Conceptualisation of the consultancy pricing paradox

23
Structural Survey Emerald Article: Conceptualisation of the consultancy pricing paradox De-Graft Owusu-Manu, Edward Badu, David J. Edwards, Michael Adesi, Gary D. Holt Article information: To cite this document: De-Graft Owusu-Manu, Edward Badu, David J. Edwards, Michael Adesi, Gary D. Holt, (2012),"Conceptualisation of the consultancy pricing paradox", Structural Survey, Vol. 30 Iss: 4 pp. 357 - 378 Permanent link to this document: http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/02630801211256706 Downloaded on: 28-08-2012 References: This document contains references to 168 other documents To copy this document: [email protected] Access to this document was granted through an Emerald subscription provided by Emerald Author Access For Authors: If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for Authors service. Information about how to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines are available for all. Please visit www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for more information. About Emerald www.emeraldinsight.com With over forty years' experience, Emerald Group Publishing is a leading independent publisher of global research with impact in business, society, public policy and education. In total, Emerald publishes over 275 journals and more than 130 book series, as well as an extensive range of online products and services. Emerald is both COUNTER 3 and TRANSFER compliant. The organization is a partner of the Committee on Publication Ethics (COPE) and also works with Portico and the LOCKSS initiative for digital archive preservation. *Related content and download information correct at time of download.

Transcript of Conceptualisation of the consultancy pricing paradox

Structural SurveyEmerald Article: Conceptualisation of the consultancy pricing paradoxDe-Graft Owusu-Manu, Edward Badu, David J. Edwards, Michael Adesi, Gary D. Holt

Article information:

To cite this document: De-Graft Owusu-Manu, Edward Badu, David J. Edwards, Michael Adesi, Gary D. Holt, (2012),"Conceptualisation of the consultancy pricing paradox", Structural Survey, Vol. 30 Iss: 4 pp. 357 - 378

Permanent link to this document: http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/02630801211256706

Downloaded on: 28-08-2012

References: This document contains references to 168 other documents

To copy this document: [email protected]

Access to this document was granted through an Emerald subscription provided by Emerald Author Access

For Authors: If you would like to write for this, or any other Emerald publication, then please use our Emerald for Authors service. Information about how to choose which publication to write for and submission guidelines are available for all. Please visit www.emeraldinsight.com/authors for more information.

About Emerald www.emeraldinsight.comWith over forty years' experience, Emerald Group Publishing is a leading independent publisher of global research with impact in business, society, public policy and education. In total, Emerald publishes over 275 journals and more than 130 book series, as well as an extensive range of online products and services. Emerald is both COUNTER 3 and TRANSFER compliant. The organization is a partner of the Committee on Publication Ethics (COPE) and also works with Portico and the LOCKSS initiative for digital archive preservation.

*Related content and download information correct at time of download.

Conceptualisation of theconsultancy pricing paradox

De-Graft Owusu-Manu and Edward BaduDepartment of Building Technology,

Kwame Nkrumah University of Science and Technology, Kumasi, Ghana

David J. EdwardsCentre for Business, Innovation and Enterprise,

Birmingham City Business School, Birmingham, UK

Michael AdesiTraining Innovations and Technology Transfer Institute,

Kumasi, Ghana, and

Gary D. HoltCentre for Business, Innovation and Enterprise,

Birmingham City Business School, Birmingham, UK

Abstract

Purpose – Despite widespread demand for consultants and especially within the surveyingprofession, driving forces of service/pricing/quality are not fully understood and have receivedminimal research attention. The purpose of this paper is to review contemporary knowledge in thisfield, highlighting en route the dilemmas of the consultancy pricing paradox.Design/methodology/approach – Methodology is of axiological, philosophical tradition –induction and inference, generalized concepts and theories. A critique of extant literature underpinsa theoretical pricing problem framework, a future research agenda, and a model of the pricingparadox.Findings – The study elucidates paradoxical aspects regarding value perceptions, objectives,strategies, cost recovery, competition and systematic processes. It conceptually models the dilemmaof service pricing and suggests a research agenda based on process and value, nature of service,competence and branding.Research limitations/implications – The formalisation of the paradox and development of theconceptual model opens opportunities for a new research agenda in the future, which is highlighted aspart of the study.Practical implications – Advancement of theory will impact pricing paradigms.Originality/value – The paper presents a novel conceptualisation of the subject.

