4 Structural links ............................................................................. 63

4.2.3.5 Barriers to entry ........................................................................... 64

4.2.3.6 Buyer power on the opposite side of the market ......................... 64

4.2.3.7 Market transparency and homogeneity ........................................ 65

4.2.3.8 Market phase ................................................................................ 65

4.2.4 Comparison with economic framework ................................................. 65

4.3 Cases ................................................................................................................. 66

4.3.1 RWE / VEW ........................................................................................... 66

4.3.1.1 Findings ....................................................................................... 66

4.3.1.2 Remedies ...................................................................................... 67

4.3.2 Shell / DEA ............................................................................................ 68

5 COLLECTIVE DOMINANCE IN EC MERGER CONTROL ............................. 705.1 Development - from Nestlé / Perrier to Airtours / First Choice ....................... 71

5.1.1 Nestlé / Perrier (1991) ............................................................................ 72

5.1.2 Kali&Salz / MdK (1993, 1998) .............................................................. 73

5.1.3 Gencor / Lonrho (1996, 1999) ................................................................ 73

6

5.1.4 Airtours / First Choice (1999, 2002) ...................................................... 74

5.1.4.1 The Commission's decision (1999) – shifting the goalposts ....... 74

5.1.4.2 Critique and interpretation - "collective confusion" .................... 76

5.1.4.2.1 Unilateral effects in a collective dominance case ............. 76

5.1.4.2.2 Interpretation: distortions in EC merger control ............... 77

5.1.4.2.3 Solutions to eliminate the distortions ................................ 78

5.1.4.3 The CFI's ruling (2002) - shifting back and

cementing the goalposts ............................................................ 79

5.1.4.3.1 Necessary conditions for coordination .............................. 79

5.1.4.3.2 Market characteristics ....................................................... 80

5.1.4.3.2.1 Product homogeneity .............................................. 80

5.1.4.3.2.2 Market transparency ............................................... 80

5.1.4.3.3 Implications for future policy ............................................ 81

5.1.5 UPM-Kymmene/Haindl and Norske Skog/Parenco/Walsum

(2001): coordination on other parameters than price or output? -

the case of capacity coordination ............................................................ 81

5.2 Approach to collective dominance ................................................................... 82

5.2.1 Identification of oligopolists and initial screening test .......................... 83

5.2.2 Structural market characteristics ............................................................ 83

5.2.2.1 Homogeneous goods .................................................................... 84

5.2.2.2 Market transparency .................................................................... 84

5.2.2.3 Mature market .............................................................................. 84

5.2.2.4 Low rate of product and/or process innovation ........................... 85

5.2.2.5 Symmetry of costs and market shares ......................................... 85

5.2.2.6 Structural links ............................................................................. 86

5.2.2.7 Other factors ................................................................................ 86

5.2.3 Impact of the merger .............................................................................. 87

5.2.3.1 Past level of competition ............................................................. 87

5.2.3.2 Impact of merger on competition between the oligopolists ......... 88

5.2.4 External competitive constraints on the oligopoly ................................. 88

5.2.4.1 Competitors ................................................................................. 88

5.2.4.1.1 Fringe firms and mavericks ............................................... 88

5.2.4.1.2 Potential competitors ......................................................... 88

7

5.2.4.2 Buyer power ................................................................................. 89

5.3 The future after Airtours: Merger Guidelines ................................................... 90

6 COORDINATED EFFECTS IN U.S. MERGER CONTROL .............................. 916.1 Difference in substance: the SLC test ............................................................... 91

6.2 Difference in procedure: ex-ante review .......................................................... 92

6.3 The role of concentration .................................................................................. 93

6.4 Coordinated effects under the 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines ................. 94

6.4.1 Market factors ........................................................................................ 94

6.4.2 Relating the market factors to the

necessary conditions of coordination ..................................................... 95

6.4.3 Evidence of prior or current coordination .............................................. 95

6.4.4 Analysis of entry .................................................................................... 96

6.4.5 The relationship between coordinated and unilateral effects ................. 96

6.5 Cases ................................................................................................................. 97

6.5.1 Union Pacific / Southern Pacific ............................................................ 97

6.5.2 Heinz / Beech-Nut .................................................................................. 98

7 COMPARISON, POLICY SUGGESTIONS AND

LOOK INTO THE FUTURE ......................................................................... 1007.1 'Soft' convergence ............................................................................................. 100

7.2 Differences and resulting suggestions for reform ............................................. 102

7.3 The European Commission's proposals for a reform of EC merger control ..... 103

7.3.1 Single dominance: one undertaking having market power

without coordinating .............................................................................. 103

7.3.2 Collective dominance: more undertakings having market power

with coordinating (collusive oligopolies) .................................................... 103

7.3.3 More undertakings having market power without coordinating

(non-collusive oligopolies) ..................................................................... 104

7.3.4 'Hard' convergence ................................................................................. 105

8

1 INTRODUCTION

"The ultimate issue in reviewing a merger under the antitrust laws ... is whether the challenged acquisition is

likely to hurt consumers, as by making it easier for the firms in the market to collude, expressly or tacitly, and

thereby force prices above or farther above the competitive level."

Richard Posner (1986)1

Horizontal mergers2 can have two distinct types of effects: The first type, called unilateral

effects both in economics and in U.S. merger control, arises from reduced mutual

interdependence in an oligopolistic market after the merger: Absent cost synergies due to the

merger and absent barriers to entry, the merged entity will raise prices (or suppress output)

because part of the cost of the price increase (or output decrease), from lost sales, is

internalised by the acquisition of the competitor. Moreover, the remaining competitors might

find it profitable in certain circumstances to respond by raising their price in turn. Hence,

even if all firms increase their prices following the merger, this is still strictly a unilateral

effect because it arises from inherently self-enforcing behaviour without any form of

coordination. Methodically, this outcome of mergers can be associated with non-cooperative

Nash equilibria in one-shot games (see section 2 below). In German and EC merger control,

concerns about price increases by the merged entity are captured under the concept of single

dominance if the merged firm's market power would allow it to "determine its policy [to a

certain degree] free from competitive restraint".3

Second, a horizontal merger might enable the remaining firms to do better than simply adapt

independently to the new environment, as hinted at by Posner's statement above: In

particular by leading to a more concentrated market, by making oligopolists more symmetric

or by removing a maverick firm, the merger might increase the scope for the remaining firms

to exercise market power collectively by coordinating their actions. Hence, due to the

merger, prices can increase above the one-shot Nash equilibrium level since firms are more

1 Case Hospital Corporation of America v. FTC, 807 F.2d 1381, 1386 (7th Cir. 1986).2 The other two types of mergers, vertical and conglomerate, have different effects, e. g. foreclosure and

portfolio effects.3 See the ECJ's definition of a dominant position in the Article 82 case 27/76, United Brands Company v.

Commission (1978) ECR 207. The Commission also applies this definition for the purpose of the MergerRegulation. The question whether there is a relevant difference between the economics of unilateral effectsand the legal definition of "single firm dominance" will be addressed below (2.1.7).

9

likely to attain - expressly or tacitly - a collusive outcome. This consequence of a merger

falls under the category of coordinated effects (or cooperative or pro-collusive effects) in the

U.S. and joint or collective or oligopolistic dominance4 respectively in Germany and the EC.

For collusion to work, there must be some mechanism in place to defeat its natural instability

arising from the incentive for each firm to undercut rivals and thus benefit privately from

their price increases, i. e. a mechanism to overcome the static non-cooperative Nash

equilibria in a prisoner's dilemma situation. In the context of dynamic competition in the

sense of repeated interaction of firms, this mechanism is provided for by (the possibility of)

punishment in the case of defection from the explicit or implicit agreement, and is

formalized by the theory of repeated games (see section 3).

1.1 Focus of the paper

From the above (non-Schumpeterian) welfare perspective, a complete merger framework

would have to balance unilateral and coordinated effects against efficiencies arising from the

merger. This is beyond the scope of this thesis. The focus will be on coordinated effects, in

particular on, first, the necessary conditions for coordination derived from the theory of

repeated games and, second, on the market factors which feed into these conditions. Both

conditions and market factors make up a normative framework for the assessment of

coordinated effects (see section 3 below). Before, unilateral effects will be explained shortly

to allow for a clear distinction of unilateral and coordinated effects and to determine their

relationship (section 2).

Moreover, to cope with the phenomenon "coordinated effects", there are several regulatory

instruments provided for in nearly every competition regime. They can be grouped into ex

ante regulation (merger control) and ex post regulation (in particular the prohibition of

horizontal restrictions of competition). Hence, defining a coherent policy towards

coordinated effects would require a comparative institutional5 cost-benefit-analysis of the

different instruments which would have to take into account, inter alia, different error costs.

This analysis is only alluded very briefly. The focus will be on merger control.

4 These terms are used synonymously.5 "Institution" in the sense of a set of rules and the instruments to implement them (see Richter/Furubotn

(1999), p. 7).

10

1.2 Reasons for the paper

Due to increasingly concentrated oligopolistic markets, the assessment of coordinated effects

by competition authorities within a merger control procedure becomes increasingly

important: For example half of the phase 2 (i. e. in-depth) investigations of the EC

Commission's Merger Task Force involve questions of collective dominance. In the U.S.,

preventing from coordinated effects has long been the main target of merger policy. Hence,

from a public policy perspective, it seems worth to compare the existing (i. e. positive)

merger control regimes with the normative framework derived from game theory. This

comparison, which will be carried out separately for German, EC and U.S. merger control

(sections 4-6), allows to criticize (and potentially improve) actual policy.

Aside from this reason for exploring merger policy towards coordinated effects for each of

the three merger regimes, there is an additional benefit from comparing different merger

control regimes with each other: Due to increasing communication between competition

authorities,6 there is a high probability of mutual learning and, consequently, convergence of

competition policies. Hence, the comparative approach allows to predict into which

directions the different merger control regimes will develop and where they will probably

converge to (section 7).

6 There are contacts between competition authorities, inter alia, on the level of global institutions (e. g. the

OECD or the International Competition Network) or in the context of global merger cases (these case-specific contacts are also to some extent institutionalised, see e. g. the respective EC-U.S. agreement).

11

2 STATIC OLIGOPOLY THEORIES, UNILATERAL EFFECTS AND

SINGLE DOMINANCE

"If I was Director-General of DG IV, I would be very happy if my policy induced the firms under investigation

to end up in a Cournot equilibrium."

L. Phlips, Applied Industrial Economics (1995)

In our context, static oligopoly theories (Cournot and Bertrand) serve four functions: First,

they give a rationale for merger control to target unilateral effects due to horizontal mergers.

Second, they explain why there might be a gap in those merger regimes which use

dominance tests (with a market share threshold). Third, as alluded by the introductory

quotation of Phlips (1995, p. 11), their equilibria serve as non-collusive benchmarks in the

sense of what would happen in a market without coordination. Fourth, they allow to

distinguish clearly and explain the relationship between unilateral and coordinated effects.

2.1 Cournot oligopoly model with homogeneous products - Merger implications

In static games, unilateral effects of a merger can be formalized by comparing the pre- and

the post-merger equilibrium.

2.1.1 Cournot-Nash equilibrium

The Nash equilibrium in a market with quantity-setting firms selling homogeneous goods

can be described by the Cournot oligopoly pricing formula. It shows the relationship

between the ratio between the profit margin and the price (Lerner index), the firm's market

share si�xi/X and the elasticity of demand �>0 at overall equilibrium demand X:

ii sXp

cXp�

)()(

. (1)

Apart from the basic Cournot oligopoly results (each firm recognizes that it possesses

(limited) market power and that the Cournot equilibrium is somewhere "in between" perfect

competition and the monopoly solution), the formula shows that the relative mark-up is

proportional to a firm's market share and inversely proportional to the elasticity of demand.

12

Moreover, the market share of the firms are directly related to their efficiencies (constant

marginal cost ci).

2.1.2 Consumer surplus

Incorporating the Herfindahl-Hirschman index of concentration (HHI)7

H � ��

n

iis

1

2

into the Cournot oligopoly pricing formula8 gives the following relationship:

p

scpn

iii )(

1��

= �

H . (2)

This suggests that with higher concentration due to a merger, mark-ups increase for a given

level of costs, and, hence, consumer surplus decreases. The explanation for this is that,

according to the Cournot model, the quantity produced by the merged firm following the

merger will be lower than the sum of the quantities produced by its parts before the merger

raising the market price. Stimulated by widened margins, the outsiders will - absent capacity

constraints - increase their outputs. However, this response by the non-merging firms will

always only partly offset the reduction in output by the merged entity, with the net effect that

all Cournot mergers in homogeneous goods markets - absent cost synergies - result in lower

total output, higher prices overall and, hence, lower consumer surplus.

2.1.3 Rationale for efficiency defence

If the merger allows for cost synergies, e. g. - statically - due the exploitation of economies

of scale and/or the amalgamation of overhead functions or - dynamically - due to learning

effects or increased potential for innovation, prices do not necessarily rise. This is the

rationale for an efficiency defence like the one explicitly provided for in the U.S. Merger

Guidelines which in particular recognize efficiencies which flow from the attainment of

scale economies, better integration of production facilities, plant specialisation and lower

transport costs. Under the Guidelines, efficiencies are cognizable if they are verified, merger

specific, and not a disguised anticompetitive effect.9

7 The HHI varies between 0, when the market is entirely fragmented (each firm has a market share close to

0), and 10.000, when there is only one firm in the industry with 100% of the market.8 By multiplying both sides of equation (1) by si and summing over all i.

13

2.1.4 Producer surplus and overall welfare

The effect on producer surplus and, hence, on overall welfare is more difficult to determine:

For symmetric firms (i.e. firms with equal cost functions), Bergstrom and Varian (1985)

show a positive relationship between the number of firms in the market and overall welfare.

However, this does not hold for firms with different cost functions.

Farrell and Shapiro (1990, p. 342), for instance, show that - with costs unchanged - the

overall welfare effect depends on the relative cost structures of the merging and non-merging

parts, and hence on the reallocation of output between these firms: in Cournot equilibrium,

larger firms have lower marginal costs, thus overall welfare is enhanced despite increased

concentration if a fixed total output X is shifted towards them away from smaller, less

efficient firms. Thus, although Cournot mergers, absent cost synergies, necessarily raise

prices and reduce consumer surplus, they may enhance total welfare nonetheless.

However, transferring production from a high-cost plant to a low-cost plant is not a

convincing efficiency since such a transfer can be achieved without a merger. Thus, such a

welfare gain is not merger specific in the sense of the U.S. Guidelines.

2.1.5 Rationale for using the HHI and �HHI

Equation (2) provides a direct link between concentration measured by the HHI and

unilateral effects: Mergers in already highly concentrated markets and/or which substantially

increase concentration should cause more concern with respect to a reduction in consumer

surplus than in the case of fragmented markets and/or a negligible changes in concentration.

Hence, the Cournot framework gives a rationale for using the HHI and a change in HHI as

screening devices for unilateral effects of mergers as they are used under the U.S. Merger

Guidelines.10

9 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, Section 4 (revised 1997).10 However, in markets in which products are differentiated either by virtue of their characteristics or by

strong branding, market shares can provide an unreliable guide to the possible extent of any unilateraleffects. In such cases it is often more informative to directly assess the proportion of each of the mergingfirms' customers who would have switched to the other merging firm's products following a price rise('diversion ratios').

14

Table 1.1:

Safe harbours for mergers under the 1992 U.S. Horizontal Merger Guidelines11

safe unsafe unsafe

safe safe unsafePost- 1800merger

HHI 1000safe safe safe

0 50 100

Increase in HHI

However, in the case of coordinated effects, the HHI has to be used with caution: First, the

HHI "punishes" asymmetry. This has to be kept in mind when discussing the role of

symmetry of firms for coordinated effects. Second, the link between concentration and

coordinated effects is a more indirect one than between concentration and unilateral effects

(see below 3.2.1.1).

2.1.6 Rationale for using market shares

Similarly, equation (1) rationalises the use of market shares as indicator of the likely market

power created by the merger. In single dominance cases, the European Commission regards

40% as critical threshold for the market share of the merged firm.

2.1.7 Distortions in EC merger control?

Comparing the European single dominance test with the economic framework set out so far,

Motta (1999, 2000) concludes that the European approach has two distortions which have

repercussions on the application of the concept of a collective dominant position by the

Commission and, hence, have to be analysed in our context:

First, Motta criticizes that all mergers which allow firms to unilaterally raise prices but do

not create or reinforce dominant positions cannot be prohibited.12 This critique relies on the

11 See Section 1.51: a market with a post-merger HHI below 1000 is regarded as "unconcentrated", a market

with a post-merger HHI between 1000 and 1800 as "moderately concentrated" and a market with a post-merger HHI above 1800 as "highly concentrated". The table is taken from Viscusi et al. (1995), p. 214.

15

assumption that the legal definition of "single firm dominance" as the potential for the

merged firm to "behave independently of competitors" requires more than the prognosis of a

price increase by the merged entity (i. e. unilateral effects). Second, so far, EC merger

control does not provide an efficiency defence.

With regard to the first alleged distortion, Motta's critique has to be relativized: Significant

unilateral effects can arise only if actual competitors are not able to offset the merged

entity's suppress of output (i. e. in particular, if they face capacity constraints or barriers to

expansion respectively) and if there are barriers to entry such that there is no constraint by

potential competition.13 Qualitatively, this is (already in theory) not different from the

dominance test which requires that the merged firm is not significantly constrained by its

competitors and thus can behave independently.

However, Motta's critique can also be interpreted quantitatively: The 40%-threshold creates

a gap for those cases in which, due to barriers to expansion and entry, relevant unilateral

effects arise, but in which the threshold is not met. Whether such unilateral effects are

"significant enough" and, hence, should be captured by merger control, is a normative

question outside the scope of this thesis. However, the Commission might want to capture

those cases (positive analysis). Hence, Motta's critique might provide an explanation for the

Commission's attempt to stretch the concept of collective dominance in order to capture such

unilateral effects. This will be further explored when discussing the Commission's Airtours

decision in the context of EC merger control (see below 5.1.4.2.1 and 5.1.4.2.2).

2.1.8 The relationship between unilateral and coordinated effects - an extension of the

Cournot model

Willig (1991) extends the Cournot model by integrating coordinated effects (exogenous

paramter �) and assuming the following relationship between the Lerner index and the mode

of behaviour among firms in the market:

pcp � =

�H ,

12 This critique is shared by Caffarra and Neven (2000).13 This is recognised by all competition authorities. Aside from rivals' ability to expand output (i. e. their cost

functions) and the likelihood of entry, the size of unilateral effects depends particularly on the elasticity ofdemand and the degree of countervailing buyer power.

16

where �=0 represents price taking behaviour, �=1 represents Cournot behaviour and �=1/H

pure cartel behaviour. With � rising from 1 to 1/H, mark-ups are generated which are higher

than the Cournot value. Hence, although the mode of conduct is determined exogenously and

not much can be said about the actual effects of a merger, the model highlights that unilateral

and coordinated effects are conceptually different: Assuming that pre-merger firms are not

colluding, the post-merger equilibrium is either another Cournot equilibrium if the mode of

conduct parameter (�=1) does not change, or a collusive equilibrium, characterised by �>1.

2.2 Bertrand oligopoly model with differentiated products - Merger implications

In the case of symmetric price-setting firms which produce a homogeneous product and

which are able to supply the entire market, prices converge to marginal cost ("Bertrand

paradox").14 There are two main approaches to solve the paradox which both make the

Bertrand model more realistic: First, firms can have capacity constraints or sufficiently

increasing marginal cost so that they cannot serve the entire market demand. Second, firms

can produce products that are differentiated in product or geographical space.

Both assumptions are reflected in the U.S. Horizontal Merger Guidelines which distinguish

between the setting where firms are distinguished primarily by differentiated products

(Section 2.21 of the Guidelines) and firms distinguished primarily by their capacities

(Section 2.22). Here, the focus will be on product differentiation as suggested by the practice

of the U.S. competition authorities.

2.2.1 Pre-merger equilibrium

Whereas in the Cournot model with homogeneous goods the "reaction curves" are

downwards sloping, in the Bertrand model an increase in the price charged by one firm also

induces the other firms to increase their prices, such that the price of all products in the

market are likely to rise. In this case, the reaction curves are upwards sloping.

If one of two firms which produce each other's closest substitutes in a differentiated products

market tries to raise its price, it may gain extra revenue per product sold, but it will loose

more revenue in total from the sales that are diverted to the other firm if it was originally

selling at the profit maximising price. Hence, neither firm has an incentive to raise prices

and/or reduce output.

14 See Shapiro (1989), pp. 343-348.

17

2.2.2 Post-merger equilibrium

However, if these two firms merge, the two competing products will be under common

ownership. As a result, the lost sales caused by increasing the price of one of the products

are likely to be recaptured by the merged firm, even if only partially, in the sales of the other

product. Thus, there is an incentive for the merged firm to unilaterally raise the prices of

both products. Moreover, since the reaction curves are upwards sloping, non-merging firms

may also be able to raise their prices. For competition authorities, it is very difficult to

distinguish this unilateral effect arising from oligopolistic interdependence from parallelism

due to coordination, i. e. coordinated effects, although both are theoretically clear separable.

2.3 A two-step approach for assessing unilateral and coordinated effects

Comparing pre- and post-merger equilibrium without and with collusion, builds upon the

idea that firms at one point in time face the strategic choice of either competing (in a

Cournot or Bertrand style depending on the setting) or colluding. Hence, due to this

assumption, a merger which changes the market structure, either leads to unilateral or

coordinated effects (so far, the latter are exogenously given) suggesting that competition

authorities have to deal only with one effect when assessing a merger.

However, there might be a non-static real world sequence in which the firms initially adapt

to the new environment, i. e. the immediate post-merger equilibrium is non-collusive and

there are only unilateral effects, but, particularly with subsequent learning, this may be

displaced by collusion. This sequence is not unrealistic since the non-cooperative gains from

realising increased unilateral market power as such are "certain" (only the size of the

additional profit depends on the market structure). In contrast, gains from cooperation are

uncertain since they, by definition, depend on the other oligopolists or the stability of the

(implicit) agreement respectively. Hence, a merger might possibly lead to both unilateral and

coordinated effects.

This suggests a two-step-approach:

1. An analysis of unilateral effects will show the likelihood of a significant increase in prices

even without any collusion (or of the creation or strengthening of a single dominant

position respectively).

2. If unilateral effects are negligible or unlikely, but the structure and other characteristics of

the market suggest a likelihood of collusive conduct between the remaining firms (or the

18

creation or strengthening of a collective dominant position), then an analysis of

coordinated effects should also be carried out.

2.4 Repeated interaction as necessary condition for collusion

Static oligopoly theory allowed for three main conclusions: First, one shot games provide for

a non-collusive benchmark for oligopolistic markets. Or as the introductory quote of Phlips

makes clear: The competitive Nash equilibrium of a single shot game is the best result

antitrust policy against collusion can hope for in oligopolistic markets. Second, coordinated

effects or collective dominance respectively is "more" than just oligopolistic

interdependence. Third, the collusive outcome is not a Nash equilibrium of a single-period

game since an individual firm can increase its profit by producing more output or charging a

lower price given that all other firms adhere to the collusive strategies. Hence, without

repeated interaction, there cannot be collusion.

19

3 DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY THEORIES, COORDINATED EFFECTS AND

COLLECTIVE DOMINANCE

"Successful coordinated interaction entails reaching terms of coordination that are profitable to the firms

involved and an ability to detect and punish deviations that would undermine the coordinated interaction.

Detection and punishment of deviations ensure that coordinating firms will find it more profitable to adhere to

the terms of coordination than to pursue short-term profits from deviating, given the costs of reprisal."

1992 U.S. Horizontal Merger Guidelines15

As demonstrated in section 2, static oligopoly theories cannot explain collusion due to the

lack of dynamics, i. e. repeated interaction of firms over time. However, in reality, inter alia

durable investments and barriers to entry promote long-run interactions among a relatively

stable set of firms.16 Assuming repeated interaction of a small number of identical firms

which produce a homogeneous product, Chamberlin (1933) introduced the concept of tacit

collusion:"If each seeks his maximum profit rationally and intelligently, he will realize that when there are

only two or a few sellers his own move has a considerable effect upon his competitors, and that

this makes it idle to suppose that they will accept without retaliation the losses he forces upon

them. Since the result of a cut by any one is inevitably to decrease his own profit, no one will cut,

and although the sellers are entirely independent, the equilibrium result is the same as though

there were a monopolistic agreement." (emphasis added)17

The main contribution of this statement is that it identifies the threat of retaliation as

mechanism which allows firms to gain profits above the static Nash outcome without legally

enforceable cartel agreements and even without communication. This idea has been

formalized by the theory of repeated games (see below 3.1).

However, Chamberlin's conjecture is far too optimistic about the success of collusion since it

assumes costless coordination on the monopoly outcome and perfect information, i. e.

costless monitoring of this outcome. In particular Stigler (1964) worked out factors that

hinder collusion such as unobservable price, demand shocks and buyer power as they relate

to the ability of firms to find, monitor and enforce a collusive equilibrium. Given these

15 Section 2.1 ("Lessening of Competition Through Coordinated Interaction").16 Tirole (1998), p. 239.17 Chamberlin (1933), p. 48.