Keywords Surveying, Consultants, Fees, Pricing policy, Value, Quality, Research.

Paper type Research paper

IntroductionArthur D. Little established the first consulting firm in the USA many decades ago(Niewien and Richter, 2004) and since then, the consulting sector has developedsignificantly (Sultana, 2009). Consultants have become critical in the diagnosis,advising, formulation and implementation of policies that can affect the affairs ofcompanies, global organizations and even nations. Resultantly, functions dealing witheconomies, industries, education, health and technology transfer, have all benefitted(Michielse and Thuronyi, 2009).

Greiner and Metzger (1983) and Naarmala and Tuomi (2006) defined consultingas an advisory service provided by qualified persons who act objectively to help

The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available atwww.emeraldinsight.com/0263-080X.htm

Structural SurveyVol. 30 No. 4, 2012

pp. 357-378r Emerald Group Publishing Limited

0263-080XDOI 10.1108/02630801211256706

357

The consultancypricing paradox

identify/analyse problems and assist in the implementation of solutions. Consultingservices are diverse and may comprise: feasibility, environmental studies; projectplanning; quality, construction or cost management; forensic services; researchand development; or tender preparation (list not definitive) (The World Bank, 2002;ACENZ, 2004). Some advancements in the sector have come from research, a notableexample being the model of consultation proffered by Schein (1990). Otherdevelopments have emphasized that consultants engage with clients (Nees andGreiner, 1985) to strive for relationship optimization (Appelbaum and Steed, 2003).However, problems persist which centre around the sector’s lack of a generic pricingframework. Parties can disagree on appropriate pricing modalities; clients often feelthat consultants overprice their services, while consultants sometimes feel they areunder-pricing to the detriment of their business.

To address these issues, the objectives of this research are to: synthesize knowledgeregarding the dilemma of service pricing; present a theoretical framework explaining therudiments of consultancy pricing and proffer a future research agenda. The researchcentres on a literature review that considered concepts of price and value, critical factorsaffecting pricing and the characteristics of the consultancy sector. Methodologically,the study is of axiological philosophy, where induction, dwelling wholly on thegeneralization and synthesis of extant research provides the basis of the framework.

Critical factors influencing pricingKiesling and Hansen (1993) suggested that products and services (hereafter “products”for brevity) must be priced in accordance with a cost structure; taking cognizance of(both fixed and variable) costs, market, and distribution costs. Market demand has amajor effect on pricing and poor demand assessment can lead to poor priceperformance (DeLozier and Woodside, 1976). Adner (2004) argued that demand-oriented pricing is superior to cost-oriented pricing, pointing out that in the lattera predetermined amount is added to cost while for the demand approach, customerwillingness (to pay) takes precedence. Globalization has increased business frontiers,which in turn has exacerbated competition. Falch (2004) reminded us that price will beinfluenced by competitors’ prices. Experience also plays a part insofar as historicalcost data will influence current pricing (Zizzo and Oswald, 2001). The OECD (2008)meanwhile identified that jurisdiction can affect pricing in terms of authority, industryaverages and legal or regulatory standards (WBI, 2003). Location can influence pricetoo, a “prime” location for a particular product can usually mean charging more for it(Tsiotsou, 2005). Learning how customers feel about products or services helpsestablish a price range and can relate to how they perceive a business and its goods(Luk, 2009). Ideally, prices should motivate customers, be competitive and profitablewhile accounting for the risks of production (Patsula, 2007). Key factors that affectpricing comprise: demand factors (client expectation and value perceptions); costfactors (envisaged and present); competitive factors (barriers to entry and competitors’strategy); trade factors (market traditions, industry standards and industry averages);legal factors (such as taxation and legislation); strategic factors (pricing objectives/market structure); and geographic factors (of the business and its customers). Thesefactors are conceptualized in Figure 1.