20

necessary conditions of collusion, coordination is potentially more sinister than unilateral

exercise of market power (it results in welfare losses in terms of lower output, higher prices,

X-inefficiency, slower innovation, and reduced product variety), but also less frequent.

In order to design a merger policy which shall prevent coordination that would arise due to a

merger (coordinated effects), it is necessary to understand how a merger alters firms'

incentives to collude (3.2). These incentives depend, as the introductory quotation from the

U.S. Merger Guidelines suggests, on the relative gains of coordination which, in turn,

depend on market factors like those already identified by Stigler. Hence, a normative merger

framework has to derive the conditions for collusion from firms' incentives (3.4) and to

relate these conditions to those factors which render a market conducive to coordination

(3.5).

3.1 The theory of repeated games

Since the 1980s, the theory of repeated games has become the main tool for modelling the

mechanism of collusion. The various models differ in several dimensions:

- the number of periods in the game (finitely/infinitely; see 3.1.1 and 3.3.1.2),

- the punishment strategies (3.1.3),

- the information available to players (perfect/imperfect; infra 3.5.3.1), and

- the way in which players form beliefs about each other and each other's strategies

(3.3.1.2).

Generally, collusion is the more difficult to sustain the more realistic assumptions the model

makes (e. g. imperfect information).

3.1.1 Finitely repeated oligopoly games

Selten (1978) shows that, given the logic of game theory, no cooperation is possible as soon

as the game is finite. If the game has a final period, firms will cheat, as there cannot be

retaliation in the future. Knowing this, firms will also cheat in the period before the last and

so on until the first period. With this backward induction argument, the game unravels from

the back, and firms will never cooperate. Hence, the unique subgame perfect equilibrium18 of

a finitely repeated game with a unique Nash equilibrium in the stage game is a simple

repetition of the stage-game equilibrium. Thus, the dynamic element contributes nothing to

18 In general, the equilibrium concept of subgame perfection requires that future strategies out of the

equilibrium must themselves constitute an equilibrium in the future (sub)game (see e. g. Shapiro (1989), pp.357-360).

21

the model.19 This so-called "chain-store paradox" can be overcome by permitting the length

of the game, T, to be infinite or at least possibly infinite (see below 3.1.2) or by giving up the

assumption of perfect rationality (see below 3.3).

3.1.2 Infinitely repeated oligopoly games (supergames) with perfect information

The above inability of the firms to collude in a credible fashion rests on the exogenously

given terminal date of the game. However, in reality, competition continues indefinitely, or

at least firms cannot be sure when it will end. Indefinitely repeated games are fundamentally

different from finitely repeated ones in that there is always the possibility of retaliation and

punishment in the future.

3.1.2.1 The basic model

Assume that player i's overall payoff in the game is given by

�i = ��

�0tit

t�� (5)

where � is the discount factor.20

The game beginning at date t is assumed to look the same for all t in the sense that the

feasible strategies and the prospective payoffs that they induce are always the same.21 Each

firm produces its share of the collusive output in each period, as long as the others continue

to do so. If, however, any firm produces more than its "quota" under this arrangement, this

defection signals a collapse of the tacitly collusive arrangement, and each firm plays its static

noncooperative strategy thereafter ("Nash forever"). In the case of a quantity-setting

supergame, each firm plays its static Cournot output following any deviation ("trigger

strategy" or "grim strategy").

19 Considering the example of a two-fold repetition of Cournot oligopoly with i firms, each firm's strategy

consists of its first- and its second-period output conditional on its rivals' first-period outputs. Anyequilibrium must involve static Cournot behaviour in the second period because otherwise some firm wouldhave an incentive to change its second-period behaviour. Hence, e. g. to flood the market in the secondperiod if one deviates during the initial period is not credible. Since no credible punishment for defectors ispossible here, it is not possible to support any first-period outcome other than the standard Cournotequilibrium, i. e. there are no linkages in behaviour between the two periods.

20� = e-r�, where r is the instantaneous rate of interest and � is the real time between "periods". � close to 1represents high patience or rapid changes of price or quantity.

21 Investments by the firms or changes in the competitive environment will be addressed below (3.3.1.1).

22

3.1.2.2 Equilibria

To show that these strategies form a subgame perfect equilibrium two conditions have to be

verified: First, no firm wants to defect from the collusive scheme. Second, the punishment

strategies are themselves credible.

Starting with the second condition, credibility requires that the punishment itself forms a

perfect equilibrium. A punishment involving repetition of an equilibrium in the stage game

is credible, since it is always a perfect equilibrium to simply repeat any equilibrium in the

stage game indefinitely.

By cooperating, firm i earns �i*/(1-�). Hence, there is an equilibrium as long as the no-

defection condition

�i*/(1-�) � �i

d + ��ip/(1-�) (6)

<=> �i* � �i

d - ��id + ��i

p

<=> � � pi

di

idi

��

��

*

(7)

holds (where �id is firm i's profit from deviating from the collusive scheme and �i

p the profits

during the infinitely long punishment phase). That means that only mild punishments (�ip <

�i*) and bounded profits from defection (�i

d < �) are sufficient for collusion to succeed if � is

close enough to 1. Moreover, stronger, swifter, or more certain punishments allow the firms

to support a more collusive equilibrium outcome.22

3.1.2.3 The Folk theorem

Using such a framework, Friedman (1971) first showed formally that any Pareto optimal

outcome - in particular, many outcomes involving joint monopoly pricing - can arise as the

subgame-perfect equilibrium path of a repeated game, provided only that there is sufficiently

little discounting (i. e. � close to 1), as there will be if the market participants can respond

rapidly to each other (so-called folk theorem). Because of this multiplicity of equilibria,

supergame theory is "too successful" in explaining tacit collusion.23 On the other hand, any

attempts to theoretically limit the number of equilibria, are, so far, based on ad hoc

assumptions. Kreps (1990, p. 529) calls this the "twin problems of too many equilibria and

the selection of one of them".

22 Hence, anything (e. g. unlimited capacities) that makes more competitive behaviour as threat feasible or

credible actually promotes collusion. Shapiro calls this the "topsy-turvy principle of tacit collusion" (1989,p. 357).

23 Tirole (1998), p. 529.

23

Hence, game theory cannot predict whether firms will indeed coordinate on a particular

collusive equilibrium. It is possible, however, to derive necessary conditions for collusion

from game theory (see below 3.2 and 3.4).

3.1.2.4 The coordination problem

As a consequence of the folk theorem, firms that want to collude face the problem that -

given a mutually acceptable collusive equilibrium exists - they have to coordinate on it.

3.1.2.4.1 Explicit vs. tacit collusion

Cartels are forbidden and, therefore, void and unenforceable under most of the competition

laws. Hence, if in the case of explicit collusion, firms establish an equilibrium as described

above, it, nevertheless, has to be sustainable. There is, thus, no difference between explicit

and tacit collusion with regard to the stages of monitoring and enforcement.

However, in the initial stage of coordination, communication (i. e. explicit collusion) would

reduce the costs of finding equilibrium. Hence, with regard to their "behavioural"

instruments (in contrast to the "structural" approach of merger control; e. g., in the EC,

especially Article 81 EC), the task of competition authorities is (at least) to force firms into a

trade-off: Communication reduces the costs of finding equilibrium, but increases the

likelihood that collusion is detected and that the firms are fined.

3.1.2.4.2 Focal points and cheap talk

With direct communication being impossible or too costly due to expected fines, firms have

to solve the coordination problem tacitly, i. e. by a trial-and-error method.

Given this highly imperfect process of selecting a particular outcome only through market

interactions, "focal points"24 can be helpful: These are outcomes, or at least behavioural

rules, which are self evident. Firms may want to try to affect the perception of particular

outcomes, or particular rules, as self-evident. Hence, focal points may be created, inter alia,

by price leadership or by cheap talk25, i. e. costless, non-binding and non-verifiable messages

which are likely to affect the listener's beliefs (e. g. a public speech in which a well-defined

price increase is announced). In the case of tacit collusion, such practices are the only

"evidence" that competition authorities might find.

24 The theory of focal points was proposed by Schelling (1960).25 See Farrell and Rabin (1996). Cheap talk is one example of so-called "facilitating practices" which will be

addressed below (3.6.1).

24

3.1.3 Punishment strategies and renegotiation-proofness

Punishment strategies that have been used as threat in collusion models include, among

others,

- reversion to the noncooperative Cournot or Bertrand outcome ("trigger" or "grim

strategy" or "Nash forever" respectively),

- a phase of expanded outputs which optimally punishes the defector and a progressive

reversion to the low output level ("stick-and-carrot") (Abreu et al. (1986)),

- an output level which minimizes the profit of the firm that has deviated, given the

anticipated best reply of this deviator to the strategy of the punishing firm (minimax

strategy).

However, the minimax strategy lacks credibility because it is not in the best interest of the

punishing firm to use it and, therefore, no mutual best reply. Thus, this strategy infringes the

concept of subgame-perfection which demands that equilibrium strategies should be mutual

best replies not only for the whole game, but also in particular contingencies, which

correspond to particular truncations of the game.

Moreover, if the pre-specified punishment hurts the "innocent" firms as well as the defector,

firms would have an incentive not to implement it, but to renegotiate in order to achieve an

equilibrium in which all firms are better off. The expectation of renegotiation undermines the

strength of the punishment. This suggests that standard subgame-perfection is not generally

the binding constraint on collusion, but instead the more restricting concept of renegotiation

proofness (see Farrell and Maskin (1987) and below 3.4.1.2). The effect of renegotiation on

the credibility of punishment strategies depends on the cost of renegotiation: The higher the

cost, the less the credibility problem.26

3.2 Merger implications

So far, the theory of repeated games suggests that there are four necessary criteria for

collusion:

1. repeated interaction,

26 With respect to renegotiation, the same statement holds as for "negotiation" (i. e. the initial coordination on

an equilibrium): It does not necessarily imply that the firms actually get together and communicate, but thepossibility to communicate might make it easier. This also implies that the standard policy suggestion thatcompetition authorities should raise the cost of communication between firms is only partially correct withrespect to negotiation. Raising the cost of renegotiation, in contrast, makes collusion easier to sustain (see

25

2. the capacity to reach a mutually acceptable equilibrium (coordination),

3. the possibility of detection of cheating (monitoring),

4. enforceability of compliance (enforcement), i. e. firms find it rational to comply with the

collusive scheme since the profit from collusion is higher than the sum of the profit from

deviating and the profit during the punishment phase (see equation (6)).

3.2.1 Collusive effects of a merger

There are three main mechanisms by which mergers can directly change each of the above

conditions 2-4 such that the the likelihood of coordinated effects is increased:

1. By definition and most obviously, a merger reduces the number of firms in the market

(see below 3.2.1.1).

2. A merger can lead to a more symmetric distribution of assets (3.2.1.2).

3. A merger might decrease the incentives of a maverick firm to compete, or, more

obviously, might lead to the loss of a maverick firm (3.2.1.3).

Furthermore, a "concentration"27 notified by oligopolists which falls short of a full merger,

but is still captured by merger control (i. e. in particular a joint venture) creates a structural

link and, thus, an element of joint welfare maximization. Existing structural links are

analysed below (3.6.2) as factor which facilitates collusion. The statements made there also

hold with regard to the creation of such a link.

3.2.1.1 Reduction of number of firms

The reduction of the number of firms in the market facilitates coordination on a collusive

equilibrium as well as monitoring and enforcement of this equilibrium:

3.2.1.1.1 Coordination and monitoring - the "dinner party story"28

In the case of explicit collusion, costs due to communication increase with the number of

firms. In the case of tacit collusion, coordination on a specific equilibrium becomes more

McCutcheon (1997)). Hence, the first-best solution for competition authorities would be to distinguishbetween negotiation and renegotiation.

27 See § 37 GWB and Article 1 Merger Regulation.28 Baker (2002, p. 139) calls this reasoning the "dinner party story" since fewer firms make coordination more

likely or more effective for the same reason that "friends arranging a restaurant get-together likely will findit easier to coordinate the calendars of four people than five and more likely will notice if one personaccepts but does not show up".

26

difficult as the number of firms increases due to higher learning costs.29 In both cases, with

more firms, the probability of differing costs and other characteristics, i. e. asymmetry, and,

hence, of more divergent preferences increases.

With respect to monitoring, the argument is similar: The more firms there are in the market,

the harder it will be to determine the identity of the deviator once it becomes clear that

cheating has occured. Punishment strategies that specifically target the deviator (e. g. the

carrot-and-stick method of Abreu) become harder to apply. Moreover, an increase in the

number of firms decreases the impact of an individual firm's action on the aggregate market

parameters. Thus, if a firm believes that its actions cannot be monitored, it will more likely

deviate from the collusive equilibrium.

3.2.1.1.2 Enforcement30

Moreover, the gains from collusion are higher the less firms there are in the market because

the individual firm receives a higher share of the collusive profit (with symmetric firms and

constant marginal costs in the case of perfect collusion: �m/n per period). The gains from

cheating are lower since the firm can capture a smaller share of the market by undercutting

the other firms relative to the situation with more smaller firms in the market (in a repeated

Bertrand oligopoly framework the additional profit from cheating is: �m(1-1/n)-�).

Together, this implies that a higher concentration of the market increases the incentive to

collude. Formally (with "Bertrand forever" as punishment and, hence, zero profit), this can

be expressed by the condition under which the fully collusive outcome is sustainable:

n

m�

��11 > �m (8)

<=> � > 1-n1 . (9)

The required discount factor is larger for larger n. In that sense, collusion is more likely with

less firms.

29 In general, the number of bilateral relations is given by

)!2(2!�N

N .

27

3.2.1.2 More symmetric distribution of assets

In general, symmetry of firms refers to similarity of their cost structures. However,

symmetry can also concern other dimensions such as market shares, number of varieties in

the product portfolio, technological knowledge, capacities and degree of vertical integration.

The most general result of most of the models addressing this issue is that asymmetries make

collusion more difficult, in particular without any facilitating practices like cheap talk.31 Like

market concentration, asymmetry feeds into the three necessary criteria of coordination,

monitoring and enforcement:

3.2.1.2.1 Coordination and monitoring

Coordination on a particular equilibrium becomes difficult when firms' costs differ

significantly since low cost firms prefer a lower price and a higher output than high cost

firms.32 Moreover, if firms' cost structures differ significantly, their incentives to cheat differ

accordingly. Hence, if any company within an oligopoly shows persistent cost advantages,

this particularly disrupts a harmony of interests and creates an incentive for aggressive

competitive behaviour.33

A similar argument can be made for monitoring: Kreps (1990) points out that firms need to

have an implicit "rule" to follow. In a situation with symmetric firms, they can check that all

firms behave similarly. This "relative" comparison is easier than an "absolute" monitoring.

3.2.1.2.2 Enforcement

Finally, firm homogeneity facilitates the enforcement of compliance. For instance

Vasconcelos (2001), using a quantity setting supergame-framework with stick and carrot

punishment schemes in the style of Abreu and firms with linearly increasing marginal costs,

shows the following:

The smallest firm in an implicit agreement, being the one which is allotted the lowest share

in the collusive aggregate output34, represents the main obstacle for collusion to be enforced

30 See Tirole (1998), pp. 247-248.31 E. g. Rothschild (1999). It should be noted, however, that the presence of one highly efficient firm (or a

small group of similar and efficient firms) along with several less efficient firms could contribute to thestability of an agreement. In that case, the low cost firm(s) could take on the role of the leader(s) with theremaining firms as followers (Ross and Baziliauskas, 2000).

32 In theory, the low cost firm could pay the high cost firm to shut down its production. However, these sidepayments are not practical (there is, inter alia, an asymmetric information problem).

33 Kantzenbach et al. (1995), p. 61.34 Since, as output increases, marginal cost rises more rapidly for a small firm than for a large firm, joint profit

maximization implies that the smaller (and, hence, the more inefficient) a member firm is, the lower its

28

because its share may be too low with regard to its optimal deviation output. If it is not too

low, then its incentive constraint is binding on the collusive path. On the other hand, if the

punishment is started, then the largest firm (i. e. the one with the highest market share) is the

one which is proportionally more penalized by the price cut. Therefore, this firm faces the

greatest incentives to deviate from the first period of the punishment strategy, making its

incentive constraint binding on the punishment path. In that sense, asymmetry makes the

enforcement of collusion more difficult.

3.2.1.2.3 A trade-off

Extending the above result by comparative statics, Vasconcelos (2001) shows that a merger

can induce two distinct effects:

1. If collusion is not feasible before the merger, then a merger might make collusion

possible afterwards. This will happen when the merger involves very small and inefficient

firms that are not able to credibly participate in a collusive scheme before the merger

takes place, because their share in the aggregate output is too low in the above sense.

2. If firms in the market are already colluding before the merger, then a merger either has no

effect on the possibility of collusion or it hurts that possibility. The latter case will happen

when the merger increases the size of the largest firm in the market, because this will

induce an increase in the minimal threshold on the discount factor above which an

industry-wide collusive agreement is sustainable.35 The intuition which underlies this

result is the same as above: The larger the largest firm, the higher will be its share on the

one period losses due to the first phase of the punishment strategy. Therefore, increasing

weight has to be attached to the future stream of payoffs in order for this firm to comply

with the punishment strategy.

Hence, there is an important trade-off: Although collusion is facilitated due to an increase in

the number of competitors, this effect can be countervailed by a more asymmetric post-

merger industry configuration. In Vasconcelos' model, the effect of market concentration is

share in the aggregate output is. Banning side payments, this implies a correspondingly smaller share in thejoint profit.

35 See equation (31) in Vasconcelos (2001, p. 24): 1k�

�� > 0, where k1 is the fraction of the - fixed (!) -

industry capital stock owned by the the largest firm. ki is a parameter of the cost function which is Ci(qi, ki)

= cqi+i

i

kq2

2

, i. e. asymmetry is dealt with by assuming that firms have a different share of industry capital

which affects marginal costs.

29

more than compensated by post-merger asymmetry if firms have already been colluding

before the merger.

3.2.1.2.4 The case of capacity constraints - the model of Compte, Jenny and Rey

Using a similar method as Vasconcelos, but a Bertrand supergame, Compte, Jenny and Rey

(2002), instead of asymmetric capital share affecting marginal cost, assume asymmetric

capacity constraints. ki denotes firm i's limited capacity with k1...kn. M is the market size.

K-i � ��ij jk is the total capacity of firm i's rivals.

3.2.1.2.4.1 The results of the model

The first important result relates to mergers involving the largest firm such that capacity is

transferred from a small firm to the largest. The following table shows the effect of a

decrease in the "small"36 firm's capacity ki, of an increase in the large firm's capacity kn and -

as their sum - the overall impact of the transfer ki kn on collusion, i. e. either an increase

(+) in the lowest discount factor �(k) for which collusion is sustainable, no change of the

factor (=) or a decrease (-):

Table 3.1 - Impact of changes in capacity

case 1

K-n < M

kn < M

case 2

K-n < M

kn > M

case 3

K-n > M

kn < M

case 4

K-n > M

kn > M

ki � + + - - / =

kn � + = + =

ki kn + + = - / =

Source: Compte / Jenny / Rey (2002), p. 14

In the cases 1 and 2, when small firms cannot serve the entire market, transferring capacity

from a small firm to the largest one decreases the scope for collusion (� increases) because

the transfer reduces small firms' punishment ability. If additionally kn<M (case 1), such a

transfer increases the large firm's incentive to deviate. In contrast, if small firms can cover

the whole market (cases 3 and 4), such a transfer is either neutral or it facilitates collusion.

30

The result of cases 1 and 2 is very similar to that of Vasconcelos: Although the merger leads

to higher concentration, increased asymmetry decreases the scope for collusion.

Based on this result, Compte et. al. (2002, pp. 14-16) derive their second important result,

the distribution of capacity that most facilitates collusion: To facilitate collusion, first, the

retaliation possibilities of the smallest firms should be increased (up to M if possible).

Second, among the distributions which maximize punishment possibilites, the gains from

deviating should be minimized. If total capacity K<1�n

n M, i. e. the smallest (n-1) firms

cannot cover the market, the main problem is the deviation concern, i. e. the largest firm's

incentive to deviate. Starting from any asymmetric situation, transferring capacity from the

largest firm to a small one both enhances the small firm's retaliation power and limits the

large firm's incentive to deviate. Hence, the distribution of capacities that most facilitates

collusion in this case is the symmetric.37

3.2.1.2.4.2 Application to Nestlé / Perrier

In the light of these results, Compte et al. evaluate the Commission's decision in

Nestlé/Perrier, a merger on the French bottled water market which the Commission used to

introduce the concept of oligopolistic dominance into EC competition law (see below 5.1.1).

Before the merger, Nestlé had a market share of 17.1 % in terms of sold water, Perrier 35.9

% and BSN 23 %. The merger was cleared only after Nestlé accepted to sell Volvic, a major

still mineral source of Perrier, to BSN. Moreover, Nestlé commited itself to sell various

brands and some capacity to a third party so that this third party could become an active

player in the market.38

Estimating the ratios of capacity over market size for the four different scenarios (1.) pre-

merger, (2.) after the merger with the resale of Volvic to BSN, (3.) without the resale of

Volvic and (4.) with the resale and the divestiture to create a new third player, Compte et al.

(pp. 20-21) compute the minimum discount factor � that allows a collusive equilibrium in

each of the scenarios with the following result: �2<�1<�4<�3. That means, contradicting the

Commission's opinion, the scenario that minimises the scope for collusion is the solution in

36 "Small" in this context just means "not the largest".37 Compte et. al. first derive this result for "collusive �-equilibria", i. e. equilibria, where firms follow the

same strategy and maintain constant market shares �i with 0��i�ki (2002, p. 5). However, the above resultstill holds for general collusive equilibria (2002, p. 15).

31

which Nestlé and Perrier merge, but do not transfer Volvic to BSN. Hence, according to the

model, it would have been best to clear the merger without conditions or, as second best

solution, to block it completely.

3.2.1.2.5 Policy implications

Both the results of Vasconcelos and Compte et al. have several policy implications: First, the

instruments used to assess unilateral effects and single dominance respectively do not reflect

the possible adverse effects of increased asymmetry on collusion. As both Vasconcelos and

Compte et. al. hint at, the HHI even punishes asymmetry (see above 2.1.5). Second, in

addition to the common wisdom that asymmetry hurts collusion, competition authorities

have to take into account which firms (in particular the largest and the smallest) are involved

in a merger. Third, if asymmetry decreases the likelihood of collusion in the above sense, in

theory, this effect might outweigh unilateral effects due to a merger with the consequence

that a single dominant position should be tolerated. Fourth, the models at least cast doubt on

the standard remedy of divesting capacity of the merged firm and transferring it to

competitors.39

However, it has to be kept in mind that models which concentrate on the effects of symmetry

necessarily abstract from other factors which might be prevailing.

3.2.1.3 Loss of a maverick or reducing its incentive to compete

The concept of a maverick appears in the U.S. Merger Guidelines, where a maverick firm is

described as one with "a greater economic incentive to deviate from the terms of

coordination than do most of [its] rivals" (Section 2.12). As an example, the Guidelines

describe a firm that has an "unusually disruptive and competitive" influence in the market.

Mavericks can be seen as an extreme case of dissimilarity of firms in which one firm is so

different from the other firms that it is unwilling to accept the terms of coordination. Hence,

aside from increasing concentration and making firms more symmetric, the loss of a

maverick or relaxing its constraint on collusion can be a third consequence of a merger that

increases the likelihood of coordinated effects.

38 After the decision, the Commission was criticized for having "constructed" a market structure. Especially

from a Hayekian perspective, this seems questionable since a market structure 'designed on the drawingboard' is based on less information than a structure which evolves evolutionary in a selection process.

39 See Motta, Polo and Vasconcelos (2002), pp. 8-10; aside from increasing symmetry, the divestiture of assetsto strenghten an existing competitor might also allow for multimarket contacts which also increase the riskof collusion (see below 3.5.7).

32

3.2.1.3.1 Identifying a maverick

According to Baker (2002, pp. 173-177), mavericks can be identified in three ways:

1. The first way is to observe that the firm actually constrains industry pricing, i. e. by

revealed preference.

2. Some factors likely affecting the market price preferred by the maverick are firm specific.

For example, a firm's marginal costs may rise or fall for reasons related to the nature or

location of its production processes, and in consequence may not be paralleled by cost

changes affecting its rivals. If that firm is a maverick, the market price will change due to

the "natural experiment" because the maverick constrains collusion. If another firm is the

maverick, the market price will remain unchanged.

3. The third approach relies on a priori factors, i. e. the reasons for a firm's preference for a

high or low price in the particular market under investigation. The U.S. Merger

Guidelines provide for two examples of a priori factors tending to identify a likely

maverick. First,"in a market where capacity constraints are significant for many competitors, a firm is more

likely to be a maverick the greater is its excess or divertible capacity in relation to its sales or its

total capacity, and the lower are its direct and opportunity costs of expanding sales in the relevant

market. This is so because a firm's incentive to deviate from price-elevating and output-limiting

terms of coordination is greater the more the firm is able profitably to expand its output as a

proportion of the sales it would obtain if it adhered to the terms of coordination and the smaller

is the base of sales on which it enjoys elevated profits prior to the price cutting deviation."

(Section 2.12)

Second,"[a] firm also may be a maverick if it has an unusual ability secretly to expand its sales in relation

to the sales it would obtain if it adhered to the terms of coordination,"

as might arise"from opportunities to expand captive production for a downstream affiliate." (Section 2.12)

3.2.1.3.2 Merger scenarios

The first scenario,40 the acquisition of a maverick, is likely to remove the maverick's

constraint on collusion since, absent cognizable efficiencies from the transaction, the

merged firm most likely would prefer higher prices than the maverick on his own.41 Second,

vice versa, a merger might create a maverick if the merger confers such large efficiencies on

40 For a complete overview on and discussion of several scenarios see Baker (2002), pp. 177-188.41 See Baker (2002), pp. 177-179.

33

the merging parties as to lead them to prefer a much lower price than either did before the

transaction. This scenario was assumed by a U.S. court in the case Heinz/Beech-Nut (see

below 6.5.2) and is recognized in general by the U.S. Merger Guidelines which state"In a coordinated interaction context ..., marginal cost reductions may make coordination less

likely or effective by enhancing the incentive of a maverick to lower price or by creating a new

maverick firm." (Section 4)

A third scenario might be a merger which does not involve the maverick, but instead affects

the maverick's incentives to compete. An example is provided for by the OECD (1999):

Consider a market where the smallest of four leading firms is a maverick. If any of the other

three leading firms merge, the increased size of its rivals might convert the maverick into a

cooperative partner. However, at the same time, such a merger might plausibly increase

asymmetry in the leading firms' market shares. Hence, there might be a trade-off between

increasing asymmetry making collusion more difficult and reducing the maverick's incentive

to compete, thus facilitating collusion.

As this example highlights, making an oligopolistic group of firms more symmetric is not in

itself a sufficient indication of a net increase of the likelihood of coordinated effects.

3.2.2 Comparative institutional analysis42

So far, it has been shown that a merger in an oligopolistic market can increase the likelihood

of collusion by increasing concentration, by making oligopolists more symmetric, and by

reducing competition by a maverick. Hence, merger control can indeed be used to prevent

collusion or at least to reduce the risk of collusion. However, what yet is to be shown is that

merger control is the optimal instrument to fight collusion.

3.2.2.1 Merger control and the prohibition of collusion as (imperfect) substitutes

When trying to define the optimal policy against coordinated effects, the alternative ex post

instruments provided for by competition law have to be taken into account: The closest

substitute for merger control is the prohibition of horizontal restrictions of competition (i. e.

both explicit and tacit collusion) provided for in § 1 GWB, Article 81 EC and Section 1 of

the Sherman Act.43 However, as, inter alia, merger control can only prevent external growth

42 See OECD (1999), pp. 31-34 for an overview on the different instruments to fight collusion; see Stroux

(2001) for an overview on the EC instruments.43 § 1 GWB and Article 81 EC prohibit (legally binding and non-binding) "agreements" as well as "concerted

practices", Section 1 Sherman Act equivalently prohibits "contract[s], combination[s] ... or conspirac[ies]".Another substitute, the prohibition of the abuse of a collective dominant position, i. e. inter alia anti-

34

of firms, markets might become more concentrated and, hence, more conducive to

coordination due to internal growth. Thus, merger control and ex post instruments against

collusion are only imperfect substitutes.

3.2.2.2 Comparative cost-benefit-analysis

Given the substitutability of merger policy and the prohibition of collusion, an optimal

policy against coordinated effects would require a comparative cost-benefit-analysis of these

instruments. Generally, from a welfare perspective, a policy instrument should be applied,

first, if the expected utility of its use is higher than the expected costs (i. e. a positive net

utility) and, second, if there is no alternative with a higher positive net utility.

Applying the first condition to merger control, a merger should be blocked on grounds of

coordinated effects if the expected net utility of blocking the merger (i. e. expected utility

minus expected loss) is higher than the expected net utility of allowing it. The first is

associated with the cost of type I errors (false positives), the second with the cost of type II

errors (false negatives).

Comparing merger control with ex post instruments (second condition), the distinction

between ex ante and ex post regulation may not be essential here: Both the evaluation of

whether collusion has taken place and the evaluation of whether it might take place as a

consequence of a merger will be uncertain because there will be a margin of error in any

evaluation.44 Hence, the risk of type I and type II errors has to be taken into account not only

for merger control, but also for the prohibition of collusion.

With respect to the cost of errors, two statements are possible: First, from the point of view

of Schumpeterian competition, in merger control, type I errors might be more costly than

type II errors because of the indirect negative effect that type I errors will have on

investment and profit incentives: Firms do not invest in gaining a high market share if they

expect to be "punished" for that by "wrong" merger control decisions.

Second, generally, reducing the margin of error for ex post regulation may be easier than for

ex ante regulation since the marginal cost of reducing uncertainty will be typically lower ex

post because (more) evidence is available. However, this holds only for express collusion

since competition authorities face great problems proofing tacit collusion:45 In contrast to

competitive or exploitative abuse of a group of firms (§§ 19, 20 GWB, Article 82 EC) has a narrower scopesince it requires the use of market power against other firms (not consumers).

44 Neven (2000), p. 8.45 See e. g. the U.S. contribution to the OECD (1999), pp. 201-202.

35

"perceptible" mergers, there is a significant probability that tacit collusion is not detected at

all. Moreover, if it is detected, the legal standard of evidence might not be met since the only

evidence might be facilitating practices like cheap talk.

This justifies why many jurisdictions (see OECD 1999) use merger control as preventive

instrument. Hence, a preliminary cost analysis suggests at least that, merger control is an

appropriate instrument to fight tacit collusion.

3.3 Other approaches to collusion

So far, basic theory of repeated games was used to explain the mechanism leading to

collusion and the effects of a merger on the likelihood of collusion. However, some

objections are put forward against traditional game theory as an explanation for collusion,

among others:

1. the absence of change of the competitive environment,

2. the counterintuitive outcome of finitely repeated games (chain-store-paradox, see above

3.1.1) and

3. the vast multiplicity of equilibria (Folk theorem) and the difficulty of selecting among

them (above 3.1.2.3).

Especially the second point has been a major criticism since, in an experimental study,

Axelrod (1980, 1981) showed that in long, but finitely repeated prisoner's dilemma

situations, cooperation does emerge, even among very sophisticated players.

Hence, before a normative framework for assessing coordinated effects can be developed on

the basis of game theory (see 3.4), it has to be checked whether refinements of repeated

games, in particular truly dynamic models (3.3.1), can cope with the above shortcomings.46

Alternatively, if another approach outside traditional game theory - especially evolutionary

game theory (3.3.2) - does not feature such shortcomings, traditional game theory might

have to be replaced as theory which explains collusion.

3.3.1 Truly dynamic models47

Repeated games which have been presented above (3.1) are limited in that history has no

effect on prospective competition since the subgame beginning at any date is identical to the

original game. However, in reality, strategic (in the sense of sunk) investments alter the

46 See Shapiro (1989), p. 360.47 See Shapiro (1989), pp. 397-408; Fudenberg and Tirole (1986).

36

subsequent competitive environment. This was first formalized in two-stage models in which

a Nash equilibrium emerges in the second period, given a strategic first-period action.48

Truly dynamic models of oligopoly combine the repeated rivalry aspects of supergames with

the investment and commitment aspects of two-period models.49 There are two types of

industry conditions that may be strategically controlled: tangible (3.3.1.1) and intangible

(3.3.1.2).

3.3.1.1 Tangible industry conditions50

Tangible state variables51 which are strategically chosen can be, e. g., firms' capital stocks,

technological capabilities or capacities. Examining such capacity decisions in a duopoly,

Benoit and Krishna (1987) stress their result that firms build excess capacity in order to

better discipline their subsequent pricing behaviour (firm 1 must build some excess capacity

if it is to be in a position to punish firm 2 for expanding its capacity). In this sense, it is

possible, but costly for firms to sustain outcomes which are more collusive than the one-

stage Nash equilibrium.

3.3.1.2 Intangible industry conditions (beliefs)

In reality, history matters not only through its direct effect on tangible variables, but also

indirectly through the information which it brings to competitors who use it to estimate

variables that they do not know, e. g. its rivals' cost structures, demand expectations or

degree of rationality. Hence, history also matters through intangible variables (beliefs). In

particular, in a repeated game with asymmetric information, a firm can sacrifice short-run

profit by raising its price in order to signal that it prefers high prices, i. e. cooperative

behaviour, if it values future returns relatively high.52 This signal may be credible because it

is costly. Using such a reputation game and assuming a small probability of "craziness" (i. e.

a preference for cooperation), Kreps et al. (1982) show that even in a finite repetition of a

48 The Stackelberg model (1934) can be regarded as "ancestor" of two-stage models.49 Aside from endogenous changes in the conditions of competition due to strategic maneuvering by the

oligopolists, the source of industry dynamics can also be quite independently of firm behaviour, e. g. in thecase of exogenous technological progress.

50 See Shapiro (1989), pp. 398-405.51 In order to focus on the strategic aspects of competition, i. e. on the changing economic environment, the

tactical short-run decisions are folded into the background. Reduced-form profit functions indicate thefirms' profits as functions of the "state variables" which affect the ensuing subgame and measure theeconomic conditions at any point in time (e. g. the firms' capital stocks).

52 Tirole (1998), p. 257.

37

prisoner's dilemma, collusion is sustainable.53 However, still a Folk theorem holds, i. e. any

outcome can be sustained as an equilibrium of a sufficiently long and little discounted game

with incomplete information.54

Hence, refinements of traditional game theory can cope with criticism 1 and 2, but not with

point 3 (see above 3.3).

3.3.2 Evolutionary game theory

Whereas the approach of Kreps et al. (1982) of assuming a small probability of craziness

remains within the boundaries of traditional game theory,55 evolutionary game theory which

is derived from biology56 assumes, first, bounded rationality of the players.57 It understands

an equilibrium as the outcome of adaption (or learning) and selection rather than as the result

of calculating best replies by rational agents. Hence, "players need to know only what was

successful, not why it was successful" (Mailath, 1998, p. 1355).

Aside from the difference in assumed rationality, second, the evolutionary approach does not

focus on individuals, but on the population distribution of behaviours (decision rules,

strategies). Strategies that provide good replies to the current population will be imitated and

played by a larger fraction in the next round. A particular type of player is evolutionary

stable if its population cannot be invaded successfully by any mutant (i. e. a competing

society). A strategy played by an evolutionary stable type is called an evolutionary-stable-

strategy (ESS).

In contrast to traditional game theory, third, evolutionary game theory specifies single

outcomes and, fourth, allows to model the coordination process between the oligopolists

which traditional theory of repeated games takes as given.58

53 According to Tirole (1998, p. 259), the intuition for this result is the following: By cooperating, each player

exposes himself to the risk that the other player does not cooperate, and that he obtains a low profit duringone period. However, by non cooperating, he reveals that he is not of a cooperative type and, therefore,loses future gains from cooperation if the other player is of a cooperative type. If the horizon is longenough, the loss of future cooperation exceeds the loss from being cheated on.

54 Fudenberg and Maskin (1986).55 In reputation games, generally, perfect rationality is assumed, but under incomplete information there might

be a small but positive probability that a player makes a mistake, e. g. fails to identify the optimal strategy.56 In nature, the basic selection mechanism is biological survival and reproduction, and the mutation process

is basically genetic. In the market place, the basic selection mechanism is economic survival, and themutation process is experimentation, innovation and mistakes (Weibull, 1998, p. 3).

57 Tirole (1998), p. 261. For a formal description of evolutionary game theory see Weibull (1995).58 More precisely, evolutionary game theory uses two sets of solution concepts: the above ESS and a set of

dynamic concepts which examine the stability of the evolutionary process. Whereas the evolutionarystability criterion does not explain how a population arrives at a strategy, but instead asks whether, oncereached, a strategy is robust, the second set allows to explicitly model a selection process (so-calledreplicator dynamics).

38

However, so far, there is no general oligopoly theory based on evolutionary game theory

which allows to derive a detailed explanation of tacit collusion.59

3.3.2.1 Tit for tat as evolutionary-stable-strategy

Based on experiments, Axelrod (1984) suggests that in the repeated prisoner's dilemma, the

tit-for-tat strategy of beginning with cooperation and then matching one's rival's previous

move tends to be evolutionary-stable.

Tit for tat combines the following properties: "It is nice, forgiving, and retaliatory. It is never

the first to defect; it forgives an isolated defection after a single response; but it is always

incited by a defection no matter how good the interaction has been so far".60 Hence, tit for tat

allows for a mix of cooperation and punishment. In contrast, the "always cheat" rule forbids

gains from cooperation with cooperative types, while the "always cheat after a deviation"

rule (grim strategy) is not forgiving enough in case of a mistake. Another advantage of the

tit-for-tat stragey is that, in an evolutionary context, it allows the survival of other

cooperative strategies such as "always cooperate" (i. e. the cartel outcome).61

3.3.2.2 Implications for merger policy

Because of its shortcomings, Amstutz (1999)62 suggests that merger policy against

coordinated effects cannot be based on new industrial economics which rests upon

traditional game theory. Instead, the concept of collective dominance should not be applied

by the EC Commission until evolutionary game theory has developed a general oligopoly

theory which allows to draw robust policy conclusions.

However, experimental studies confirm the insights of the theory of repeated games that,

first, a higher number of suppliers leads to more competition and less cooperation and that,

second, cooperation increases the more periods the game has (Alger (1986), Holt (1995)).63

The first insight is also confirmed by empirical studies on cartels (see e. g. Marquez (1992),

Dick (1997)). Hence, game theory has not been falsified. Moreover, imperfect information

and unstable market conditions (the starting point of evolutionary economics) can be

integrated into the framework of repeated games (see below 3.5.4).

59 Amstutz (1999), Kollektive Marktbeherrschung im europäischen Wettbewerbsrecht – Eine evolutorische

Perspektive, p. 47.60 Axelrod (1984), p. 46.61 Tirole (1998), p. 261.62 Amstutz (1999), pp. 49-51.63 This argument against Amstutz' conclusion stems from Haucap (2000), p. 4.

39

What remains as criticism against the theory of repeated games, is that it cannot predict that

firms will collude (point 3 above). Hence, it has to be regarded as exemplifying theory. An

exemplifying theory does not tell what must happen, but what can happen.64 Most

importantly for merger policy, it does not only allow to derive necessary conditions for

collusion, but it can also explain with theoretical rigour how certain market characteristics

might support these conditions as will be pointed out in the upcoming sections. Hence, it

allows a relative prognosis of the probability of collusion.

3.4 Necessary conditions for collusion

So far, four necessary criteria for collusion have been worked out on the basis of the theory

of repeated games (see above 3.2):

1. repeated interaction,

2. the capacity to reach a mutually acceptable equilibrium (coordination),

3. the detection of cheating (monitoring) and

4. enforciability of compliance (enforcement).

Two additional criteria should be added:

5. few firms and

6. barriers to entry/exit and expansion.

It has already been outlined that a low number of firms feeds into the conditions 2-4 (see

above 3.2.1). Consequently, there is an intersection of condition 5 with these conditions. The

same holds for condition 6 (see below 3.4.2). Despite these intersections, conditions 5 and 6

should be included in the list of necessary criteria to highlight their importance.65 Both

conditions are going to be addressed in more detail now.

3.4.1 "Few" firms - is there a "magic" number?

Basic supergame models suggest that even with many firms monopoly pricing is possible.

For example, in repeated n-firm Bertrand oligopoly with constant marginal costs, shared

monopoly is sustainable in subgame-perfect equilibrium provided that the per-period

discount factor � is at least 1-n1 (see equation (9)). With �=0.99, representing a plausible

interest rate if the detection and response lag is a month, 100 firms can sustain the monopoly

64 See Fisher (1989), p. 117.65 The importance of the conditions of few firms and barriers to entry and expansion is also emphasized in the

OECD roundtable report (1999, pp. 21-23).

40

price. As Shapiro (1989, pp. 365-366) calculates, a symmetric Cournot industry can sustain a

shared monopoly with up to 400 firms if punishment consists of Cournot reversion.

In practice, however, there is a consensus that coordinated effects are likely only in much

more concentrated markets. Two answers from theory shall be presented.

3.4.1.1 Selten's "four are few and six are many"

In Selten's model (1973), firms can either be cartel members or fringe competitors. The

competitive fringe competes in a Cournot fashion, while those in the cartel collude. In this

situation, there must be both internal and external stability for the cartel to work. Internal

stability requires that, given the number of firms in the cartel and the number of firms in the

fringe, the cartel members are better off in the cartel than in the fringe. External stability

symmetrically requires that members of the fringe must be better off outside the cartel than

in it.

Using linear demand and cost functions and assuming perfect and complete information,

Selten shows that with four firms or less a complete cartel will always be formed.66

However, as the number of firms rises, joining the fringe becomes relatively more attractive.

This is because the members of the cartel behave as one player and the output of the cartel

does not depend on the number of firms in it. Thus, the higher the number of firms in the

cartel the lower the profit of each participant and the greater the attraction of competing on

the fringe. As Phlips (1995) points out, this is a very different point from the one which

states that more competitors make it harder to enforce the agreement. In the Selten model,

there is no cheating since the cartels are Nash equilibria. Hence, it would be misleading to

regard the model as noncooperative theory of cartels.67

In Selten's equilibrium a partial cartel will exist with some firms in the cartel and others

outside. Specifically, within the framework used by Selten, there will be four cartel members

with five or six symmetric firms in the industry, five members with seven or eight symmetric

firms and six members with nine or ten symmetric firms. Finally, Selten calculates the

probability that a firm takes part in a partial or complete cartel. Due to symmetry this

probability is the same for all firms. Using the derived probabilities, Selten is able to derive

the probability of a complete or partial cartel actually being formed. For four firms or fewer

66 Selten's result that a complete cartel arises in equilibria only if there are four firms or less has also been

obtained by Martin (1993) who extends the analysis to repeated games and by Shaffer (1995) who derivesconditions under which the behaviour of the fringe and the cartel emerges endogeneously.

67 Wolfstetter (1999), p. 101.

41

the probability is 100 per cent, for five firms it is 22 per cent, but for six firms it is only 1 per

cent. This suggests that with six firms or more, even if a partial cartel is an equilibrium, the

chances of a cartel actually forming are extremely low.

This suggests that coordinated effects or collective dominance respectively with more than 5

firms in the market are highly unlikely. Hence, 6-5 mergers could be regarded as "absolute

boundary" for merger control.

3.4.1.2 Renegotiation-proofness as binding constraint

Elaborating the the theory of "weak renegotiation-proofness" in repeated games of Farrell

and Maskin (1989), Farrell (2001) defines "quasi-symmetrically weakly renegotiation-

proofness" in the following way: A subgame-perfect equilibrium is quasi-symmetrically

weakly renegotiation-proof (QSWRP) if, evaluated at the beginning of the period after

player i alone deviates from prescribed play, every other player's continuation payoff

(weakly) exceeds what it would have been had player i not just deviated. Thus no innocent

player would want to forget and forgive.

Using this definition, Farrell (2001, pp. 11-12) shows that in repeated Bertrand competition,

full collusion is impossible in QSWRP equilibrium if n>3, even for discount factors very

close to 1. In repeated Cournot oligopoly, full collusion is not QSWRP with more than nine

firms, even for � very close to 1 (p. 17).

In particular the result for Bertrand competition seems to be very plausible. It coincides with

the practice of competition authorities which focus on 4-3 and 3-2 mergers.

3.4.2 Barriers to entry/exit and expansion

There are two related mechanisms by which barriers to entry and expansion can facilitate

collusion by preventing from hit-and-run competition (3.4.2.1) and from competitive

pressure by fringe firms (3.4.2.2).

3.4.2.1 Barriers to entry/exit: prevention of hit-and-run competition

In repeated games, the number of player is assumed to be constant. In reputation games,

some models specifically address entry with the decisions of the incumbent and the potential

entrant modelled explicitly. In both scenarios, costless entry changes the game such that

collusion becomes unprofitable since without (significant) barriers to entry and exit, there is

always the threat of "hit-and-run competition": With expected positive profits, firms will

42

enter, reap the profit and possibly retreat from the market. If they can exit the market as

easily as they entered, no threat of future losses can keep them from entering and

undercutting the incumbent firms.68 Hence, the likelihood of collusion depends on the extent

of barriers to entry (e. g. sunk costs, economies of scale and regulation) and exit.

3.4.2.2 Barriers to expansion: prevention of competitive pressure by fringe firms

Fringe players are small firms that have overcome barriers to entry and already operate in the

market. They act as price takers and follow the price of the leading oligopolistic group.69

But, as prices rise, they increase output. Hence, if cooperation in the market leads to

permanently supra-competitive prices (competitive prices in the sense of one-shot game

prices), the fringe firms have the incentive to expand their output in order to capture more of

the market. Thus, if fringe firms can expand relatively easily, they can exert a strong

competitive pressure on the coordinating firms. Or as von Weizsäcker (2001) phrases it:

Collusion is only stable if it is at the expense of the non-colluding fringe. Vice versa, if

expansion of output is easy for the fringe firms, they will gain a higher market share at the

expense of the cartel.

However, first, the same features that act as barriers to entry may also act as barriers to

expansion, thus impeding destabilisation of the coordinated behaviour. Second, even if a

fringe firm is able to expand, barriers to entry could allow the colluding firms to retaliate

successfully against the expanding firm (e. g. in the case of sunk costs) or to include the firm

into the colluding group. The latter case might arise if market conditions are such that only

one or two fringe firms reach the scale needed to effectively compete with the leading firms

making it profitable for the former fringe to join the colluding group as in Selten's "four are

few and six are many".

3.5 Market characteristics corresponding to the necessary conditions

In contrast to the necessary conditions of "few firms" and "barriers to entry and expansion"

which constitute market factors themselves, the other four conditions derived from game

theory are abstract concepts that cannot directly be established by observation. However,

there are structural market characteristics that feed into these necessary criteria. Most of

them are already part of the "checklists" that competition authorities use when assessing

68 This is the idea of the "contestable market hypothesis" formalised by Baumol, Panzar and Willig (1982).69 This price-taking behaviour can be formalised by leader-follower models along the lines of Stackelberg

(1934).

43

mergers to find out whether a market is conducive to coordination. The following table

provides for an overview of these market factors which correspond to the conditions

necessary for coordinated conduct.

Table 3.1 - Conditions for coordinated conduct in oligopolistic markets70

Necessary condition Factors contributing to the condition

Few firms

Barriers to entry/exit

Repeated interaction No large and infrequent orders

(see below 3.5.1)

Capacity to reach a mutually acceptable

equilibrium (coordination)

- Symmetry (see above 3.2.1.2)

- No maverick firm (3.2.1.3)

- Homogeneous products (3.5.2)

- Market transparency (3.5.3)

- Stable demand conditions (3.5.4)

- Low buyer power (3.5.5)

Detection of cheating (monitoring) - Symmetry (3.2.1.2)

- Homogeneous products (3.5.2)

- Market transparency (3.5.3)

- Stable demand conditions (3.5.4)

- Low buyer power (3.5.5)

Enforceability of compliance

(enforcement)

- Symmetry (3.2.1.2)

- No maverick firm (3.2.1.3)

- Stable demand conditions (low rate of

change in market size and low degree of

innovation) (3.5.4)

- Low price elasticity in the sub-market

composed of the leading firms' products

(3.5.6)

- Multi-market contact (3.5.7)

- Excess capacity (3.5.8)

70 See Europe Economics (2001), p. 29.

44

The relationships between the necessary conditions and the demand and supply factors

contributing to them will be outlined now.71

3.5.1 No large and lumpy orders

Repeated interaction is necessary both for coordination, which - in the absence of readily

identifiable focal points - can be thought of as a trial-and-error approximation or iterative

process, and for punishment (see above difference between finite and infinite games). In

practice, it seems unlikely that this criterion is not met. A market characteristic which

corresponds to it are many and frequent orders. Vice versa, large and lumpy orders would

hinder collusion.72

3.5.2 Homogeneous products

Product homogeneity mainly feeds into the necessary criteria of coordination and

monitoring:

Coordination on a particular collusive equilibrium is facilitated by product homogeneity

since it becomes easier to find, e. g., a common collusive price. Vice versa, if products are

differentiated and firms produce a large number of products, they will have difficulties

determining a complete schedule of collusive prices for these products. Moreover, product

homogeneity makes markets more transparent by reducing the parameters that need to be

observed. Hence, detection of any deviation tends to be easier.73

With respect to enforcement, the effect is ambiguous: On the one hand, product homogeneity

increases the gain from cheating by allowing the deviating firm to capture a larger share of

the market by undercutting its rivals. On the other hand, homogeneous products allow for

harsher punishment, thus reducing the incentive to cheat.74 Häckner (1996) shows for a

horizontally differentiated duopoly that the best collusive price is lower, the more

substitutable the products are, i. e. product differentiation can lead to higher prices in the

case of tacit collusion.

The degree of product homogeneity is closely linked to how broadly the market is defined:

Ceteribus paribus, the narrower the definition of a market, the greater the likelihood that

71 Except symmetry and the absence of a maverick firm which have been discussed already in detail above

(see 3.2.1.2 and 3.2.1.3).72 Formally, a more infrequent interaction corresponds to a decrease in � (see Tirole (1998), p. 248, and

Shapiro (1989), p. 378).73 See Kantzenbach et al. (1995), p. 17.74 See Ross (1992).

45

products will be regarded as homogeneous. Hence, because of the importance of product

homogeneity as a facilitating factor, the market definition must be particularly robust in

coordinated effects or collective dominance cases respectively.

3.5.3 Market transparency

Market transpareny can, inter alia, refer to the transparency of price, production, capacity,

R&D and advertisement levels. Very similarly to product homogeneity, transparency is one

of the "classic" market characteristics which makes it easier for firms to coordinate on and to

monitor a particular collusive equilibrium by making market parameters and firms' actions

more observable.

3.5.3.1 Supergames with imperfect information

Market transparency can be identified with perfect or - better - costless information. Hence,

transpareny can be seen as a combination of various other factors contributing to making the

finding of information cheaper, e. g. product homogeneity. If the market is intransparent or

information expensive respectively, then secret price cuts and detection lags can occur.

Secret price cuts have been formalized as supergames with imperfect information by Porter

(1983) and by Green and Porter (1984). The basic idea is that when one of the oligopolists

observes a low profit during period t, it is incapable of determing whether the low price is a

consequence of low demand or a price cut by its rival.75 If the observed price falls below a

certain level, a price war is triggered. After T periods, the firms return to their original

strategies, again cooperating at the optimal quantity x* (or price) until the price falls below

the trigger again.76 Porter (1983) shows that it is optimal for the firms to produce in excess of

the monopoly output in order to ease the problem of cartel enforcement (x*<xc if �<1).77

The intuition is the following: The fully collusive outcome could be sustained only if the

firms continued to collude fully even when making small profits with the argument that even

under collusion small profits can occur as a result of low demand. However, a firm that is

confident that its competitor will continue to cooperate even if its profit is low has the

75 E. g. in a quantity-setting supergame, demand uncertainty can be modelled by assuming that demand has

the form pt=�tp(X), where �t~N(1,��

2) is the realization of a random demand shock at period t and �t's areuncorrelated.

76 According to Shapiro (1989), the key contribution of repeated oligopoly games with imperfect monitoringis that they actually predict the occurence of price wars in equilibrium (with higher probability duringrecessions than in booms). In contrast, in supergames with perfect monitoring, while the credibility and sizeof punishments is critical, price wars never actually occur.

46

incentive to (secretly) undercut. Hence, full collusion is not consistent with the deterrence of

price cuts.78

The main conclusion from this class of models (Abreu, Pearce and Stacchetti (1986),

Fudenberg and Maskin (1986), Matsushima (2000)) is that imperfect information or market

intransparency generally tends to limit the extent to which firms can tacitly collude.

However, there is some ambiguity concerning this finding: Transparency also decreases

consumers' costs to search for the best deal (transaction costs). This may make consumers

switch suppliers more easily, increasing cross-price elasticity and, thus, the incentives to

cheat as well as the severity of punishment.79

3.5.3.2 Empiric evidence80

Empiric evidence for this result is provided, inter alia, by Albaek et al. (1997) who study the

impact of the 1993 decision by the Danish competition authority to publish statistics on

transaction prices for ready-mixed cement following the guidelines set out in the Danish

Competition Act which calls for transparency in competitive conditions. The authors suggest

that the impact of this move backfired since the publication of such data allowed firms to

reduce the intensity of the competition between themselves and increase their prices.

Similarly, Christie and Schultz (1994a, b) present strong evidence for tacit collusion of

brokerage firms trading in Nasdaq stocks which was facilitated by the very high

transparency in the market

3.5.4 Stable demand conditions (low rate of change in market size and low degree of

innovation)

As already Stigler (1964) noted, fluctuations in demand in a realistic imperfect information

environment are one of the major problems for firms wishing to collude. As was pointed out

previously with respect to market transparency, if the output or price of each firm is not

77 Formally, a small reduction in output below the monopoly level has no first-order effect on �*, but does

reduce the gains from deviation.78 Tirole (1998), p. 252. Contrary to Green's and Porter's finding, Rotemberg and Saloner (1986) in an

alternative model show that the gain from defection increases with demand (random variable �), i. e., tacitcollusion becomes more difficult in high-demand states. However, as Rotemberg and Saloner point outthemselves, capacity constraints are likely to be binding during periods of high demand making defectionimpossible.

79 See Møllgaard and Overgaard (2001).80 For an extensive overview on the empiric evidence on market factors which may increase the scope for

collusion see the contribution of the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice to the OECDroundtable report (1999, p. 237).

47

observable, random demand fluctuations make it difficult for the non-cheating firms to

determine whether cheating has occured or not.81

Considering the risk of coordinated effects, market demand can be unstable especially in two

dimensions:

3.5.4.1 Market size

In markets with stagnant demand, there is no incentive among incumbent firms to compete

for an increase in demand since any gain in market share can only be achieved at the expense

of competitors, possibly ending in a damaging price war with no winners. Moreover, low

growth does not attract outsiders to enter the market. Hence, in particular mature markets

with no or only low growth are prone to collusion.

3.5.4.2 Innovation

Apart from the variability of demand due to a change in market size, the likelihood and

degree of innovation plays a significant role: Technical change means that at any one time

firms in the industry may have very different technologies and, therefore, very different cost

bases and may consequently face very different incentives to expand output at the margin,

making tacit collusion more difficult. Moreover, if the nature of the game is set to change

radically following major innovation or product development, the incentive to collude

decreases since there may be no stream of long term collusive profit to set against the higher

short term profits available from cheating.

Both arguments (market growth and innovation) come together in the case of Schumpeterian

competition: competition may not be primarily on price, but may take the form of

competition to be the first to produce the next generation of the product. If a firm expects to

reap a temporary monopoly profit, there is no necessity for collusion. Similar arguments can

be made with respect to market phase (product and/or technology life cycle): In earlier stages

of an industry's development, there are a larger number of factors on which firms could

compete, plus overall growth is quicker, making coordination more difficult.82

81 This similarity or intersection of arguments shows that market intransparency identfied with imperfect

information can be thought of as a sort of supra-characteristic that becomes relevant in situations whereinformation become relevant.

82 OECD (1999), p. 29.

48

The above arguments on the role of innovation are similar to those concerning barriers to

entry and expansion. This highlights that the absence of innovation is very important for

coordination to be sustainable.

In this context of business cycles and collusive behaviour, the model of Fershtman and Pakes

(2000) should be mentionned who find that only collusive industries generate price wars.

Hence, price wars that occured in the past can be used as additional indication that there has

been collusion in the industry.

3.5.5 Low buyer power

Buyer power is generally recognised as a countervailing force to destabilise collusion among

a small group of sellers. Powerful and concentrated buyers might be able to induce

competition among their suppliers by providing a sufficient incentive for a member of the

oligopoly to deviate from coordinated behaviour. For example, if an order from a single

buyer is important enough, each member of the oligopoly will be under strong pressure to

make a competitive offer before any other oligopolist does.83

There are two other possibilities of powerful buyers to constrain the oligopolists:84 first, (the

threat of) vertical integration upstream to counteract collusive behaviour of suppliers and,

second, (the threat of) inducing entry into the upstream market by sponsoring a new entrant

or by committing to a certain volume of purchases from the new firm.

3.5.6 Low price elasticity in the sub-market composed of the leading firms' products

Ceteribus paribus, a lower price elasticity of demand for the leading firms products'

translates into greater incentives to engage in coordination and lower incentives to cheat.85

3.5.7 Multi-market contact

It appears that the incentive to cheat is larger with multiple markets, as more can be gained if

cheating occurs simultaneously in all markets. On the other hand, punishment is also more

severe since the gains from cheating in one market can more easily be wiped out by

punishments in all markets. Hence, when deciding whether to deviate or not, firms might

fear the possibility of a general warfare.

83 See OECD (1999), p. 30.84 Ross and Baziliauskas (2000).85 Kantzenbach et al. (1995), pp. 15-16. Contrary to a low price elasticity of demand for the leading firms'

products, a low individual elasticity of demand of each of those firms means a higher degree of productdifferentiation facilitating collusion (see above 3.5.2).

49

Due to Bernheim and Whinston (1990), firms can pool the sustainability criteria over several

markets, i. e. they can transfer slack in the sustainability condition from one market to

another. It is feasible that in one market the discount factor is well above the minimum value

required for stable collusion, whereas in another market the discount factor is too low to

sustain collusion. If firms operate in both markets, collusion might be extended to both

markets.86 Additionally, multi-market contacts allow firms to obtain additional information

about their competitors which make it easier to engage in coordination.87

Evans and Kessides (1994) examined the impact of multi-market contact on domestic pricing

in the U.S. airline industry. They show that airline fares are higher in those city-pair markets

served by airlines with extensive contacts across different routes. This result is consistent

with the view that airlines are less likely to price aggressively on a route for fear of reprisals

on other routes and fits in with the above theoretical analysis.

3.5.8 Excess capacity

As already illustrated in the model of Compte et al., excess capacity has an ambiguous effect

on the sustainability of collusion depending on its distribution: If firms have excess capacity,

they can gain more from cheating. But, if their rivals have excess capacity, they can easily

punish the deviator.

In the model of Davidson and Deneckere (1990), investment in capacity is followed by tacit

collusion and an infinitely repeated pricing game. Their result indicates a positive correlation

between the effectiveness of collusion and the level of industry and excess capacity.

However, if only one firm invests into capacity, committing itself to this capacity and hence

making capacities more asymmetric, this might make collusion less likely.88

3.6 Facilitating practices and structural links

In addition to - more or less exogenous - structural market factors that facilitate collusion,

there are practices and business strategies (i. e. conduct) which firms can adopt and which

are likely to contribute to meeting the six conditions outlined previously. They can be

grouped under two headings: facilitating practices (3.6.1) and structural links (3.6.2).

86 For an example see Tirole (1998), p. 251.87 Kantzenbach et al. (1995), pp. 73-74.88 See e. g. the reasoning of the EC Commission in Pilkington-Techint/SIV, case IV/M.358, (1994) OJ

L158/24.

50

3.6.1 Facilitating practices

Facilitating practices are schemes adopted by firms, either individually or industry-wide,

which increase the probability of an implicit agreement by stimulating the contact between

them and/or by creating focal points (reaching a "meeting of the minds"), aiding the

detection of cheating, increasing the severity of punishment or decreasing the response time

for punishment. Some examples of facilitating practices can be grouped as follows:89

Main mechanism to facilitate

collusion

Facilitating practice

Helping to reach an understanding - Exchange of information90

- Cheap talk (e. g. public speeches)91

- Standardisation

Helping to detect deviations - Exchange of information

- Meeting competition clauses92

Helping to punish deviations - Resale price maintenance

- Most-favoured-customer clauses

In collusion cases, mainly the exchange of information is used as evidence. Whereas it

serves as direct evidence when using ex-post-instruments targetted at coordinated conduct,

structure-oriented merger control can use such communication - like any other evidence of

prior or current coordination - only as indication that market conditions are currently

favourable to collusion (see below 3.7).

3.6.2 Structural links

In contrast to facilitating practices, structural links can be identified more easily and used as

indication for coordination in merger control. In particular, in EC competition law, there has

89 See Europe Economics (2001), p. 41; for a more extensive overview on facilitating practices and detailed

explanations of their effects see OECD (1999), pp. 237-242.90 The degree of exchange of information and the evidence on this exchange determines whether the

coordinated conduct is legally qualified as explicit or tacit collusion.91 See above 3.2.92 In a contract between a buyer and a seller, a meeting competition clause (MCC) ensure the buyer that he

will not be paying a price above that asked by other competing sellers. This converts buyers into monitorsof coordinated interaction (OECD (1999), p. 28). Moreover, MCCs lower the incentive of firms to undercuttheir prices as they know that their prices as they know that their rivals are contractually obliged to lowertheir own prices (see Salop (1986)).

51

been a discussion whether structural links between oligopolists are a necessary condition for

joint dominance from the legal point of view (see below 5.1.3 and 5.2.2.6).

On a scale reflecting cooperation, structural links are located between facilitating practices

and a merger: Contrary to facilitating practices, they are formal agreements which lead firms

to cooperate in some field of their activity such that the objective function of each partnering

firm will partly reflect the welfare of its partners, while at the same time falling short of a

merger (see above 3.2). Examples are partial cross shareholding, inter-locking directorships,

cooperative R&D agreements, joint ventures and shared ownership of suppliers or

distribution channels.

By reducing the number of independent decision makers and introducing an element of joint

profit maximisation, structural links create a greater similarity of interest. In addition to the

shift of behaviour towards joint-profit-maximisation, structural links make firms more

transparent to rivals and allow them to come into closer contact to each other.

However, with respect to incentives, particularly cross ownership provides for a trade-off:

On the one hand, it reduces the gain from cheating since some of the gains accrue to rivals.

On the other hand, it softens the punishment since some of the penalty is borne by rivals.

Overall, in particular when emphasising the importance of mutual learning and common

industry "culture", structural links facilitate collusion. However, they are not a necessary

condition for collusion. Hence, in turn, the condition that structural links between

oligopolists have to be cut, which is a typical remedy in coordinated effects cases, is not

sufficient to eliminate the risk of collusion.

3.7 Evidence of current coordination

Evidence of prior or current coordinated conduct is used by all competition authorities in

merger control (particularly by the U.S. authorities, see below 6.4.3). However, as alluded

above (3.6.1), this has to be done with caution: Competition authorities have to assess how

the merger changes the game, i. e. to estimate the risk of future coordinated conduct on the

basis of the future market structure. Evidence of prior or current collusion only allows for the

conclusion of future coordination if the merger leaves the likelihood of coordinated effects

unchanged or even increases it. However, it has to be kept in mind that a merger (though

increasing concentration) might decrease the likelihood of coordination (for example if it

creates a maverick), i. e. it might change the game such that current coordination will be

brought to an end.

52

In most cases, where evidence on collusion is available, such evidence will consist of

communication between the colluding firms. Even without taking into account that a merger

changes the game, it might be wrong to conclude from such past explicit collusion that there

is a risk of future tacit collusion:

When deciding whether to collude, firms take into account the gains from collusion (see

equation (6)). These gains are determined to some extent by the costs of reaching a (tacit)

agreement. These costs, in turn, depend on the trade-off that a firm faces when deciding

whether to use express communication (explicit collusion) or not (tacit collusion): By using

communication, the costs of finding a common equilibrium are reduced, but at the same time

the risk of being detected and fined should be increased (see above 3.1.2.4.1). Depending on

the solution of the trade-off, four outcomes are possible: First, there is no collusion at all

because both explicit and tacit collusion are prohibitively costly. Second, only explicit

collusion fulfills the condition for collusion (equation (6)). Third, only tacit collusion is

sustainable (for instance because of a high detection probability concerning explicit

collusion due to very efficient monitoring by the antitrust authority in combination with high

fines). Fourth, either explicit or tacit collusion constitutes the optimal solution of the trade-

off, but in both cases, collusion is sustainable.

Hence, in the second case, where finding an equilibrium by "meeting of the minds" is

prohibitively costly, it would be wrong to draw a conclusion from explicit collusion to the

risk of tacit coordination.

Despite these restrictions, prior collusion can be seen as a natural experiment which helps to

find out how the industry works and in particular whether entry is easy:93 If there has been

collusion and no firm entered despite prise increases, one can conclude that there are (still)

considerable barriers to entry in the industry (if technology has not changed).

3.8 Relative importance of the market characteristics

Economic models draw conclusions about a subset of factors by keeping all others constant.

Therefore, no conclusion about the relative importance of several factors can be drawn from

one model. Also, in practice, it seems to be generally accepted that it is very difficult, if not

impossible, to give a clear ranking of the above market characteristics.94

93 See an interview with Michael Katz, the DoJ's chief antitrust economist, American Bar Association Section

of Antitrust Law "Brown Bag Program", 5 December 2001 (available at<http://www.antitrustsource.com>), pp. 16-17.

94 E. g. Shapiro (1995) and OECD (1999) round-table report on oligopoly, Section 3: "none of the factorsconsidered individually can conclusively establish a high probability of coordinated interaction".

53

Nevertheless, the two market characteristics which at the same time constitute necessary

conditions for collusion in the above framework - few firms (and, consequently, high

concentration) and barriers to entry and expansion - could be used to construct safe

harbours.95 Both the German Checklist and the U.S. Merger Guidelines point into this

direction by attributing a central role to concentration and entry barriers (see below 4.2.4.5

and 6.4.4).

From economic theory, one cannot conclude that a stable demand is a necessary condition

like concentration and entry barriers. However, if the market is characterised by high growth,

high volatility and uncertainty, firms' ability to coordinate on, monitor and enforce a

collusive equilibrium is severely impeded. Hence, at least, stable demand should be singled

out as very important factor.

Furthermore, as important should be regarded a certain degree of product homogeneity

(although already "included" in the market definition) and of market transparency. The same

holds for the absence of mavericks, a strong fringe and sophisticated large buyers.

3.9 Policy implications

Given the relative importance of the above factors, some rules for the assessment of

coordinated effects or collective dominance cases respectively can be established:

1. If there are more than five leading firms in the market or if there are no (significant)

barriers to entry, competition authorities should not start to investigate a merger on

grounds of coordinated effects.

2. Otherwise, an investigation should be carried out. It should include demand conditions,

product homogeneity, market transparency, mavericks, the fringe and the buyers. If

demand conditions turn out to be unstable, the merger should be cleared, unless the other

market factors do not point into the other direction.

3. If these important market factors - as will typically be the case - do not point into one

direction, the competition authority should further examine the other less important

factors mentioned above. Particularly, in these complex cases, the assessment should

contain an analysis of the interaction of the market factors which should be based on a

sound understanding of the respective industry.

Despite these substantive guidelines, there remains much discretion for competition

authorities. This suggests two additional procedural safeguards:

95 OECD (1999), p. 21.

54

4. There should be clear guidelines on the assessment of coordinated effects in merger

control. These will - although issued by competition authorities themselves and although

possibly not legally binding - increase transparency and, hence, constitute a (self-)binding

of the competition authority.

5. Especially in merger cases, judicial review by courts should be as swift as possible in

order to constrain the bargaining position of the competition authority.

Whether and to what extent the German, EC and U.S. merger control regimes correspond to

the above normative framework, will be explored in the following sections 4, 5 and 6. Each

of these sections contains an analysis of the law and the (alleged) policy towards coordinated

effects or collective dominance respectively. Reference will be made to case law in order to

check whether and how the abstract approach is applied in reality. In addition, for each

merger regime, two recent cases will be presented in more detail.

55

4 COLLECTIVE DOMINANCE IN GERMAN MERGER CONTROL

"Oligopoly does not feature prominently in the decision-making practice of the Bundeskartellamt. This is true,

in particular, of prohibitions in the field of merger control."

Bundeskartellamt (1999)96

There are two reasons why the BKartA - in comparison to the European Commission and the

FTC and the DoJ - might block relatively few mergers on grounds of collective dominance:

First, the underlying concept of collective dominance might be more narrow than in the EC

and the U.S.. This is going to be explored below. Second, as pointed out in the introduction,

oligopolies, in particular due to economies of scale, involve few large firms which often

have a high turnover. Since merger cases are allocated between the EC and its Member

States on the basis of turnover thresholds (see Article 1 Merger Regulation),97 the

distribution of mergers investigated by national competition authorities might be biased

towards "smaller" mergers involving relatively few oligopolistic dominance cases.

4.1 GWB (Act against Restraints of Competition)

Starting point for the assessment of a merger is § 36(1) GWB which states:"A concentration which is expected to create or strengthen a dominant position shall be

prohibited by the Federal Cartel Office unless the participating undertakings prove that the

concentration will also lead to improvements of the conditions of competition, and that these

improvements will outweigh the disadvantages of dominance."98 (emphasis added)

Usually, in practice, the Bundeskartellamt - like the European Commission - first assesses

whether a single dominant position is created or strenghtened. If this is not the case,

collective dominance is assessed.

4.1.1 The definition of collective dominance

§ 19(2)2 GWB gives the following definition of collective dominance:

96 OECD (1999), p. 139; see also Emmerich (1999), p. 315 ("... Bedeutung der Oligopolklausel im Rahmen

der Fusionskontrolle bisher gering geblieben").97 The turnover thresholds and the allocation of cases are currently under review (see the Commission's Green

Paper (2001), pp. 10-19).98 Quotation according to the official English translation by the Bundeskartellamt.

56

"Two or more undertakings are dominant insofar as no substantial competition exists between

them with respect to certain kinds of goods or commercial services and they jointly satisfy the

conditions of sentence 1." (emphasis added)

§ 19(2)1 GWB defines a single dominant position:"An undertaking is dominant where, as a supplier or purchaser of certain kinds of goods or

commercial services, it

1. has no competitors or is not exposed to any substantial competition, or

2. has a paramount market position in relation to its competitors; ..."

4.1.2 Legal constructions and economic meanings

The dominance test builds upon the idea of independence of one market participant: One

firm cannot be effectively constrained by its actual or potential competitors and, hence,

dominates the market. As was pointed out above (2.1.7), this approach can be (at least)

reconciled with the economics of unilateral effects.

In order to capture coordinated effects, the dominance test needs the legal construction of

"joint dominance": The notion of "dominance" or "independence" respectively is maintained

by regarding the colluding firms as group which dominates the market. Both the reference to

sentence 1 in § 19(2)2 GWB ("jointly satisfy the conditions of sentence 1") and the notion of

"external competition" take this construction of joint dominance 'too serious' insofar as they

imply the notion of an "oligopolistic entity". Economically, the "dominance" or

"independence" of the collusive firms corresponds to the absence of significant fringe firms

and potential competitors. Hence, it would be sufficient to talk of barriers to expansion

(capacity constraints) and to entry.

Additionally, to capture coordination, § 19(2)2 GWB requires that there is no competition

between the oligopolists (so-called internal competition). Hence, trying to rationalise

economically the legal distinction between "internal" and "external competition" would

mean to identify "internal competition" with the five other necessary conditions of collusion

(i. e. except barriers to entry; see above 3.4) and the market characteristics (see above 3.5)

which contribute to them (first approach).

A second approach to align § 19(2)2 GWB with the economic framework in section 3 would

be to assume that the absence of internal competition captures all necessary conditions of

collusion. Consequently, there would be no additional problem in showing the lack of

57

external competition since an oligopolistic group which fulfills all these conditions will

typically have a dominant position towards the fringe.99

Analysing its revised 2000 Guidelines for Merger Control Procedures (in the following

referred to as Guidelines),100 it is particularly interisting to see whether the BKartA adopts

one of the two above approaches and succeeds in breaking down the notions of "internal"

and "external competition" into a practical framework for the assessment of collective

dominance which comes close to the economic framework set out in section 3.

4.2 Guidelines for Merger Control Procedures ("Auslegungsgrundsätze")

In Section II of its Guidelines, the BKartA outlines how it assesses collective dominance in

merger control:

4.2.1 Underlying economics101

Citing the research by Kantzenbach, Kottmann and Krüger (1996), the Guidelines explicitly

recognise that modern oligopoly theorie is based on industrial economics which rests on

game theory. With respect to collusive effects, the Guidelines state that both game theory

and case law have worked out a number of factors which might facilitate a collusive

outcome. Referring to section 2.1 of the U.S. Horizontal Merger Guidelines, the German

Guidelines highlight the potential for punishment ("Vergeltungspotenzial") as decisive for

maintaining collusive "discipline". According to the Guidelines, the scope for punishment in

turn depends on several market factors which are set out in a checklist.

In line with the preliminary comparative analysis above (3.2.2) and with the EC and U.S.

approaches, the Guidelines emphasize that the structure-oriented merger control is the

primary instrument to prevent from collusive oligopolies. According to the Guidelines, the

conduct-oriented instruments - the prohibition of concerted practices (set out in § 1 GWB)

and the prohibition of the abuse of a joint dominant position (set out in §§ 19, 20 GWB) -

can often only be applied too late, i. e. after welfare losses have occured over a longer period

due to collusion.

99 Mestmäcker/Veelken in Immenga/mestmäcker (2001), GWB § 36 GWB, 172; Rittner (1999), pp. 281-282;

Möschel in Immenga/Mestmäcker, GWB, § 19, 82. For an overview on the different interpretations of"internal" and "external competition" and their distinction see also Möschel in Immenga/Mestmäcker(2001), GWB, § 19, 80.

100 The new version was issued in October 2000 by the Bundeskartellamt. Like notices of the Commission, theGuidelines are not legally binding.

58

4.2.2 Three-step approach

On the basis of § 19(2)2 GWB, the Guidelines set out a three-step approach assessing the

following conditions respectively:

4.2.2.1 Internal competition ("Wettbewerbsbedingungen - Binnenwettbewerb")

First, the BKartA assesses whether there are market characteristics which facilitate

coordinated behaviour. If yes, there is no internal competition between the oligopolists in the

sense of § 19(2)2. In this context, many of the 'usual' market factors are checked (see below

4.2.3).

4.2.2.2 External competition ("Wettbewerbsbedingungen - Aussenwettbewerb")

Second, the BKartA asks whether there is substantial competition from the fringe. Given the

reference to § 19(2)1 GWB, there is no external competition if there is no substantial

competition between the oligopoly and the competitive fringe (case 1) or if the oligopoly has

a paramount market position to the competitive fringe (case 2).

The Guidelines (p. 52) explicity confirm that this corresponds to the assessment of a single

dominant position of the oligopolistic group as entity in relation to the competitive fringe.

According to the Guidelines (p. 52), here the same criteria have to be checked as with regard

to internal competition.

This appears to be superfluous with respect to those factors which characterise the market as

such (for instance, the market is transparent for both the oligopolists (internal) and the fringe

(external)) and which, hence, have already been checked under the heading of "internal

competition". Accordingly, with regard to external competition, the Guidelines (p. 52)

suggest to focus on those factors for which the change of perspective from the oligopolists

(internal) to the fringe (external) makes sense: For example, structural links between the

oligopolists would be checked under the heading of "internal competition", links between the

oligopolists and the fringe would belong to "external competition".

Moreover, according to the Guidelines, the assessment of "external competition" focuses on

the potential of the fringe to compete with the oligopolists (p. 52), i. e. economically in

particular barriers to expansion and entry. This interpretation of "external competition"

points into the direction of the first approach towards § 19(2)2 outlined above (4.1.2).

101 See the Guidelines (2000), pp. 41-43.

59

However, the Guidelines (p. 50) also put barriers to entry under the heading of "internal

competition". This suggests, instead, that the BKartA interpretes the distinction

'internal/external' in the second way which was outlined above.

In practice, the BKartA does not stick to the Guidelines: For example in RWE/VEW the

assessment of external competition completely focused on the fringe players and barriers to

entry (suggesting that the BKartA applies the first approach suggested above). In Shell/DEA,

the distinction 'internal/external' is even not mentioned at all; this also holds for the BKartA's

contribution to the OECD (1999, pp. 135-137).102

Hence, overall, the interpretation of the distinction 'internal/external' by the BKartA remains

unclear and cannot be not completely aligned to the structure of the economic framework set

out in section 3. Although this appears to be unsatisfactory from the point of view of

consistency and transparency, the checklist itself - and this is decisive - is very much in line

with our framework as will be pointed out immediately (4.2.3).

4.2.2.3 Conduct ("Wettbewerbsgeschehen")

Whereas internal and external competition (due to the Guidelines) refer to the market

structure, finally the oligopolists' conduct is assessed, i. e. whether and how the oligopolists

actually use competitive parameters. According to the Guidelines, the oligopolists' conduct

shall serve as an indicator for the first two points. However, it has already been emphasized

(see above 3.6.1) that evidence on past or current coordinated conduct has to be applied with

caution due to the prospective nature of merger control. This is acknowledged by the

BKartA and the courts.103

According to the Guidelines (pp. 55-56), in particular the interaction of market transparency

and conduct and between homogeneity and conduct shall be analysed.

4.2.3 Checklist and case law104

The Guidelines provide a list of market factors which are examined in cases of collective

dominance and which are grouped under the headings of the above three conditions.

Although all factors are assessed in their totality ("Gesamtbetrachtung")105 like in the EC

102 See Mestmäcker/Veelken in Immenga/Mestmäcker (2001), § 36 GWB, 172: "... Unterscheidung [von

Binnen- und Aussenwettbewerb] kommt in der Praxis nur geringe Bedeutung zu."103 See KG WuW/E OLG 3051, 3072, case Morris/Rothmans.104 For an overview on the case law on collective dominance in merger control see Möschel in

Immenga/Mestmäcker (2001), § 19, footnote 576, and Emmerich (1999), pp. 315-316.105 See WuW/E BGH 1824, case Tonolli-Blei- und Silberhütte Braubach (1981).

60

and the U.S., the BKartA regards market shares and barriers to entry as necessary conditions

for coordinated effects and, hence, central criteria of the assessment.106 Additionally, in its

the contribution to the OECD (1999, pp. 137, 139), the BKartA specifies structural links,

market phase and symmetry as very important.

4.2.3.1 Concentration and market shares

In contrast to the European Merger Regulation, the GWB in § 19(3)2 provides for rules of

presumption concerning a joint dominant position:"A number of undertakings is presumed to be dominant if it

1. consists of three or fewer undertakings reaching a combined market share of 50 percent, or

2. consists of five or fewer undertakings reaching a combined market share of two thirds, unless

the undertakings demonstrate that the conditions of competition may be expected to maintain

substantial competition between them, or that the number of undertakings has no paramount

market position in relation to the remaining competitors."

According to its Guidelines (p. 44), the BKartA, referring to the policy of the European

Commission, usually considers only two or three firms to be able to maintain a joint

dominant position.107 Hence, in practice, only § 19(3)2 No. 1 GWB (C3�50%)108 is relevant.

The presumption in § 19(3)2 GWB can be rebutted by showing that there is internal or

external competition. However, since the BKartA has the duty arising from public law to

investigate all relevant facts (Amtsermittlungsgrundsatz), the presumption of § 19(3)2 GWB

becomes relevant only in the (theoretic) cases of non liquet, i. e. where the facts are not

completely convincing evidence of a joint dominant position. The BKartA itself states (p.

46) that the presumption rules are not reliable without additional factors and have been

rebutted in the vast majority of cases. However, due to the presumption, the concentration

screening is the starting point for the assessment like in the U.S. and the EC.109

In addition to the actual figures and the differences between the firms (with regard to

symmetry between the oligopolists), the BKartA assesses fluctuations of market shares over

the last years. If market shares have remained stable this may point to an uncompetitive

oligopoly, in particular, if there have been significant changes in external circumstances

during this time period, such as a substantial drop in demand.

106 Guidelines (2000), p. 53.107 Insofar, the case of Philip Morris/Rothmans (BKartA, WuW/E 2247) in which five leading producers of

cigarettes were held to be collectively dominant constitutes an exception.108 "C" means concentration ratio; C2 is the combined market share of the two largest firms, C3 of the three

largest, etc.109 See Mestmäcker/Veelken in Immenga/Mestmäcker (2001), § 36 GWB, 172.

61

For example in Philips/Lindner, Philips intended to acquire a share in Lindner, a medium-

sized manufacturer of lamps. The BKartA blocked the merger because it would have

strengthened the dominant oligopoly consisting of Philips and Osram arguing, inter alia, that

their market shares had been stable for years.110

4.2.3.2 Symmetry

With regard to symmetry, there has been a change in the policy of the BKartA: Initially, the

BKartA did not block mergers if they made the oligopoly more symmetric111 (in this context,

the term "Aufholfusion" was developed to justify a merger between a small oligopolist and

another small (fringe) firm112). However, in Morris/Rothmans, the Kammergericht

emphasized that a market with symmetric oligopolists might be particulary conducive to

coordination.113 After this judgment of the KG, the BKartA changed its practice.114

Now, with regard to similarity of market shares, capacities, cost structures, financial

resources and access to supply and sale markets, the Guidelines (pp. 47-48) and the

BKartA's contribution to the OECD reflect the economic reasoning as outlined above (see

above 3.2.1.2): Symmetric oligopolies have a stronger tendency towards collusion than

asymmetric ones since "any competitive moves would be equally perceptible to all firms,

easily detectable due to the transparency of competitive

conduct and hardly promising because all the firms have a similary retaliatory potential".115

However, a merger which makes firms more similar does not always increase the likelihood

of collusion: In innovative, expanding markets (with Schumpeterian competition), firms'

incentives are mainly set by expected monopoly profits due to innovation or system

competition and, hence, the relative gains from coordination are low. A merger in such a

market which helps a smaller firm to catch up with the leading firm and, thus, makes it more

symmetric, might even increase competition.

This was acknowledged by the BKartA in Checkpoint/Meto:116 It held that the acquisition of

Meto (market share: 10-15%) by Checkpoint (13-17%) would not create a joint dominant

position by Sensormatic (35-40%) on the expanding market for electronic security systems

for larger stores where three non-compatible systems competed with each other.

110 WuW/E BKartA 2669, 2674, case Lindner Licht GmbH (1994).111 See Tätigkeitsbericht 1979/80, pp. 88-89 (case Tchibo/Reemtsma).112 See Mestmäcker/Veelken in Immenga/Mestmäcker (2001), § 36 GWB, 174.113 See KG WuW/E OLG 3051, 3079 and 3080.114 See Tätigkeitsbericht 1985/86, p. 85 (case NUR/ITS).115 OECD (1999), p. 136.

62

4.2.3.3 Ressources and vertical up- and downstream integration

With respect to this factors, the Guidelines (p. 48) refer to Section I where the assessment of

single dominance is set out. However, this reference does not take into account the different

functions of these factors for single and collective dominance: The stronger the market

leader in comparison with its competitors e. g. with regard to financial ressources, the more

dominant his position. Thus asymmetry with respect to these factors increases the likelihood

of a single dominant position. This also holds for "external competition" under the concept

of collective dominance: If the oligopolistic group is much 'stronger' than the fringe with

respect to ressources and integration, it presumably has a collective dominant position

towards the fringe.

In contrast, the more similar the oligopolists to each other with regard to ressources and

integration, the better coordination and punishment work, i. e. the weaker "internal

competition".

4.2.3.4 Structural links

Both Guidelines and case law show a clear emphasis on interlocks117, both on the merger's

relevant market and on other markets, especially up- and downstream markets. However, the

Guidelines (pp. 48-49) also recognize the insight from above (3.6.2) that structural links are

not a necessary condition for collusion. This is also in line with the EC approach after

Gencor/Lonrho (see below 5.1.3 and 5.2.2.6).

Due to the BKartA's broad definition of "link", apart from interlocking directorates and

capital arrangements, also e. g. a seller-buyer-relationship is captured. In Philips/Lindner, a

cross-licensing agreement between Philips and Osram was considered as sufficient link.

4.2.3.5 Barriers to entry

Barriers to entry are - in line with the economic approach and the U.S. Horizontal Merger

Guidelines - regarded as necessary conditions for collusion by the BKartA118 and,

accordingly, are assessed in each case of collective dominance. A sub-section of section I of

116 Case Checkpoint Systems/Meto B7-173/99, available at <http://www.bkarta.de/B7-173-99.pdf>.117 See OECD (1999), p. 137, and, e. g., case Philips/Lindner, decision of 11 August 1994, WuW/E BKartA

2669, and case RWE/VEW, B8 - 309/99, available at <http://www.bundeskartellamt.de /B8-309-99.pdf>,pp. 52, 59.

118 See the Guidelines (2000), p. 53, which explicitly refer to the U.S. Merger Guidelines.

63

the Guidelines (pp. 25-31), which deals extensively with barriers to entry in the context of

single dominance, distinguishes between legal, structural and strategical barriers.

An example of a legal barrier to entry in the context of collective dominance is provided for

in the case "Bertelsmann/Kirch/Premiere" which concerned the proposed transformation of

the pay-TV channel Premiere into a 50:50 joint venture by CLT/UFA (Bertelsmann) and

KirchGruppe. According to the BKartA, the concentration would have led to a spillover

effect on the free-TV market creating or strengthening a joint dominant position of

CLT/UFA and KirchGruppe on this market. In the TV advertising market, public channels

were considered to constitute no effective constraint due to the regulation of advertising time

that allows them only partially to participate in this market.119

4.2.3.6 Buyer Power on the opposite side of the market

In both its Guidelines (pp. 50-51) and its contribution to the OECD, the BKartA

acknowledges that "relatively large buyers can disrupt the oligopolistic discipline by playing

the members of the oligopoly off against each other and causing them to engage in secret

competition".120 The BKartA also takes into account the potential of a buyer to produce the

good on its own which serves as threat to and, thus, as constraint on the oligopolists (hence,

"internal competition" would be increased).121

4.2.3.7 Market Transparency and homogeneity

In its Guidelines (pp. 55-56) and its practice (see the cases RWE/VEW and Shell/DEA

below), the BKartA acknowledges the above insights (3.5.2, 3.5.3) that market transparency

and product homogeneity facilitate collusion.

The fact that both market characteristics are put under the heading of “conduct”

(Wettbewerbsgeschehen) shows that the BKartA especially takes into account practices of

firms which increase transparency and – vice versa -, in the case of homogeneity, which lead

to product differentiation.

119 BKartA, WuW/E DE-V 53, 61 (1998).120 OECD (1999), p. 137.121 See BKartA's decision of 11 February 2000, Dürr/Alstom, p. 11 (available at <http://www.

bundeskartellamt.de>).

64

4.2.3.8 Market phase

Also with respect to market phase, the Guideline's approach (pp. 52-53) is in line with

economic theory (3.5.4): The BKartA acknowledges that dynamic markets, which are

characterised by rapid change of technology, innovation competition and market growth, are

less conducive to coordination than mature and stagnant markets.

However, it is unclear how much weight the BKartA attaches precisely to this factor in

practice since there seems to be no clear-cut case in the past in which demand conditions

were unstable, but all other factors suggested that the market is conducive to coordination.

This also holds for the EC Commission and its case law.

The case Checkpoint/Meto (see above 4.2.3.2), in which system competition in an expanding

market played a decisive role, suggests that the factor is regarded as very important also in

practice.

4.2.4 Comparison with economic framework

Overall, the BKartA’s checklist is very much in line with the economic framework set out in

section 3. As will become clear in the following sections, this also holds for the analytical

frameworks of the EC Comission, the FTC and the DoJ.122

However, particularly in contrast to the U.S. Horizontal Merger Guidelines, the German

checklist does not relate the market characteristics to the necessary conditions of

coordination like the framework presented in section 3. Hence, the interdependence of the

different factors is not worked out clearly.

4.3 Cases

Given its two recent prominent cases of RWE/VEW (2000) and Shell/DEA (2001) which are

going to be presented in the following the BKartA would probably not repeat its 1999

statement quoted in the beginning. However, at least the case Shell/DEA does not contradict

the hypothesis that the distribution of mergers investigated by national competition

authorities might be biased towards "smaller" mergers involving relatively few oligopolistic

dominance cases: The concentration met the thresholds of Article 1 MR, but the

Commission partly referred the case to the BKartA.123

122 See the summarising table in Section 7.123 The Commission may refer a case to a national competition authority under Article 9 MR (the so-called

"German clause").

65

4.3.1 RWE / VEW124

Since the European Commission parallely investigated the merger of VEBA and Viag and

harmonized its conditions and obligations with those which were imposed on RWE/VEW by

the BKartA, the cases confirm to some extent the conjecture from the introduction that the

approach to coordinated effects converges due to mutual learning of competition authorities.

4.3.1.1 Findings

After the merger, RWE/VEW together with E.ON (the former PreussenElektra AG, a

subsidiary of VEBA, and Bayernwerk AG (VIAG)) would have controlled over 70% of the

German market in electricity supply of major industrial customers and well over 55% of the

market in electricity delivered to private customers. Hence, the merger would have created a

symmetric duopoly fulfilling the presumption of § 19(3)2 No. 1 GWB.125

Expected small growth in demand, low price elasticity and the fact that electricity is a totally

homogeneous and mature product, which is sold on a highly transparent market (production

costs and prices are well-known), all favour coordination.126 Moreover, the duopolists were

symmetric in terms of market shares, cost structures and vertical integration.127 Hence, the

decision explicitly states that price cuts would be easy to monitor and, due to similar

potential to retaliate, unlikely to be successful.128 Finally, there were various structural links

between the duopolists, particularly their holdings in the east German interconnected

company Vereinigte Energiewerke AG (VEAG) and the lignite producer LAUBAG which

additionally created parallel interests and which would facilitate the exchange of

information.129

The counterargument that there were significant price drops before and at the time of the

investigation of the merger was refuted by the BKartA with two arguments: First, the market

was still in the initial phase of the liberalisation process, in which firms were positioning

themselves on the German market and trying to deter from entry into "their" regional or local

sub-market. Second, from the fact that reductions in price happened before the

concentrations took place one cannot draw the conclusion that there would be similar price

124 Decision of 3 July 2000, case RWE/VEW, B8 - 309/99; see <http://www.bundeskartellamt.de /B8-309-

99.pdf>.125 See paras 112-115 of the decision.126 See para 122.127 Para 123.128 Para 129.129 Para 124.

66

competition post merger.130 Hence, the BKartA concluded that no substantial competition

between duopolists could be expected.131

With respect to external competition, the decision puts emphasis on the enormous difference

in market share between on the one side RWE/VEW and E.ON and on the other side EnBW

and HEW and regionally fragmented competitors which in addition partially depend on the

supply by the duopolists. Explicitly, the decision states that EdF/EnBW might have

ressources to compete with the duopolists. But as long as there are no other larger potential

mavericks in the market, it would be very likely that EdF/EnBW abstains from active

competition. Moreover, there are high barriers to entry due to high fixed costs. Additionally,

interconnection fees have to be paid to the duopolists as owner of the transmission networks.

Finally, imports are constrained by restricted interconnection facilities (paras 138, 139).

Hence, the BKartA concludes that there is no substantial external competition.

Overall, the market characteristics assessed by the BKartA in this decision fit in with the

checklist set out in section 3. However, the decision does not exactly relate the market

characteristics to the necessary conditions of coordination.

4.3.1.2 Remedies

The BKartA cleared the merger, but imposed conditions and obligations on RWE/VEW (the

same holds for the Commission in relation to VEBA/VIAG) which had three main goals:

first, the reduction of its market share by disposing of numerous holdings in other

companies; second, the severance of the main links between RWE/VEW and VEBA/VIAG;

third, the creation of a "third force" on the German market for electricity supply. The

condition on RWE/VEW (and VEBA/VIAG) to sell all holdings in VEAG and LAUBAG to

a third party (HEW, which today, together with VEAG and BEWAG, constitutes the "third

force") served all three goals.

However, by assuming that RWE and E.ON have a joint dominant position in the case of

E.ON/Ruhrgas (2002), the BKartA itself conceded that the conditions and obligations could

not prevent from collective dominance on the German power market.

130 Paras 131, 132.

67

4.3.2 Shell / DEA132

Shell and DEA (DEA Mineralöl is a 100-percent subsidiary of RWE) intended to combine

their downstream oil and petrochemicals business in a joint venture. The agreement foresees

that Shell will take sole control of DEA from 1 July 2004 at the latest. Due to the acquisition

of DEA by Shell and the merger of BP and Aral (a subsidiary of VEBA Oil), which was

registered shortly afterwards, Shell/DEA, BP/Aral and Esso would have reached a combined

market share of 61% on the German market for supply of petrol at filling stations. Hence,

according to the presumption of § 19(3)2 No. 1 GWB, the concentration Shell/DEA would

have created an oligopolistic dominant position. As the BKartA states in its decision, even

without taking into account the merger of BP/Aral, the combined market share of

Shell/DEA, Aral and Esso would have been above 50%.133

The decision checks the usual factors (similar oligopolists, high market transparency, low

price elasticity, stagnant demand, homogeneous good) and concludes that competition

initiated by the oligopolists could not be expected due to easy monitoring and similar

potential of punishment.134 Moreover, structural links (in the form of share holding in the

same refineries and in a pipeline system) create common interests and provide for a

possibility to exchange information.135

Without explicitly paying reference to the distinction of internal and external competition,

the BKartA states that the next largest competitors Total-FinaElf and Conoco are too small

to constrain coordination. According to the decision, this also holds for the independent fuel

stations since they heavily depend on the supply of the oligopolists which, in contrast, are

integrated upstream.136

Since the presumption of oligopolistic market dominance was not rebutted by Shell and

DEA, conditions and obligations were imposed on the merging parties.

131 Paras 128, 129.132 Case B8 - 120/01, available at <http://www.bundeskartellamt.de/B8-120-01.pdf>.133 Case Shell/DEA, B8 - 120/01, available at <http://www.bundeskartellamt.de/B8-120-01.pdf>, pp. 15-16.134 P. 18.135 P. 20.136 Pp. 21-23.

68

5 COLLECTIVE DOMINANCE IN EC MERGER CONTROL

"The Commission does not consider that it is necessary to show that the market participants as a result of the

proposed merger would behave as if there were a cartel, with a tacit rather than explicit cartel agreement. In

particular, it is not necessary to show that there would be a strict punishment mechanism."

EC Commission, Airtours decision, 22 September 1999137

"... the Court concludes that the [Commission's] Decision [in Airtours], far from basing its prospective

analysis on cogent evidence, is vitiated by a series of errors of assessment as to factors fundamental to any

assessment of whether a collective dominant position might be created."

Court of First Instance, Airtours judgment, 6 June 2002138

Article 2(3) of the Merger Regulation which came into force in 1990 provides that:"A concentration which creates or strengthens a dominant position as a result of which effective

competition would be significantly impeded in the common market or a substantial part of it shall

be declared incompatible with the common market." (emphasis added)

The term "dominant position" is not defined in the Merger Regulation. So far,139 the

Regulation lacks, in particular in comparison to Article 82 EC, an explicit reference to

dominance by "one or more undertakings". Because of this "oligopoly blind spot" in the

Merger Regulation, the law governing the assessment of oligopolistic dominance in merger

control had to be developed by the Commission and the European courts, i. e. the Court of

First Instance (CFI) and the European Court of Justice (ECJ).

Consequently, the best access to the concept of collective dominance - like to European

(competition) law in general - is via landmark cases which will be presented first (see below

5.1). Special attention is paid to the Airtours case (5.1.4) since the case can be interpreted as

focus of the general problems of the European approach. Moreover, the recent CFI judgment

sets important limits to the concept of joint dominance. Additionally, the recent parallel

cases of UPM-Kymmene/Haindl and Norske Skog/Parenco/Walsum will be discussed

137 Commission decision of 22 September 1999, Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, available at

<http://www.europa.eu.int>, para 150.138 Judgment of 6 June 2002, Airtours v. Commission, Case T-342/99, available at <http:www.curia.eu.int>,

para 294.139 See below 7. .

69

(5.1.5) because they raised the general question whether coordination on long-term variables

like capacities is sustainable.

Then, the European approach to oligopolistic dominance in merger controll will be analysed

in abstracto (5.2). So far, in contrast to Germany and the U.S., no EC Merger Guidelines

exist. Hence, one has to rely on extracts of the case law and unofficial statements, in

particular a Commission contribution to the OECD (1999), a Commission working

document on the telecommunications sector140 and a statement by Commission members.141

5.1 Development142 - from Nestlé / Perrier to Airtours / First Choice

During the first year after the entering into force of the Merger Regulation, the Commission

applied the Regulation exclusively to prevent mergers that led to a single firm dominance.

The Commission considered the presence of other large firms on the market as constraint on

a single dominant position rather than as risk with regard to a collective dominant

position.143

Emerging concern of the Commission that a merger can lead to coordinated effects can be

found in its Varta/Bosch decision where it noted that"the existence of an equally strong competitor could lead for several reasons to alignment of the

behaviour of both competitors. In particular the absence of other large competitors able to

counter any alignment of the behaviour of the main competitors on the ... market is noted."144

In 1992, the merger of Alcatel/AEG Kabel created an oligolistic market with three

significant firms on the German power cable market which is characterised by, inter alia,

industrial maturity, static demand and product homogeneity. In its decision, the Commission

rejected a request by the Bundeskartellamt to apply a 'German version' of the concept of

collective dominance by stating:"[Unlike German merger control law, the Merger Regulation] does not contain a legal

presumption of the existence of a collective dominant oligopoly as soon as certain companies

attain a certain combined market share. ... Under the Regulation, such a presumption which

amounts to a reversal of the burden of proof does not exist. On the contrary, the Commission

would have to demonstrate in all cases that effective competition could not be expected on

140 Commission Working Document On Proposed New Regulatory Framework for Electronic Communications

Networks and Services (2001), paras 77-93.141 Christensen and Rabassa (2001). Since this article is the attempt to justify the Airtours decision by its case

handler, it will be dealt with in the context of the decision (see 5.3.1).142 An in-depth overview on the early cases is given by Morgan (1996).143 See e. g. Renault/Volvo, Case IV/M.004, (1990) OJ C281/2, where the Commission cleared the merger

because the post-merger firm would not dominate its rivals such as Mercedes and Iveco, but did not discussthat the merger created an oligopoly.

144 Varta/Bosch, Case IV/M.012, (1991) OJ L320/26.

70

structural grounds between the leading companies in a highly concentrated market." (emphasis

added)145

The last sentence of the quotation shows that the Commission was ready to introduce

collective dominance under the Merger Regulation, but was waiting for a clear-cut case.

5.1.1 Nestlé / Perrier (1991)146

Shortly after the Court had finally accepted the concept of collective dominance under

Article 82 EC,147 such a clear-cut case seemed to have arrived with the notification of the

merger Nestlé/Perrier. By widening the interpretation of the notion of "dominance" in

Article 2(3) MR, the Commission introduced joint dominance into EC merger control.

The most important facts of the case have already been outlined above (see 3.2.2) when

discussing the role of symmetry. Whereas the Commission did not consider properly

symmetry and the effects of its condition, the split-off of Volvic to BSN, it applied notions

and a checklist of criteria suggested by game theory as outlined in section 3: Inter alia, the

Commission found that the 3-2 merger would make anti-competitive parallel behaviour

much easier and explicitly referred to the possibility of "immediate detection of any

deviation ... of the expected performance". According to the decision, "tacit coordination" of

pricing policies was facilitated by transparent prices, a low price elasticity of demand,

mature technology, high barriers to entry and an insignificant competitive fringe.148 In

addition to these structural factors, the Commission found that the oligopolists had acted

together to deter the entry of a third party into the market.

The decision was appealed, but not on issues related to collective dominance with the

consequence that the Commission had to wait until the ECJ's judgment in Kali&Salz to get

confirmation for its use of the concept of collective dominance.

5.1.2 Kali & Salz / MdK (1993, 1998)149

The case concerned a proposed joint venture between Kali&Salz (K&S), a subsidiary of

BASF, and the Treuhandanstalt by which the potash and rock-salt businesses of K&S would

be combined with those of the former East German producer, Mitteldeutsche Kali AG

145 Alcatel/AEG Kabel, Case IV/M.0165, (1992) OJ C6/23, para 22.146 Commission decision of 22 July 1992, Nestlé/Perrier, Case IV/M.0190, (1992) OJ L356/01.147 In Società Italiana Vetro SpA and Others v. Commission, Joined Cases T-68/89, T-77/89 and T-78/89,

(1992) ECR II-1403, para 358.148 Nestlé/Perrier, Case IV/M.0190, (1992) OJ L356/01, paras 119-131.149 For detailed comment on the case see Ysewyn and Caffarra (1998) and Venit (1998).

71

(MdK). The Commission150 found that the merged entity and the French producer SCPA

would hold a collective dominant position in the market for potash in the EC excluding

Germany and, hence, declared the merger compatible only subject to conditions and

obligations (offered as commitments by the parties).

On appeal of the parties, the ECJ confirmed that the Merger Regulation applies to joint

dominance and confers on the Commission "a certain discretion, especially with respect to

assessments of economic nature".151 Apart from the asymmetries between the firms and the

ability of third parties to exercise competitive constraint on the parties, the ECJ,

paradoxically, annulled the Commission's decision because of the absence of structural links

between the parties although the Commission had put most effort on proving "exceptionally"

close links between K&S and SCPA.

5.1.3 Gencor / Lonrho (1996, 1999)

The merger was the first one which was blocked completely by the Commission on grounds

of collective dominance.152 It would have brought together the platinum and rhodium mines

of two producers in South Africa (Implats, owned by Gencor, and Eastplats/Westplats,

owned by Lonrho's LPD) into a joint venture and would have led to a symmetric duopoly of

Gencor/Lonrho and Amplats with market shares for each of the duopolists of about 35% of

the world market.

The Commission's decision was entirely upheld by the CFI153 which made two important

statements: First, the CFI ended the debate about structural links and stated that the existence

of "structural links" between the remaining undertakings in a market is neither a necessary

nor sufficient condition for the existence of joint dominance after a merger.154 Second, the

market factor of (price) transparency was pointed out to be fundamental for the detection and

punishment of cheating.155

150 Commission decision of 14 December 1993, Kali&Salz/MdK/Treuhand, Case IV/M.0308, (1994) OJ

L186/38.151 Judgment of 31 March 1998, France and others v. Commission, Joined Cases C-68/94 and C-30/95, (1998)

ECR-I-1453, para 223.152 Commission decision of 24 April 1996, Gencor/Lonrho, Case IV/M.0619, (1997) OJ L11/30.153 Judgment of 25 March 1999, Gencor v. Commission, Case T-102/96, (1999) CMLR 971. For comments on

the judgment see Korah (1999).154 Gencor v. Commission, Case T-102/96, para 276; see also para 273.

72

5.1.4 Airtours / First Choice (1999, 2002)

In its decision in Airtours/First Choice, which led to the recent landmark judgment by the

CFI, the Commission tried to increase the scope of the concept of collective dominance in

three ways:

First, giving up its previous 'duopoly policy', the Commission, for the first time, blocked a

merger since it would have created a joint dominant position consisting of three firms. In

general, this is in line with economic theory (see above 3.4.1) and has not been criticised by

CFI.

Second, the Commission attempted to abolish the game theoretic mechanism of tacit

collusion as underlying concept of collective dominance, in particular with respect to the

punishment mechanism. Third, the concept was applied to a market which, at least at first

sight, did not lend itself easily to collusion. With regard to the last two points, the CFI

quashed the Commission's decision.

5.1.4.1 The Commission's decision (1999)156 - shifting the goalposts

The acquisition of First Choice (market share: 11%) by Airtours (21%) would have left three

major vertically integrated travel groups in the UK short-haul foreign package holiday

market, the other two being Thomson (27%) and Thomas Cook (20%). In its decision, the

Commission - in addition to the market shares - pointed out that the HHI would increase

from 1700 by more than 450 points to more than 2150 as a result of the merger.157

However, the HHI is an instrument which is derived from unilateral effects theory and which

punishes asymmetry (see above 2.1.5). As pointed out above (see 3.2.1.1), concentration

increases the scope of coordinated effects in a distinct way than it increases the scope of

unilateral effects. Hence, for unilateral effects cases, it is appropriate that the Commission

increasingly uses the HHI in addition to market shares. In coordinated effects cases,

however, the number of the firms and their (combined) market shares seem to be more

appropriate than the HHI.

Additionally, the Commission argues that the decrease in the number of major competitors

from four to three would reduce the number of competitive relationships by half - from six to

three - and that the number of bilateral links in which one of the major parties would not

participate would fall from three to one. This argument is even better suited than market

155 Gencor v. Commission, Case T-102/96, para 227.156 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524.157 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, para 139.

73

shares to indicate to what extent the costs of coordination and monitoring are reduced by the

merger.

Moreover, according to the Commission, First Choice would be lost as supplier and

distributor for the fringe.158 From these observations and the result of its checklist - which

included product homogeneity, low demand growth, low price sensitivity, similar cost

structures, transparency, interdependency and structural links, barriers to entry, no buyer

power, past competition - the Commission drew the conclusion that, post-merger, the

interdependency between the parties and the transparency of the market would be reinforced,

as would the incentive to coordinate.

However, an important particularity of the market is that operators' capacity plans are

typically fixed 12 to 18 months ahead of the holiday season, and few adjustments can be

made afterwards.159 Hence, the Commission's argument was essentially that, post-merger,

the major foreign package holiday operators would have an incentive to keep capacity tight

and thereby increase price: "... any decision by a tour operator to try to increase market share

by increasing capacity ... will lead to a fall in prices unless competitors reduce their share by

an equivalent amount by cutting supply."160 So far, this argument reflects the obvious insight

that every firm would like to raise prices in order to increase profits. But the decisive

question is whether firms are able to achieve this, in the case of coordination by means of the

threat of punishment.

Consequently, Airtours' economic advisors explicitly put forward that a punishment

mechanism is a necessary condition for coordination.161 However, according to Airtours,

immediate punishment is unlikely since capacity can only be increased marginally during a

season. A punishment in a later season could in principle take place through a large increase

in capacity for the following season. However, this is not very likely because it will inflict a

lower cost due to discounting and because the association between deviation and punishment

will be blurred.162

In an apparent attempt to (ab)use the discretion granted by the CFI in Gencor/Lonrho,163 the

Commission, dealing with Airtours' arguments, stated that "where, as in the present case,

158 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, para 140 et seq.159 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, paras 143, 144.160 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, para 66.161 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, para 148; D. Neven and K. Binmore acted as economic advisors to

Airtours.162 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, para 149.163 See e. g. Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, footnote 94.

74

there are strong incentives to reduce competitive action, coercion may be unnecessary."164

Hence, contrary to the findings of game theory, the Commission did not regard a strict

retaliation mechanism as necessary condition for collective dominance in this case.

5.1.4.2 Critique and interpretation - "collective confusion"165

The major criticism against the Airtours decision is that it dilutes the concept of collusion in

three ways: First, as just pointed out before, it attempts to abandon the necessary condition

of a punishment mechanism. Second, it puts unilateral effects arguments under the heading

of "collective dominance" (5.1.4.2.1). Third, it applies the concept of "collective dominance"

to a market which is not conducive to collusion (see the CFI's judgment, 5.1.4.3.2).

5.1.4.2.1 Unilateral effects in a collective dominance case

In its decision, the Commission states:"... it is not a necessary condition of collective dominance for the oligopolists always to behave

as if there were one or more explicit agreements ... between them. It is sufficient that the merger

makes it rational for the oligopolists, in adapting themselves to market conditions, to act -

individually - in ways which will substantially reduce competition between them, and as a result

of which they may act, to an appreciable extent, independently of competitors, customers and

consumers."166 (emphasis added)

Again, this statement misses the crucial point insofar as firms will find it rational to choose

collusive actions (whether on prices, quantities or even capacities) only if they anticipate that

a punishment awaits them if they do not so. Even more importantly, the statement refers to

unilateral action of the merged entity and the other oligopolists suggesting that the decision

to block the merger relies heavily on unilateral effects.

In an attempt to justify the decision, the case handler in Airtours/First Choice in an article

stated that, in the case,"conceptually the Commission has focused on coordinated effects rather than unilateral effects,

even though it has in reality never been decided whether collective dominance also could arise

due to unilateral effects or whether the degree of coordination in a market could be dependent on

the magnitude of some preliminary unilateral effects." (emphasis added)167

164 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, para 55.165 This is the subtitle of the article by Neven (2000).166 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, para 54.167 Christensen and Rabassa (2001). Contrary to the result of the above analysis, the authors deny the question

asked in the article's title "The Airtours decision: Is there a new Commission approach to collectivedominance?".

75

This could simply be a another circumscription of the possible sequence described above

(2.3) in which the firms first adapt unilaterally to the post-merger environment by raising

prices (unilateral effects) and afterwards find it rational to collude since, with increased

concentration, the individual gains from collusion are higher and the gains from deviation

are lower.

However, if this is the correct interpretation of the above statement, two points have to be

criticised: First, it has to be insisted that still a punishment mechanism is necessary to

overcome the prisoner's dilemma situation. Second, if the Commission wants to block a

merger because of unilateral effects, it should use the concept of single dominance instead of

mixing unilateral and coordinated effects under the heading of "joint dominance".

5.1.4.2.2 Interpretation: two distortions in EC merger control

Motta (1999, 2000) and Neven (2000) suggest a 'structural' explanation for the Commission's

attempt to put unilateral effects under the heading of "collective dominance": As was pointed

out in section 2 (2.1.7), according to Motta, there is a gap in EC merger control concerning

those cases in which unilateral effects are likely, but the merged entity remains below the

40%-market-share-threshold. In his view, there is a second distortion due to the lack of an

efficiency defence.

Motta (1999, 2000) and Neven (2000) interprete the Commission's Airtours decision as the

attempt of a 'second-best solution' which takes these distortions as given: To cope with the

first distortion, the Merger Task Force may be trying to stretch (and hence dilutes) the

concept of collective dominance so that it covers not only tacit collusion, but also market-

wide168 unilateral effects.169 To avoid further distortions, in Motta's view, the Commission

should also explicitly take into account efficiency gains.

Considering the combined market share of Airtours/First Choice (32%, i. e. below the 40%-

threshold), the likelihood of market-wide unilateral effects due to the oligopolistic market

structure in the case and the Commission's reasoning, Motta's and Neven's interpretation fits.

This triggers the question whether the current EC merger regime has to be reformed.

168 Market-wide unilateral effects can arise in the Bertrand model (see above 2.2).169 Hence, in Motta's view, the Commission's decision to block the merger might be correct (because of

unilateral effects), but on the wrong grounds (coordinated effects).

76

5.1.4.2.3 Solutions to eliminate the distortions

A 'first-best' merger framework should avoid a mixture of unilateral and coordinated effects

arguments and allow for a clearly separated analysis of the two effects. Considering the

alleged distortions, the Commission in its 2001 Green Paper on the Review of the Merger

Regulation itself asks whether the current substantive test has to be changed:"One of the more specific hypothetical questions that has occasionally been raised about the

reach of the dominance test in the Merger Regulation is the extent to which it would allow for

effective control in some specific situations where firms unilaterally may be able to raise price

and thus exercise market power. ... The argument goes that the SLC-test would be better adapted

to addressing such a situation, in particular if the market characteristics would not be conducive

to a finding of collective dominance." (emphasis added)170

Although the SLC-test seems generally preferable since it coincides with the economics of

unilateral and coordinated effects, it is very similar to the dominance test in its practical

application.171 Most importantly in our context, it is not necessary to introduce the SLC test

to cope with the alleged first distortion. Instead, it would be sufficient to abandon the 40%-

threshold in unilateral effects cases which is not even determined by the Merger Regulation

itself, but used by the Commission as rule of thumb. Hence, lowering the threshold would

only require the approval of the Court. To eliminate the second distortion, an efficiency

defence172 has to be introduced. This would also be a necessary corrective if the 40%-

threshold is abandoned.

Keeping the dominance test has the advantage of avoiding the costs of legal uncertainty

which would be brought about by an introduction of the SLC test in the EC. Finally,

repercussions on Article 82 EC, which rests on the dominance test, are avoided.

5.1.4.3 The CFI's ruling (2002) - shifting back and cementing the goalposts

The CFI's judgment in Airtours/First Choice can be regarded as a milestone in EC

competition law, not only because it was the first time that a European court annulled a

decision to block a merger, but also because it set boundaries to the concept of collective

dominance under the Merger Regulation.

170 Commission (2001), para 166.171 See BKartA (2001).172 For an extensive overview on and analysis of efficiency gains from mergers in theory and efficiency

defences in practice see the study of Röller, Stennek and Verboven (2000) which was carried out on behalfof the European Commission. For a discussion of how to take into account efficiencies in EC mergercontrol see Wirtz (2002).

77

5.1.4.3.1 Necessary conditions for coordination

With regard to the necessity of a retaliation mechanism, the CFI states that it is not necessary

to "prove that there is a specific retaliation mechanism involving a degree of severity"

(emphasis added), i. e. the CFI does not expect the Commission to specify the retaliation

quantitatively. However, the Court does insist that the Commission "must ... establish that

deterrents exist which are such that it is not worth the while of any member of the dominant

oligopoly to depart from the common course of conduct to the detriment of the other

oligopolists",173 i. e. the Commission has to show that collusion is incentive compatible due

to a punishment mechanism.

Most importantly, the CFI sets out three necessary conditions for a finding of collective

dominance:1. "Each member of the dominant oligopoly must have the ability to know how the other

members are behaving in order to monitor whether or not they are adopting the common

policy."

2. "The situation of tacit coordination must be sustainable over time, that is to say, there must be

an incentive not to depart from the common policy on the market. ... The notion of retaliation

in respect of conduct deviating from the common policy is inherent in this condition."

3. "... the Commission must also establish that the foreseeable reaction of current and future

competitors, as well as of consumers, would not jeopardise the results expected from the

common policy."174 (emphasis added)

Conditions 1 and 2 are the same as set out in section 3 (monitoring and enforcement).

Condition 3 paraphrases barriers to entry and expansion which determine the reaction of

current and future competitors and the constraint that the fringe can put on the oligopolists.

Hence, the conditions set out by the CFI with respect to the supply side are essentially the

same as in the economic framework derived in section 3.

With regard to the reaction of the consumers, i. e. the demand side, the CFI emphasizes the

above insight (3.5.6) that a high-cross price elasticity (in combination with low barriers to

expansion) helps the fringe and entrants to destabilise collusion.

5.1.4.3.2 Market characteristics

Overall, the Commission's findings concerning its market factor checklist seem to be guided

by the aim to block the merger, not by the persuasiveness of its evidence. Hence, examining

the Commission's findings in detail, the CFI dissented with the Commission in nearly every

173 Airtours v. Commission, Case T-342/99, para 193.174 Airtours v. Commission, Case T-342/99, para 62.

78

point. Two further examples for the Commission's flawed economic analysis shall be

presented:

5.1.4.3.2.1 Product homogeneity

In its decision, the Commission stated that (short-haul) package holiday products are

"fundamentally similar" since they all involve the packaging of the two key elements travel

and accomodation and they all depend on bulk buying to produce economies of scale and

scope.175 In contrast, the CFI rightly found that package holiday products are differentiated

by destination, departure date and airport, aircraft model, type and quality of accomodation

and length of stay.176

5.1.4.3.2.2 Market transparency

The Commission distinguished between transparency in the planning period when capacity

decisions are made and in the selling season. Capacity levels in the planning period were

believed by the Commission to be transparent due to factors such as that the major tour

operators were publicly quoted companies and would not be able to keep substantial capacity

additions secret, and also that they were likely to be in contact with the same hotels and

shared discussions concerning seat requirements and availability.177 If these arguments

constituted sufficient evidence for transparency, nearly every market would be transparent

enough for coordination.

The CFI held that transparency in the selling season is irrelevant since the crucial capacity

decisions - over which allegedly the collusion took place on - are taken in the planning

period.178 With very detailed arguments179, the CFI quashed the Commission's finding that

the market was transparent: First, taking into account the considerable degree of product

differentiation (there are various categories of package holidays), the CFI doubts the

Commission's allegation that coordination would take place with regard to the total number

of package holidays offered by each operator (para 167). Second, it states that in a market in

which demand is on the whole increasing, but volatile from one year to the next, an

integrated tour operator will have difficulty in interpreting accurately capacity decisions

taken by the other operators.

175 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, para 88.176 Airtours v. Commission, Case T-342/99, para 167.177 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M.1524, para 105.178 Airtours v. Commission, Case T-342/99, para 180.179 Airtours v. Commission, Case T-342/99, paras 157-180.

79

5.1.4.3.3 Implications for future policy

Analysing the CFI's judgment, three general points can be made: First, the CFI reduces the

Commission's discretion with respect to economic considerations considerably. Second,

according to the judgment, it is necessary to set out how the interaction of the various

market factors may create or strengthen a position of collective dominance rather than

'ticking' them. Third, the CFI itself tries to relate its arguments on market factors to the

necessary conditions of collusion as the economic framework in section 3 suggests. Hence,

the judgment also insofar sets standards for further collective dominance cases.

5.1.5 UPM-Kymmene / Haindl and Norske Skog / Parenco / Walsum (2001):

coordination on other parameters than price or output? - the case of capacity

coordination180

Although the Commission has made allegations of coordination over capacity in

Airtours/First Choice181 and a number of other past collective dominance investigations, the

main focus in these cases remained on arguments about coordination of prices or output

decisions. In the recent cases of UPM-Kymmene/Haindl and Norske

Skog/Parenco/Walsum182, two parallel mergers in the newsprint and magazine paper market,

the Commission has carried out for the first time a detailed assessment of the possibility of

capacity coordination.183 The crucial question was whether firms can succeed in coordinating

on the installation of new plants and thereby ensure that capacity remains tight - and prices

high - even if coordination of prices (or output) is unlikely.184

Taking the paper industry as an example, it becomes clear that coordination over capacities

is unlikely at least in certain industries: Paper plant and machinery represent massive

investments.185 An oligopoly would need to find some 'rota' system as a way of coordinating

on the decision which firm is to build the next machine. If anyone deviates, i. e. builds a

machine 'out of rota', rivals would have to punish, i. e. designate someone to bear the

180 See Lexecon (2002).181 In its judgment on Airtours/First Choice, the CFI did not dismiss generally the possibility of capacity

coordination.182 Cases IV/M.2498 and IV/M.2499.183 has to be distinguished from above discussion where capacity constraints were factor that facilitated or

made more difficult collusion.184 The coordination on the installation of new plants has to be clearly distinguished from coordination on

prices or output with the possibility of investing in the installation of a plant like in some truly dynamicmodels (see above 3.3.1.1).

80

investment cost of carrying out the punishment, including low profits for the whole industry.

This threat of retaliation is not credible because the deviating firm is irreversibly commited

to its capacity and, hence, the best response for rivals to the deviation is not to start

punishment by an 'investment war', but to accomodate the deviator.

Hence, coordination of capacities is unlikely if an industry is characterised by large and

irreversible investments, most importantly industries producing commodities, such as steel

or chemicals. This reasoning was accepted by the Commission in the above cases.

5.2 Approach to collective dominance

According to the Commission's contribution to the OECD (1999, p. 216) which corresponds

with other statements and the recent case law, the assessment of whether a merger will lead

to the creation or strengthening of a joint dominant position involves three steps:

1. analysis of the market structure and identification of the oligopolists (5.2.1),

2. analysis of the structural characteristics of the market in order to check whether the

market is conducive to coordination (5.2.2),

3. analysis of the impact of the merger on the competitive relationship between the

oligopolists (5.2.3).186

5.2.1 Identification of the oligopolists and initial screening test

The oligopoly includes all those firms which as a group have the ability to raise prices above

the competitive level and which, if left out, would make it impossible for the others to

achieve the anti-competitive outcome. In order to determine which firms are part of the

oligopoly and which ones part of the fringe, the Commission uses market shares and

differences in market shares as indicators.187

Having analysed the market structure in that way, the Commission appears to apply an initial

screening test based on the number of significant firms and on their combined market shares

in order to find out whether it should spend ressources on a detailed assessment of the next

two steps.

185 E. g. in the newsprint segment, a Euro 300-500 million machine is needed only about once every three to

four years, and machines have very long lives.186 Compare the very similar steps of the BKartA as outlined by Mestmäcker/Veelken in

Immenga/Mestmäcker, § 36 GWB, 172.187 A textbook example would be a market consisting of three large firms with a market share of 25% each and

the rest of the supply is accounted for by ten small suppliers each with 2-3% market share.

81

So far, there is no official statement determining a maximum number of firms and a market

share threshold. However, in Price Waterhouse/Coopers the Commission stated that "from a

general viewpoint, collective dominance involving more than three or four suppliers is

unlikely simply because of the complexity of the interrelationships involved, and the

consequent temptation to deviate ..."188 (emphasis added). This tentative upper-bound of four

coincides with answers from theory (see above 3.4.1). Moreover, in past oligopoly cases, the

collectively dominant firms have generally held at least 60-70% of the market.

5.2.2 Structural market characteristics

Considering both its contribution to the OECD189, statements of (former) members of the

MTF190 and the recent case law, the Commission's checklist contains all market factors

presumably facilitating collusion which were set out in the economic framework above (3.5):

5.2.2.1 Homogeneous goods

Concerning the homogeneity of goods, the Commission's decisions reflect economic theory

(see above 3.5.2). The classification of products as homogeneous is clearest when these refer

to commodities as in Kali&Salz191 and Gencor/Lonrho192. In other cases, the Commission

tried to qualify the degree of homogeneity. It found, e. g., X-ray films to be "essentially

homogeneous" in Agfa-Gevaert and audit services to be "relatively homogeneous" in Price

Waterhouse/Coopers.

The Commission has acknowledged that products can be differentiated by advertising and

branding even where these seem physically homogeneous. However, e. g. in Nestlé/Perrier,

the Commission regarded brand loyalty only as barrier to entry. The Commission did not

examine how brand loyalty might alter consumers' perceptions of the homogeneity which, in

turn, define the degree of homogeneity and, hence, affect the likelihood of coordination by

making it harder to reach an equilibrium or by clouding market transparency.

5.2.2.2 Market transparency

The Commission uses both structural and behavioural characteristics to establish the level of

transparency on a market. For example in Gencor/Lonhro, the Commission established that,

188 Price Waterhouse/Coopers&Lybrand, Case IV/M.1016, (1998) OJ L50/27, para 103.189 OECD (1999), pp. 217-219.190 Briones and Padilla (2001); Christensen and Rabassa (2001), pp. 231-234.191 Kali&Salz/MdK/Treuhand, Case IV/M.0308, (1994) OJ L186/38, para 57.192 Gencor/Lonrho, Case IV/M.0619, (1997) OJ L11/30, para 138a.

82

structurally, the commodity nature of platinum and the fact that it is traded in a world metal

exchange showed conclusively that its price was transparent.193 In Nestlé/Perrier, regarding

conduct, it found that the major suppliers published standardised price lists that could be

easily compared and also implemented a regular exchange of information.194

5.2.2.3 Mature market

The Commission, in line with economic theory (3.5.4), has drawn a strong link between a

stable level of demand and the likelihood of collective dominance. In Gencor/Lonrho, the

Commission explicitly stated that "a fairly stable market will not encourage new entry or

aggressive moves to capture the growth of the market"195 citing this factor when justifying

its decision. In past cases, collective dominance has been found in markets with low growth

rates of 2-4%.196

Vice versa, also in line with theory, the decline of the size of the potash market in Kali&Salz

led the Court to reason that there would be incentives to compete. At the opposite end,

similar incentives to compete were found by the Commission in a high growth market in

France Telecom/Orange.197 These incentives, inter alia, were regarded to be sufficient to

outweigh the increased likelihood of collusion due to high concentration.

5.2.2.4 Low rate of product and/or process innovation

Similarly, the Commission assumes industries with high rates of product and/or process

innovation unlikely to be conducive to oligopolistic dominance.198

However, according to (former) members of the MTF, product or process innovations which

happen in most markets to a certain extent (like, e. g., the increased use of computer

technology in an industry as an adaption to the normal technological development) are

usually not considered to remove a concern about collective dominance. Instead,

technological changes normally have to be quite fundamental to eliminate the Commission's

concern.199

193 Gencor/Lonrho, Case IV/M.0619, (1997) OJ L11/30, para 144.194 Nestlé/Perrier, Case IV/M.0190, (1992) OJ L356/1, paras 121, 122.195 Gencor/Lonrho, Case IV/M.0619, (1997) OJ L11/30, para 151.196 Christensen and Rabassa (2001), p. 231.197 France Telecom/Orange, Case IV/M.2016, para 40.198 See its contribution to the OECD (1999), p. 218; Christensen and Rabassa (2001), pp. 231-232;

Gencor/Lonrho, Case IV/M.0619, (1997) OJ L11/30, para 151.199 Christensen and Rabassa (2001), p. 232.

83

5.2.2.5 Symmetry of costs and market shares

With regard to symmetry, the Commission tries to gather information not only on

similarities of market shares, but also on similarities of cost structures.200 This approachs is

correct since the latter fundamentally determine the degree of similarity of incentives and

retaliation possibilities. The scale of operations and, hence, market shares depend on these

parameters, but only to some extent. Hence, market shares are only a biased indicator of

costs.

The Commission explicitly relied on an analysis of cost structures in, e. g., Nestlé/Perrier201,

Gencor/Lonrho202 and Airtours/First Choice203.

However, an assessment of costs cannot be found in each case.204 This might be explained

by the fact that, first, gathering and assessing data on costs is much more costly than the

simple comparison of market shares and, second, that there is asymmetric information

between the firms and the competition authority concerning costs (moral hazard) that the

MTF might take into account.205

5.2.2.6 Structural links

After the CFI's judgment in Gencor/Lonrho, structural links between the oligopolists - in line

with theory - are not viewed as necessary condition for coordination, but as facilitating

factor. However, structural links still seem to feature prominently in the Commission's

checklist. One reason for that might be that the condition of cutting such links can be used as

remedy (see above 3.6.2).

In Exxon-Mobil,206 the Commission distinguished the following effects of a structural link

between the competitors:

1. It reduces the incentive to compete,

2. it can give access to commercially sensitive information,

3. it gives a possibility to influence the strategic choices of the competitor, and

4. it can be a vehicle for retaliation.

200 See OECD (1999), p. 218; Christensen and Rabassa (2001), p. 232.201 Nestlé/Perrier, Case IV/M.0190, (1992) OJ L356/1.202 Gencor/Lonrho, Case IV/M.0619, (1997) OJ L11/30, paras 182-185.203 Airtours/First Choice, Case IV/M. 1524.204 E. g. in AKZO Nobel/Hoechst Roussel Vet, Case IV/M.1681, the Commission assessed only the symmetry

of market shares.205 This asymmetric information problem might be smaller than in "single-party" cases (e. g. (alleged)

predatory pricing) since not only the merging party has to submit data on costs, but also the otheroligopolist(s). Hence, if they want to convince the competition authority that their costs are asymmetric,they have to coordinate their submissions, thus facing a cartel problem.

84

Moreover, the Commission seems to qualify the different types of links with regard to their

significance: Ownership ties207 such as cross-holdings are regarded as forming a tighter link

and, hence, more dangerous than membership of a trade association208 or commercial links.

5.2.2.7 Other factors

Other factors which might be assessed include

- excess capacity and its distribution209,

- a low price elasticity of demand210,

- multi-market contact211 and

- the nature of market transactions (i. e. infrequent, non-standard and secret transactions

versus smaller contracts on a frequent and on-going basis)212.

5.2.3 Impact of the merger

Having analysed the environment in which a proposed merger takes place, the Commission

then focuses on the change which would be brought about by the proposed merger, i. e. its

effects on the likelihood of collusion.

5.2.3.1 Past level of competition

The assessment of the merger's impact starts with the past level of competition in order to

determine whether a collective dominant position already existed in the pre-merger market.

If so, the merger might strengthen such a position. If not, the analysis of past competition

serves as starting point for the prognosis whether the merger creates joint dominance. Such

an analysis usually includes

1. past movements in market shares and prices,

2. the past existence of excess capacity and

3. a past history of cooperative behaviour.

With regard to the first point, the Commission, e. g. in AKZO Nobel,213 established that in

some of the affected markets the fluctuating market shares were evidence of competition.

206 Case IV/M.1383, para 480.207 See Gencor/Lonrho, Case IV/M.0619, (1997) OJ L11/30, para 156.208 In Price Waterhouse/Coopers, the Commission found that the parties were linked through their membership

and running of the institutions self-regulating the auditing sector.209 Christensen and Rabassa (2001), p. 232, quote the article of Compte et al.210 See OECD (1999), p. 218.211 See e. g. Gencor/Lonrho, Case IV/M.0619, (1997) OJ L11/30.212 See Christensen and Rabassa (2001), p. 232.

85

Concerning the last point, the Commission, in Kali&Salz214 and Gencor/Lonrho215, found

that parties had coordinated in the past and that conditions were in place for this to be

repeated in the future. However, evidence of past behaviour has to be applied with caution

(see above 3.6.1) since the analysis in merger cases is prospective in nature. This was also

emphasized by the Court in its ruling on the Commission's Kali&Salz decision.216

5.2.3.2 Impact of merger on competition between the oligopolists

On the basis of the analysis of the past level of competition, the Commission tries to forecast

the effects of the merger on competition between the oligopolists. The Commission

acknowledges the variety of mechanisms through which a merger might influence the

likelihood of collusion (see above 3.2.1) including the absorption of a maverick firm.217

5.2.4 External competitive constraints on the oligopoly

The role of both supply and demand side constraints on the oligopoly was highlighted by the

CFI which demanded that "the Commission must establish that the foreseeable reaction of

current and future competitors, as well as of consumers, would not jeopardise the results" of

collusion (third necessary condition according to the CFI, see above 5.1.4.3.1).

5.2.4.1 Competitors

The Commission assesses the role of mavericks and other fringe firms which are already

competing in the market as well as the role of potential competitors:

5.2.4.1.1 Fringe firms and mavericks

With respect to fringe firms, the Commission in particular asks whether they would be

capable of increasing their supply sufficiently to offset a restriction of supply by the

oligopolists after the merger (i. e. whether there are barriers to expansion, see above 3.4.2.2).

For example in Nestlé/Perrier, Kali&Salz and Airtours/First Choice, the Commission found

that the fringe would not be powerful enough to upset collusive behaviour.

The loss of a maverick was discussed in the decision France Telecom/Orange in which the

Commission regarded the takeover of Orange in the Belgium market for telecommunication

213 AKZO Nobel/Hoechst Roussel Vet, Case IV/M.1681.214 Kali&Salz/MdK/Treuhand, Case IV/M.0308, (1994) OJ L186/38, para 57.215 Gencor/Lonrho, Case IV/M.0619, (1997) OJ L11/30, paras 168-172.216 France v. Commission, Case C 68/94, para 163.217 OECD (1999), p. 220; Christensen and Rabassa (2001), p. 234.

86

services as putting an end to the role of Orange in breaking up the duopolistic pricing

behaviour that had characterised the market before.218

5.2.4.1.2 Potential competitors

The Commission has - in line with the economic theory (3.4.2.1) - considered the presence

of barriers to entry as important factor in the assessment of collective dominance because of

the possibility of a "hit and run" entry. First, the Commission assesses the size of barriers to

entry (i. e. the contestability of the market) and, second, the likelihood of entry of new

competitors within a reasonable period of time. The second step involves scanning the

industry for potential entrants.219

For instance in Ciba-Geigy/Sandoz,220 the Commission found a duopoly with a market share

of 70-80% on the Greek and Spanish markets for seeds. However, entry barriers were

considered low for these two markets for other established producers of seeds with the

consequence that collective dominance was denied.

5.2.4.2 Buyer power

The strategic position of highly concentrated buyers that allows them to exercise competitive

pressure on suppliers has been taken into account by the Commission in several cases: For

example, in Pilkington/SIV221, the tendency to single sourcing by car manufacturers for each

piece of glass, the importance of each single order by major car manufacturers and their

technical capability to monitor their supplier's manufacturing costs was judged to confer a

strong countervailing purchasing power to the demand side. In SNECMA/TC222, buyer

power was considered a leading factor excluding oligopolistic dominance by suppliers of

landing gears for aircraft, because the three main constructors of aircraft accounted for over

three quarters of the world market, had a non-transparent procurement policy and a

preference for long term contracts which involved large quantities in each negotiation.

However, generally, the Commission has been cautious in its assessment of countervailing

buyer power and has only in exceptional cases accepted that buyer power without additional

countervailing factors could motivate the clearance of a case.223 This is in line with the

218 France Telecom/Orange, Case IV/M.2016.219 See Venit (1998).220 Case IV/M.0737, (1997) OJ L201/01.221 Case IV/M.0358.222 Case IV/M.0368.223 See Christensen and Rabassa (2001), p. 233.

87

framework in section 3 which regards the absence of buyer power not as necessary condition

of collusion (see above 3.5.5), but seems to conflict with the CFI's judgment in Airtours (see

above 5.1.4.3.1).

5.3 The future after Airtours: Merger Guidelines

Overall, both the Commission's general approach to collective dominance under the Merger

Regulation and its checklist of market characteristics are largely in line with the framework

set out in section 3 except three points which also have been highlighted by the CFI in its

Airtours judgement (see above 5.1.4.3.1 and 5.1.4.3.3): First, barriers to entry are not only a

market factor that just facilitates collusion, but a necessary condition of collusion. Second,

the market characteristics should be related to the necessary conditions of collusion (inter

alia, to make the economic analysis more transparent). Third, the economic analysis should

work out the interaction of the different market characteristics.

Both future decisions of the Commission and its Guidelines (see below 7.3) will have to

meet these standards.

88

6 COORDINATED EFFECTS IN U.S. MERGER CONTROL

"... both the [EC] Commission's analytical framework and the factors it considers in determining whether a

market is conducive to coordinated interaction are very similar to our's. ... the most important differences that

remain between us in this area relate not to the analytical framework we use, but to process issues ..."

William J. Kolasky, Deputaty Assistant Attorney General, Antitrust Division, DoJ (2002)224

In contrast to the stagnant coordinated effects concept, new developments in economic

theory have provided tools, in particular econometric and simulation techniques, which are

used to generate estimates of unilateral price effects of horizontal mergers. Hence, whereas,

in the past, U.S. merger policy has always been mainly concerned with the effects of mergers

on the likelihood of collusion, it is now in fact moving in the opposite direction, increasingly

focusing on the unilateral effects of mergers rather than on collusion.225 Assuming that

additional costs due to collection of the necessary input data for the unilateral effects

analysis are more than outweighed by the increase in quality of the analysis which

substantially reduces error costs, this shift in ressources of the U.S. antitrust agencies (the

Antitrust Division of the DoJ and the FTC) seems logic. Nevertheless, the agencies see it as

a major objective of merger policy to prevent the more tacit forms of collusion because, in

their opinion, these are difficult (i. e. more costly) to deal with under the other antitrust

statutes (compare above 3.2.2).

6.1 Difference in substance: the SLC test

When discussing the alleged distortions of EC merger control (see above 2.1.7 and

5.1.4.2.2), it has already been pointed out that U.S. merger control does not rely on a

dominance test. Instead, section 7 Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C § 18, prohibits mergers or

acquisitions"... where in any line of commerce or in any activity affecting commerce in any section of the

country, the effect of such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to

create a monopoly." (emphasis added)

224 Speech with the apt title "Coordinated Effects in Merger Review: From Dead Frenchmen to Beautiful

Minds and Mavericks", held before the American Bar Association, Section of Antitrust Law, WashingtonD.C., 24 April 2002, pp. 21, 23.

225 See Baker (1997).

89

The 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines (issued by both agencies) interprete the notion of

"substantial lessening of competition" (SLC) by distinguishing between coordinated and

unilateral effects.226 Similar to Germany and the EC, the standard for the predictive analysis

is whether the merger creates an unreasonable risk of anticompetitive effects.227

6.2 Difference in procedure: ex-ante review

As indicated by the introductory quotation, there is a major procedural difference between

the U.S. on the one side and Germany and EC on the other side which is probably even more

important than the difference in the general tests: Whereas in Germany and the EC decisions

to block a merger or to impose conditions and obligations can be reviewed by courts only ex

post (without time limit), the DoJ and the FTC have to apply for an injunction by a court to

stop a merger, i. e. there is a review ex ante.

Hence, the BKartA and even more the Commission (due to a period of between 2-3 years

between appeal and the judgment by the CFI) have a relatively strong "bargaining" position

towards the merging firms since they can use the 'threat' to stop the merger de facto for some

time. This threat is especially effective in cases where the acquisition is financed by an

exchange of stock options and, hence, depends on volatile prices of shares. This was

highlighted by the Commission's 1999 Airtours decision which was annulled by the CFI

three years later. Analysts suggested that the companies have changed role since 1999:

MyTravel, the former Airtours, is now seen as target for First Choice.228 Hence, despite the

legal defeat, the Commission had de facto stopped the merger.

In contrast, due to the ex-ante-review, the U.S. agencies have to argue more carefully and

detailed to win the case not only legally, but also de facto. This incentive is especially useful

with respect to coordinated effects cases where a careful economic analysis is necessary and

might be one of the explanations for the fact that U.S. agencies typically carry out a more

rigorous economic analysis.

226 Since the Guidelines are not legally binding, it should be mentionned that the distinction between unilateral

and coordinated effecs has been endorsed by the courts.227 United States v. Philadelphia Nat'l Bank, 347 U.S. 321, 362 (1963); Hospital Corp. of America v. FTC, 807

F.2d 1381, 1389 (7th Cir. 1986), cert denied, 481 U. S. 1038 (1987) ("appreciable danger" standard); FTCv. University Health, 938 F.2d 1206, 1218 (11th Cir. 1991) (government must show "reasonablepropability" that the proposed transaction would substantially lessen competition in the future).

90

6.3 The role of concentration

With regard to both coordinated and unilateral effects, the U.S. agencies - like the BKartA

and the Commission - start the assessment of a merger by examining the effect on market

concentration. Interestingly, the presumption rules based on the HHI and �HHI (see above

table 2.1) are used both for coordinated and unilateral effects although, as has been already

pointed out, concentration has diffent functions concerning unilateral and coordinated

effects. However, the Guidelines are well aware of these different functions.229

Moreover, the weight which is afforded to the traditional presumption of illegality, created

by a significant increase in market concentration due to the proposed merger, has been

lessened in coordinated effects cases since courts have been more receptive than in the past

to non-market share evidence.230 The agencies themself see market share and concentration

data only as starting point for the analysis of the competitive impact of a merger.231 Hence,

concentration no longer serves as a proxy against which other evidence is tested. This has

two implications: First, the U.S. approach with regard to concentration fits in with the

analytical framework set out in section 3 which regards few firms and high concentration as

necessary, but not sufficient condition of collusion. Second, the courts' increasing demand

for non-market share evidence seems to have led to a more cautious approach to the use of

coordinated effects theory.

However, in contrast to Germany and the EC, the U.S. antitrust agencies still challenge even

5-4 mergers.232

6.4 Coordinated effects under the 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines

Section 2.1 of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines233 sets out the approach of the DoJ and the

FTC towards the "lessening of competition through coordinated interaction". According to

228 See Financial Times: "Brussels' veto over Airtours is censured", 7 June 2002, p. 1.229 Section 2.0: "Other things being equal, market concentration affects the likelihood that one firm, or a small

group of firms, could successfully exercise market power. The smaller the percentage of total supply that afirm controls, the more severely it must restrict its own output in order to produce a given price increase,and the less likely it is that an output restriction will be profitable. If collective action is necessary for theexercise of market power, as the number of firms necessary to control a given percentage of total supplydecreases, the difficulties and costs of reaching and enforcing an understanding with respect to the controlof that supply might be reduced." (emphasis added)

230 See ABA Antitrust Section (1997), pp. 326-327.231 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, Section 2.0.232 A recent case was the merger of the two leading U.S. aluminium producers, Alcoa and Reynolds (see below

6.4.2).233 The Merger Guidelines are available on the Internet: <http://www.ftc.gov/bc/docs/horizmer.htm>.

91

the Guidelines and the agencies' contributions to the OECD, the FTC and the DoJ, after the

concentration screen, typically look for and analyse respectively

1. the susceptibility of the market to coordination (see below 6.4.1),

2. evidence of prior conduct or ongoing-price fixing or other collusive conduct (6.4.3),

3. evidence that the proposed acquisition would remove a substantial impediment to

coordination, such as by eliminating a maverick firm (above 3.2.1.3),

4. the likelihood of entry in response to oligopolistic situations (6.4.4) and

5. efficiencies (Section 4 of the Guidelines and above 2.1.3).

6.4.1 Market factors

According to the Guidelines, the agencies will examine, "depending on the circumstances",

the following market factors:

- the availability of key information concerning market conditions, transactions and

individual competitors (i. e. transparency),

- the extent of firm and product heterogeneity,

- pricing or marketing practices typically employed by firms in the market (i. e. facilitating

practices),

- the characteristics of buyers (i. e. buyer power) and sellers and

- the characteristics of typical transactions (e. g. long-term high-volume contracting vs. a

spot market).234

Other factors like demand fluctuations are mentionned implicitly in the Guidelines when

describing the mechanism of collusion (Sections 2.11 and 2.12) and explicitly in the

contributions to the OECD.

Comparing these factors with the German and the European checklist, there are (aside from

the explicit emphasis on facilitating practices) no substantial differences.

6.4.2 Relating the market factors to the necessary conditions of coordination

However - in contrast to the 1984 Guidelines235, the German checklist and the unofficial

European statements - the 1992 Guidelines isolate the market factors regarded as conducive

to reaching terms of coordination, those conducive to detecting deveations from those terms

and those conducive to punishing deviations, i. e. each factor is put in the context of the

234 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, Section 2.1.235 Compare 1984 Guidelines Sections 3.41 and 3.42 with 1992 Guidelines Sections 2.11 and 2.12.

92

specific element of the analysis to which it relates. Taking this as model, the framework set

out in section 3 was developed.

Moreover, according to the DoJ's chief antitrust economist, the U.S. authorities will focus on

two aspects in the assessment of coordinated effects in the future:236 First, instead of looking

at factors individually, which make a market conducive to coordinated effects, the U.S.

authorities will rather concentrate on the interaction among the different factors. Second, the

analysis will be tied to how a merger changes those factors and the likelihood of tacit

collusion. Especially the first point has been also highlighted by the CFI in its Airtours

judgment (see above 5.1.4.3.3). Since the future EC Merger Guidelines meet the standards

set by the judgment (see below 7.3), there will also be convergence concerning the aspect of

interaction.

6.4.3 Evidence of prior or current coordination

In both the Guidelines and the contributions to the OECD, the DoJ and the FTC emphasize

the importance of evidence of prior or current current coordination. The U.S. view seems to

be that it would be difficult to substantiate coordinated effects where there remained four or

more firms in the market unless there was some clear facilitating device or practice which

could be argued to be the vehicle for tacit collusion.

The U.S. authorities are well aware of the restrictions (see above 3.7) with which such

evidence has to be applied.237

6.4.4 Analysis of entry

In the U.S. Horizontal Merger Guidelines, a whole section (Section 3: "Entry Analysis")

deals with barriers to entry. Summarising the role of barriers to entry in merger analysis, the

Guidelines state:"A merger is not likely to create or enhance market power or to facilitate its exercise, if entry into

the market is so easy that market participants, after the merger either collectively or unilaterally

could not profitably maintain a price increase above premerger levels."

According to the three-step approach set out by the Guidelines, the agencies assess whether

1. entry can achieve significant market impact within a timely period,

236 Interview with Michael Katz, American Bar Association Section of Antitrust Law "Brown Bag Program", 5

December 2001 (available at <http://www.antitrustsource.com>).237 See the interview with Michael Katz, the DoJ's chief antitrust economist, American Bar Association Section

of Antitrust Law "Brown Bag Program", 5 December 2001 (available at<http://www.antitrustsource.com>), pp. 16-17.

93

2. commited entry would be a profitable and, hence, a likely response to a merger having

competitive effects of concern and

3. timely and likely entry would be sufficient to return market prices to their premerger

levels.

Both the analysis and the significant role of barriers to entry the assessment of mergers with

coordinated effects fit in with the framework set out in section 3 which finds barriers to entry

as necessary condition for collusion.

6.4.5 The relationship between coordinated and unilateral effects

In contrast to the practice of the BKartA and the EC Commission, the U.S. authorities in

some cases ascribe both unilateral and coordinated effects to a merger.238 E. g. in its

complaint against the proposed merger of WorldCom and Sprint (2000), the DoJ alleged

coordinated as well as unilateral effects in, inter alia, the U.S. market for long distance

telephony services. In this market, AT&T, WorldCom and Sprint accounted for 80% of the

market with the next largest competitor having only 3% of the market. The DoJ noted that

competition from Sprint provided a significant constraint on the prices charged by

WorldCom: "The proposed acquisition, by eliminating this competition from Sprint, will

permit the merged entity profitably to charge higher prices than it could profitably charge

absent the merger". Moreover, the DoJ stated that "the merger will also facilitate coordinated

or other collusive pricing ... by the merged entity and AT&T" (emphasis added).239

There are two reasons why the U.S. authorities may allege both effects, one substantive and

one procedural argument: First, as was pointed out above (2.3), in reality there might be a

sequence with unilateral effects first and coordinated effects afterwards. Second, in

comparison to German and EC ex-post review, the ex-ante review by courts in the U.S.

increases the incentive to 'do everything' to win the case (see above 6.2). This explains why

the U.S. authorities "plead in the alternative".

6.5 Cases240

Both cases which are presented in the following highlight two general points:

238 E. g. in the (proposed) mergers of Coca-Cola/Dr. Pepper (FTC, 1994), Cargill/Continental Grain (DoJ, July

1999), Alcoa/Reynolds Metals (DoJ, May 2000), Heinz/BeechNut (see below 6.5.2).239 WorldCom/Sprint, available at <http://www.doj.gov>.240 For other U.S. merger cases see OECD, pp. 45-46.

94

First, if the BKartA or the EC Commission or German or EC courts had dealt with the cases

under the concept of collective dominance, it would have been very likely that the

assessment would have been similar to the assessment of the U.S. agencies and courts except

the consideration of efficiencies. Hence, there is considerable convergence of the analytical

frameworks (see below 7.1).

Second, although the analytical framework in coordinated effects cases in abstracto is clear,

there is much discretion for competition authorities and courts in using evidence for the

different factors and in weighing the different factors concerning a specific case (this

becomes especially clear in the case Heinz/Beech-Nut).

6.5.1 Union Pacific / Southern Pacific

In 1996, the DoJ (like many states) opposed the proposed merger of the Union Pacific and

Southern Pacific railroads, two of the three major rail carriers in the western United States,

since it would have reduced the number of rail carriers on major routes from three to two,

creating a duopoly that would facilitate coordinated price increases.

However, the court which had jurisdiction, the Surface Transportation Board (STB), allowed

the merger to proceed over these objections.241 While accepting that coordination is more

likely in a duopoly than in a market with three players, the STB identified a number of

factors which argued against significant coordinated effects, inter alia

- the heterogeneity of rail transportation service,

- the lack of transparency of rail prices and services,

- the extensive use of long-term, individually-negotiated contracts by large shippers,

- the significant economies of density and scope which created an incentive for railroads to

compete for all profitable volumes rather than to collude, and

- the relatively high elasticity of demand for rail service due to intermodal competition with

trucks and barges.

In addition, the STB found that the disappearance of Southern Pacific was not likely to

increase the probability of coordination because Southern Pacific was a relatively weak,

high-cost third bidder, whose presence did not significantly constrain its larger rivals' prices.

Finally, the STB found that the "small risk of coordination" was outweighed by the

substantial efficiencies of the merger due to significant cost savings.

241 Union Pacific Co./Southern Pacific Transportation Co. 1996 WL 467636 (S.T.B. 1996).

95

6.5.2 Heinz / Beech-Nut242

In the market for jarred baby food in the U.S., the market leader Gerber had a market share

of at least 65%, Heinz accounted for 17.4%, and Beech-Nut's share was 15.4% with Heinz

and Beech-Nut competing for the "second slot" on retailers' shelves. The acquisition of

Beech-Nut by Heinz would have raised the HHI by more than 500 points to a level in excess

of 5000. This would have represented a substantial increase in concentration in an already

concentrated market, reducing the number of significant sellers from three to two.

The FTC's primary competitive effects theory was that the merger would facilitate tacit

collusion.243 The FTC alleged that Heinz and Beech-Nut could not collude successfully with

Gerber pre-merger because the two second brands would have a too great incentive to cheat

through more aggressive shelf-space competition. If, e. g., Heinz went along with a high

price, Beech-Nut would approach supermarkets with a lower price to replace Heinz on the

shelf expecting to profit by taking business away from Gerber by a lower retail price. After

the merger, however, the wholesale competition between Heinz and Beech-Nut, which the

FTC saw as the key obstacle to tacit collusion, would be removed.

In contrast, Heinz claimed that, due to the merger, substantial efficiencies would be obtained

in the production, and that these efficiencies would be used to compete with Gerber.244

The district court rejected the FTC's arguments emphasizing two coordination problems:245

first, the difficulty of deterring cheating, given the time it would take for rivals to detect and

respond price cutting, and, second, the difficulty the merged firm would have in reaching a

consensus with Gerber given the combined firm's incentive to disrupt coordination by

expanding share at Gerber's expense. The court held that the defendants had rebutted the

FTC's prima facie presumption based on market concentration. It also accepted Heinz's

contention that the efficiencies from the merger would promote competition in the market.

The appeals court, the D.C. Circuit, disagreed with the district court, and remanded the case

with an order that a preliminary injunction should be entered. It held that the defendants had

failed to show that the difficulties of overcoming "cartel problems" were "so much greater in

the baby food industry than in other industries that they rebut the normal presumption" that

242 See Baker (2002), pp. 182-185.243 The FTC also alleged a unilateral effects theory arguing on appeal that the loss of wholesale competition

between the merging firms should be an independent basis for finding a violation.244 Baker as Heinz's economic expert testified that "the merged firm ... would disrupt coordination, make it

more difficult for the firms to coordinate." (see Heinz, 116 F. Supp. 2d).245 116 F. Supp. 2d 190 (D.D.C. 2000).

96

would apply in reviewing a merger to duopoly.246 In finding that the defendants had not met

this burden, the D.C. Circuit, in contrast to the district court, noted that policing and

monitoring a collusive agreement would be relatively easy because information on

supermarket prices and sales were highly transparent due to the availability of industry-wide

scanner data and that there was a history of price leadership in the industry. Moreover, the

court found that the claimed efficiencies were both overstated and not merger-specific.

Finally, it rejected the argument that the merged Heinz/Beech-Nut, which would still be only

half of Gerber's size, would have an increased incentive to behave as a maverick due to the

efficiencies the merger would generate.

246 FTC v. H.J. Heinz, 246 F.3d 708 (D.C. Cir. 2001).

7 COMPARISON, POLICY SUGGESTIONS AND LOOK INTO THE

FUTURE

"... the two jurisdictions have moved closer, if not to absolute convergence, because of a shared

appreciation that mergers that contribute substantially to concentration can produce cartel-like effects

(hence the EC has moved to expand its zone of challenge), but those effects will occur only if there is

relatively high concentration, significant barriers to entry and conditions that facilitate collusion or non-

collusive coordination (hence the U. S. has narrowed its range of targets). I wonder if ten years from now

observers will be able to detect significant differences in the way the U.S. and the EC address the

combined market share of mergers that are likely to have oligopolistic effects."

Robert Pitofsky, Chairman of the Federal Trade Commission (2000)247

The overall development over the last ten years was that the EC and the U.S. approach

towards horizontal mergers have converged substantially, with the U.S. agencies and

courts paying increasing attention to unilateral effects and the European Commission

and courts similarly paying more attention to coordinated effects.248

7.1 'Soft' convergence

With regard to coordinated effects, the above statement of the FTC's Chairman has been

confirmed by sections 5 and 6: Although the underlying general tests are still different

(i. e. the law has not been changed), the analytical frameworks and checklists of the EC

Commission and the FTC and the DoJ have converged substantially. From this point of

view, the Commission's decision in Airtours can be even regarded as "overshooting".

Except for the legal(istic) distinction between internal and external competition which

the GWB determines as starting point of the analysis, the German approach to collective

dominance - as set out in the revised Merger Guidelines and as applied in practice - is

largely comparable to the EC and U.S. approach. The insights from economic theory

and the findings concerning the assessment of coordinated effects under the three

merger regimes are summarised in the following table:

247 Speech with the title "EU and U.S. Approaches to International Mergers - Views from the U.S. Federal

Trade Commission", held at the EC Merger Control 10th Anniversary Conference in Brussels on 14/15September 2000, p. 2.

248 See the speech of William J. Kolasky, Deputy Assistant Attorney General at the DoJ's AntitrustDivision with the title "Coordinated Effects in Merger Review: From Dead Frenchmen to BeautifulMinds and Mavericks", held before the American Bar Association, Section of Antitrust Law,Washington D.C., 24 April 2002, p. 1.

98

Economic theory Germany EC (so far) U.S.

1 Substantive issues

1.1 Underlying test

SLC test preferable

in abstracto: identi-

fiable with econo-

mics of unilateral/

coordinated effects

dominance test

=> collective

dominance

dominance test

=> collective

dominance

SLC test

=> coordinated

effects

1.2 (Market) factors which are assessed in coordinated effects cases

Few firmsSelten: 4

Farrell: 3

3-2 and 4-3

mergers

3-2 and 4-3

mergers

3-2, 4-3 and

5-4 mergers

Concentration (in terms of

market shares, concen-

tration ratios, HHI)

++++

++++

lower bound:

C3�50%

(presumption

rule)

++++

lower bound:

C4�60%

(no presumption

rule)

++++

1. HHI>1000 and

�HHI>100

2. HHI>1800 and

�HHI>50

(presumption

rules)

Barriers to expansion and

entry (=no actual competi-

tion by the fringe and no

potential competition)

++++ ++++

- Commission so

far: +++

- CFI: ++++

++++

(No loss of a) maverick +++ ++ ++ +++

Stable demand conditions +++ ++(+) ++(+) ++(+)

Homogeneous products +++ +++ +++ +++

Market transparency +++ +++ +++ +++

Low buyer power +++ +++ CFI: ++++ +++

Low price elasticity ++ ++ ++ ++

Symmetry ++ ++ ++ +

Structural links ++ +++ +++ ?

Facilitating practices ++ + + ++

Past collusion++, if used

correctly++ ++ +++

Multi-market contact + + + +

2 Procedural issues

Guidelines

Increase transpa-

rency and consti-

tute self-binding

yes (2000) draft (2002) yes (1992)

Review by courts ex ante ex post ex post ex ante

++++ = considered to be a necessary condition of collusion; +++ = very important factor;

++ = important factor; + = factor that is only additionally assessed;

( ) = no clear-cut statement possible; ? = no statement by competition authority or court

99

7.2 Differences and resulting suggestions for reform from a European point of view

Although there has been considerable convergence overall, the table shows that there

are still differences between the three merger regimes concerning the assessment of

coordinated effects:

First, still different weight appears to be attached to certain market factors. Second, in

contrast to German and U.S. merger control, the EC approach does not use presumption

rules based on market concentration. Due to the importance of non-market share

evidence and due to the complexity of the analysis, it does not seem to be appropriate in

coordinated effects cases to reverse the burden of proof. Instead, concentration

measures should only be used to provide for safe harbours.

Third, the SLC test coincides with the economics of unilateral and coordinated effects.

Hence, it is clearest about the underlying economic mechanisms.

Fourth, the ex-ante review by U.S. courts appears to be the better solution to the

question of checks-and-balances in merger cases than ex-post review with the

possibility of interim orders. Hence, in particular the EC should start thinking about the

introduction of such an ex-ante review by the Court to end the debate about the

Commission's executive, legislative and de facto judicial power in the field of merger

control. Internal "due process", as currently debated, is not sufficient to solve the

problem of the Commission's bargaining position.249

Fifth, another general institutional difference, which makes a difference with respect to

the quality of the economic analysis especially in complex coordinated effects cases,

lies in the simple fact that particularly the FTC already maintains a large staff of

Industrial Organization economists and econometricians. In contrast, DG IV is currently

still considering to expand its economics section.250

249 For a discussion of an internal reform of DG IV after the Airtours judgment see the Economist, "Will

the real Mario Monti please stand up? A court ruling has given Europe's competition authority aunique chance to reform itself. Will it take it?", 15 June 2002, pp. 65-66.

250 See the speech of William J. Kolasky with the title "Coordinated Effects in Merger Review" heldbefore the American Bar Association, Section of Antitrust Law, Washington D.C., 24 April 2002, p.23.

100

7.3 The European Commission’s proposals for a reform of EC merger control

On 11 December 2002, the European Commission has adopted a proposal for a revised

Merger Regulation (which requires approval by the Council) and a draft Notice on the

appraisal of horizontal mergers under the Merger Regulation.251

The revised Merger Regulation will contain a new definition of “dominance” in Article

2(2)

“For the purpose of this Regulation, one or more undertakings shall be deemed to be in a

dominant position if, with or without coordinating, they hold the economic power to

influence appreciably and sustainably the parameters of competition, in particular, prices,

production, quality of output, distribution or innovation, or appreciably to foreclose

competition.”252

This definition distinguishes between three main merger scenarios:

7.3.1 Single dominance: One undertaking having market power without

coordinating

The first category - one undertaking having market power without coordinating - can be

identified with the current notion of “single dominance”: A horizontal, vertical or

conglomerate merger creates or strengthens the market position of a single entity. This

category is described as follows in the draft Guidelines on horizontal mergers (para 11,

see also paras 19-24):

“(a) A merger may create or strengthen a paramount market position. A firm in such a

position will often be able to increase prices without being constrained by actions of its

customers and its actual or potential competitors.”

7.3.2 Collective dominance: More undertakings having market power with

coordinatin (collusive oligopolies)

The second category given by the draft Article 2(2) MR - more undertakings having

market power with coordinating - incorporates collective or joint dominance into the

Merger Regulation and, hence, eliminates the current “blind spot” in the text of the

Regulation. The creation or strengthening of a collective dominant position is described

as follows in the Guidelines (para 11):

251 Commission Notice on the appraisal of horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the control

of concentrations between undertakings; both drafts are available at: <http://www.europa.eu.int/comm/competition/ mergers/review/>.

252 See also the proposed new recital 21.

101

“(c) A merger may change the nature of competition in an oligopolistic market so sellers,

who previously were not co-ordinating their behaviour, now are able to co-ordinate and

therefore raise prices. A merger may also make co-ordinating easier for sellers who were

co-ordinating prior to the merger.”

In the draft Notice (paras 40-69), the Commission makes clear that it has learned its

lesson from the Airtours decision. It explicitly quotes the three basic conditions for co-

ordination to be sustainable which have been worked out by the judgment (see para 44):

1. monitoring (paras 55-60),

2. a deterrent mechanism (paras 61-68) and

3. the inability of outsiders (competitors and customers) to jeopardise the results

expected from the co-ordination (paras 69).

Moreover, the Notice relates these conditions to the market factors which feed into these

conditions.

7.3.3 More undertakings having market power without coordinating (non-collusive

oligopolies)

By introducing the third category of “more undertakings having market power without

coordinating”, the Commission equips itself with an instrument to deal with a situation

like in Airtours, i. e. a pre-merger market structure with three or four firms which all

have less than 40 % market share where a merger might have relevant unilateral effects.

This category is described as follows in the draft Guidelines on horizontal mergers (para

11):

“(b) A merger may diminish the degree of competition in an oligopolistic market by

eliminating important competitive constraints on one or more sellers, who consequently

would be able to increase their prices.”253

Hence, the first distortion (unilateral effects under the heading of collective dominance)

will be prevented from in the future. Inspired by the U. S. Guidelines, the draft Notice,

for such situations, explicitly introduces the HHI (paras 26-29) and distinguishes

between Cournot (paras 30-33) and Bertrand markets (paras 34-38).

102

7.3.4 ‘Hard’ convergence

Hence, under the future Merger Regulation, the term “dominance” will be interpreted by

the economics of unilateral (one or more undertakings having market power without

coordinating) and coordinated effects (more undertakings having market power with

coordinating).

Moreover, the draft Notice explicitly deals with entry (paras 78-86) and introduces an

efficiency defence (paras 87-95), which is very similar to the respective defence under

the U.S. Merger Guidelines, thus eliminating the second distortion of the current Merger

Regulation. Hence, overall, there will be no important substantive differences between

U.S. and EC merger control in the future.

The above analysis has demonstrated the 'victory' of the economics of coordinated

effects in merger control which was reached - to some extent - by mutual learning of

competition authorities.

253 Para 11.

103

REFERENCES

Abreu, D., D. Pearce, and E. Stacchetti (1986): "Optimal Cartel Equilibria with

Imperfect Monitoring", Journal of Economic Theory, 39, pp. 251-269.

Albaek, S. et al. (1997): “Government-Assisted Oligopoly Coordination? A Concrete

Case”, The Journal of Industrial Economics, 45, pp. 429-443.

Alger, D. (1986): Investigating Oligopolies within the Laboratory, Federal Trade

Commission, Washington, D.C.

American Bar Association, Antitrust Section (ed.) (1997): Antitrust Law

Developments, 4th ed., Washington D. C.

Amstutz, M. (1999): Kollektive Marktbeherrschung im europäischen Wettbewerbs-

recht – Eine evolutorische Perspektive, Beiträge zur Ordnungstheorie und

Ordnungspolitik 161, Tübingen, Mohr Siebeck.

Axelrod, R. (1980): "Effective Choice in the Prisoner's Dilemma", Journal of Conflict

Resolution, 24, pp. 3-25.

Axelrod, R. (1981): "The Emergence of Cooperation among Egoists", American

Political Science Review, 28, pp. 1-12.

Axelrod, R. (1984): The Evolution of Cooperation, New York, Basic Books.

Baker, J. B. (1997): "Unilateral Competitive Effects Theories in Merger Analysis",

Antitrust, Spring 1997.

Baker, J. B. (2002): “Mavericks, Mergers, and Exclusion: Proving Coordinated

Competitive Effects Under the Antitrust Laws”, New York University Law

Review, 77 (4), April, pp. 135-203.

104

Baumol, W., J. Panzer, and R. Willig (1982): Contestable Markets and the Theory of

Industry Structure, New York, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

Benoit, J. P., and V. Krishna (1987): „Dynamic Duopoly: Prices and quantities“,

Review of Economic Studies, 54, pp. 23-25.

Bergstrom, T. C., and H. Varian (1985): "Two remarks on Cournot equilibria",

Economics Letters, 19, pp. 5-8.

Bernheim, B. D., and M. D. Whinston (1990): “Multimarket Contact and Collusive

Behavior”, RAND Journal of Economics, 21, pp. 1-26.

Briones, J. (1995): “Oligopolistic Dominance: Is there a Common Approach in

Different Jurisdictions? A Review of Decisions Adopted by the Commission

under the Merger Regulation”, European Competition Law Review,

pp. 334-347.

Briones, J., and A. J. Padilla (2001): “The Complex Landscape of Oligopolies under

EU Competition Policy – Is Collective Dominance Ripe for Guidelines?”,

Journal of World Competition, 24 (3), pp. 307-318.

Bundeskartellamt (2002): „Das Untersagungskriterium in der Fusionskontrolle –

Marktbeherrschende Stellung versus Substantial Lessening of Competition?“,

Discussion Paper, Bonn.

Caffarra, C., and D. J. Neven (2000): "Collective Confusion? An Economic View on

'Joint Dominance' in Merger Control", mimeo, University of Lausanne.

Chamberlin, E. (1933): The Theory of Monopolistic Competition, Cambridge Mass.,

Harvard University Press.

105

Christensen, P., and V. Rabassa (2001): "The Airtours decision: Is there a new

Commission approach to collective dominance", European Competition Law

Review, pp. 227-237.

Christie, W., and P. Schultz (1994a): “Why do Nasdaq Market Makers Avoid Odd-

Eight Quotes?”, Journal of Finance, 49 (5), pp. 1813-1840.

Christie, W., and P. Schultz (1994b): “Why did Nasdaq Market Makers Stop Avoiding

Odd-Eight Quotes?”, Journal of Finance, 49 (5), pp. 1841-1860.

Compte, O., F. Jenny, and P. Rey (2002): "Capacity constraints, mergers and

collusion", European Economic Review, 46, pp. 1-29.

Davidson, C., and R. Deneckere (1990): “Excess Capacity and Collusion”,

International Economic Review, 31, pp. 521-542.

Dick, A. R. (1997): “ If Cartels Were Legal, Would Firms Fix Prices?”, Working Paper,

U.S. Department of Justice.

Emmerich, V. (1999): Kartellrecht, 8th ed., Munich, C. H. Beck.

European Commission (2001): Green Paper on the Review of Council Regulation

(EEC) No 4064/89, Brussels, <http://www.europa.eu.int/comm/competition/

mergers/review/green_paper/en.pdf>.

Europe Economics (2001): Study on Assessment Criteria for Distinguishing between

Competitive and Dominant Oligopolies in Merger Control - Final Report for the

European Commission Enterprise Directorate General, London.

Evans, W., and N. Kessides (1994): “Living by the Golden Rule: Multimarket Contact

in the US Airline Industry”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109 (2), pp. 341-

366.

106

Farrell, J. (2001): "Renegotiation in Repeated Oligopoly Interaction", University of

California, Berkeley, Working Paper.

Farrell, J., and E. Maskin (1987): “Notes on renegotiation in repeated games”, Harvard

University.

Farrell, J., and E. Maskin (1989): “Renegotiation in Repeated Games”, Games and

Economic Behavoir, 1, pp. 327-360.

Farrell, J., and C. Shapiro (1990): “Profitable Horizontal Mergers and Welfare”, in:

L. Phlips (1998), Applied Industrial Economics, Cambridge University Press.

Farrell, J., and M. Rabin (1996): “Cheap Talk”, The Journal of Economics

Perspectives, 19 (3), pp. 103-118.

Fershtman, C., and A. Pakes (2000): “A Dynamic Oligopoly with Collusion and Price

Wars”, RAND Journal of Economics, 31 (2), pp. 207-236.

Fisher, F. M. (1989): "Games Economists Play: a Non-cooperative View", RAND

Journal of Economics, 20, pp. 113-124.

Friedman, J. (1971): "A Non-cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames", Review of

Economic Studies, 38 (1), pp. 1-12.

Fudenberg, D., and E. Maskin (1986): "The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with

Discounting and with Incomplete Information", Econometrica, 54,

pp. 533-554.

Fudenberg, D., and J. Tirole (1986): "Dynamic models of oligopoly", in: A. Jacquemin

(ed.), Fundamentals of pure and applied economics, 3,

New York, Harwood.

107

Haucap, J. (2000): "Kollektive Marktbeherrschung im europäischen Wettbewerbsrecht

– Anmerkungen zum gleichnamigen Buch von Marc Amstutz", mimeo,

Hamburg.

Häckner, J. (1996): „Optimal symmetric punishments in a Bertrand differentiated

products duopoly“, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14 (5), pp.

611-630.

Holt, C. A. (1995): Industrial Organization: A Survey of Laboratory Research, in: J. E.

Kagel & A. E. Roth (ed.), Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton

University Press.

Immenga, U., and E.-J. Mestmäcker (ed.) (2001): GWB-Kommentar, 3rd ed., Munich,

C. H. Beck.

Kantzenbach, E., E. Kottmann, and R. Krüger (1995): New Industrial Economics and

Experiences from European Merger Control - New lessons about collective

dominance?, Study commissioned by the European Commission, Office for

Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

Kantzenbach, E., E. Kottmann, and R. Krüger (1996): Kollektive

Marktbeherrschung: Neue Industrieökonomik und Erfahrungen aus der

Europäischen Fusionskontrolle, Baden-Baden.

Korah, V. (1999): "Gencor v. Commission: Collective Dominance", European

Competition Law Review, pp. 337-341.

Kreps, D., P. Milgrom, J. Roberts, and R. Wilson (1982): "Rational Cooperation in

the Finitely Repeated Prisoner's Dilemma", Journal of Economic Theory, 27, pp.

245-252.

Kreps, D. (1990): A Course In Microeconomic Theory, Hertfordshire, Simon &

Schuster International Group.

108

Lexecon (2002): “Collective Dominance and Capacity Coordination”, available at

<http://www.lexecon.co.uk>.

Mailath, G. J. (1998): "Do people play Nash equilibrium? Lessons from evolutionary

game theory", Journal of Economic Literature, 36, pp. 1347-1374.

Marquez, J. (1992): “Life Expectancy of International Cartels: An Empirical Analysis”,

Board of Governors of the Federal reserve System Discussion Paper.

Martin, S. (1993): Advanced Industrial Economics, Oxford and Cambridge, Blackwell.

Matsushima, H. (2000): “The Folk Theorem with Private Monitoring and Uniform

Sustainability”, CIRJE Working Paper F-84.

McCutcheon, B. (1997): “Do Meetings in Smoke-Filled Rooms Facilitate Collusion?”,

Journal of Political Economy, 105, pp. 330-350.

Møllgaard, P., and B. Overgaard (2001): “Market Transparency: A Mixed Blessing?”,

Mimeo.

Morgan, E. J. (1996): "The treatment of oligopoly under the European merger control

regulation", The Antitrust Bulletin, pp. 203-246.

Motta, M. (1999): “Economic analysis and EC Merger Policy”, European University

Institute Working Paper, Florence.

Motta, M. (2000): "E.C. Merger Policy and the Airtours Case", European Competition

Law Review, pp. 199-207.

Motta, M., M. Polo, and H. Vasconcelos (2002): "Merger Remedies in the European

Union: An Overview", European University Institute Working Paper, Florence.

109

Neven, D. J. (2000): " 'Collusion' under Art 81 and the merger regulation", Paper

presented at the 3rd Nordic Competition Policy Conference, Stockholm.

OECD, Commitee on Competition Law and Policy (1999): Roundtable on Oligopoly,

Paris.

Phlips, L. (1995): Competition Policy: A Game-Theoretic Perspective, Cambridge

University Press.

Porter, R. (1983): A Study of Cartel Stability”, Bell Journal of Economics, 14, pp. 301-

314.

Richter, R., and Furubotn, E. (1999): Neue Institutionenökonomik, Tübingen, Mohr

Siebeck.

Rittner, F. (1999): Wettbewerbs- und Kartellrecht, 6th ed., Heidelberg, C.F. Müller.

Röller, L.-H., J. Stennek, and F. Verboven (2000): "Efficiency Gains from Mergers",

Discussion Paper FS IV 00-09, Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin.

.

Ross, T. W. (1992): “Cartel stability and product differentiation”, International Journal

of Industrial Organization, 10 (1), pp. 1-13.

Ross, T. W., and A. Baziliauskaus (2000): "Lessening of Competition in Mergers

Under the Competition Act: Unilateral and Interdependence Effects", Canadian

Business Law Journal, 33, pp. 373-426.

Rotemberg, J., and G. Saloner (1986): “A Supergame-Theoretic Model of Business

Cycles and Price Wars During Booms”, American Economic Review, 76, pp.

390-407.

Rothschild, R. (1999): “Cartel stability When Costs Are Heterogeneous”, International

Journal of Industrial Organization, 17 (5), pp. 717-734.

110

Salop, S. (1986): “Practices that (Credibly) Facilitate Oligopoly Coordination”, in: J.

Stiglitz, and F. Mathewson (ed.) (1986), New Developments in the Analysis of

Market Structure, Cambridge, MIT Press, pp. 265-290.

Schelling, T. C. (1960): The Strategy of Conflict, Cambridge Mass., Harvard University

Press.

Selten, R. (1973): “A Simple Model of Imperfect Competition Where Four Are Few

and Six Are Many”, International Journal of Game Theory, 2, pp. 141-201.

Selten, R. (1978): “The Chain Store Paradox”, Theory and Decision, 9, pp. 127-159.

Shaffer, S. (1995): “Stable Cartels with Cournot Fringe”, Southern Economic Journal,

61.

Shapiro, C. (1989): "Theories of Oligopoly Behaviour", in: R. Schmalensee, and R.

Willig (ed.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Amsterdam.

Shapiro, C. (1995): “Mergers with Differentiated Products”, Speech to the American

Bar Association and International Bar Association, The Merger Review Process

in the US and Abroad.

Stackelberg, H. von (1934): Marktform und Gleichgewicht, Vienna, Springer.

Stigler, G. (1964): “A Theory of Oligopoly”, Journal of Political Economy, 72, pp. 44-

61.

Stroux, S. (2000): "Is EC Oligopoly Control Outgrowing Its Infancy?", Journal of

World Competition, 23 (1), pp. 3-50.

Tirole, J. (1998): Industrial Economics, 10th print., Cambridge Mass., MIT Press.

111

Vasconcelos, H. (2001): "Tacit Collusion, Cost Asymmetries and Mergers", European

University Institute Working Paper, Florence.

Venit, J. S. (1998): "Two steps forward and no steps back: economic analysis and

oligopolistic dominance after Kali&Salz", Common Market Law Review, 35,

pp. 1101-1134.

Viscusi, W. K., J. M. Vernon, and J. E. Harrington, Jr. (1995): Economics of

regulation and antitrust, 2nd ed., Cambridge, MIT Press.

Weibull, J. W. (1995): Evolutionary Game Theory, Cambridge/London, MIT Press.

Weibull, J. W. (1998): "What have we learned from evolutionary game theory so far?",

Working paper, Stockholm School of Economics.

Weizsäcker, C. C. von (2001): "'Kollektive Marktbeherrschung im Rahmen der

staatlichen und internationalen Fusionskontrolle", Contribution to the Economic

Seminar Ottobeuren 2001.

Willig, R. (1991): Merger Analysis, Industrial Organisation Theory and Merger

Guidelines, Brookings Papers Microeconomics.

Wirtz, M. M. (2002): "Wohin mit den Effizienzen in der europäischen

Fusionskontrolle?", Europäisches Wirtschaftsrecht, pp. 59-65.

Wolfstetter, E. (1999): Topics in Microeconomics, Cambridge University Press.

Ysewyn, J., and C. Caffarra (1998): "Two's Company, Three's a Crowd: The Future of

Collective Dominance After the Kali&Salz Judgment", European Competition

Law Review, pp. 468-472.