The rudiments of consultancy services pricingInfluences of consultancy pricing include the above, along with objectivity, flexibility,discounts and allowances (Perreault and McCarthy, 2002). ACENZ (2004) asserted that

358

SS30,4

consultancy prices should reward the consultant’s qualifications, training, skill andexperience, in addition to allowance for risk and reasonable profit. The Ministry ofFinance (2009) opined that breakdown of consultancy fees should demonstrate basicsalary; social charges of non-monetary nature (e.g. sick leave, pension, social security);overheads not charged directly to the assignment; and fee or profit. The latter may beexpressed as a percentage, normally within the range 5-20 per cent depending onnature and duration of services, level of specialization, and risk. Clients often negotiatesome cost elements such as living expenses and travel, with contingencies forassignments of 18 months or more to allow for price escalation (Ministry of Finance, 2009).

Consulting Engineers South Africa (CESA, 2009) opined that pricing of servicesshould conform to guidelines taking account of project requirements; costs involved;and “knowing” the client. The Islamic Development Bank (IDB) suggested thatconsulting remuneration depends on the type of service rendered and degree offlexibility (or control) to be exercised. According to Davidson and Simonetto (2005),price variability is influenced by client negotiating power, timing of the deal, politicalclout and management intervention. The “basic” form of pricing consultancy cannot beoverlooked, thus ACENZ (2004) identified basic fee nomenclature, which is suitablefor small projects and/or where the scope of work cannot be clearly defined. Othersundry charges identified by ACENZ include measurement of works (involvingcharges for the preparation of bills of quantities) in the range of 0.5-1.5 per cent ofthe value of works, and charges for valuations of insurance and preparation ofcertificates. The World Bank (2002) stipulates that consultancy fees shouldinclude staff remuneration; travel; mobilization/demobilization; staff allowances;

Competition

Demand

> Expectation

> Value

> Experience

Price

Cost

Regulatory

> Anticipated/ present cost

> Profit/ risk

> Taxation

> Restriction

> Legislation

Location

TradeStrategic

> Traditions > Price objectives

> Market structure> Industry standards

> Manufacture

> Market

> Clients

> Entry barriers

> Competion objectives

Figure 1.Conceptualisation of

pricing factors

359

The consultancypricing paradox

communication; report production; office rent, supplies, equipment and insurance;survey and training programmes; taxes; and contingencies.

Davidson and Simonetto (2005) opined that pricing has been revolutionized by software,for setting, optimizing and enforcing – and that the best tools have an integrated view ofcustomers along with full historical reporting facilities. Software tools need models tooperate, thus Sheedy et al. (2010) identified models that consultants currently use including:time –and expense (charge per unit of time plus expenses), fixed price (flat fee), risk/reward(includes a bonus for key achievements or penalty for missing milestones) and results-based (paid upon meeting agreed targets). Time and expense is best where the scope of theassignment is ill defined; fixed price where the scope is clearly defined; and for projects thatfrequently require the services of several consultants, a hybrid is appropriate (APEGGA,2005). Figure 2 graphically conceptualizes the pricing rudiments discussed above.

Consultancy price

Add risk and profit

Staff allowance: Out-of-pocket expenses

Office: Rent; insurance; equipment and supplies

Reporting: Translation and printing

Communication: International calls; local calls; internetservices; teleconferncing

Travel: Local fares; number/ types of vehicles; maintenance;revenue costs

Surveys and training: Topography; cartography; subsurface investigations;satellite imaging; traininig programmes

Mobilization/Demobilization: Hotel cost; cost for shipping; transportation

Taxes and duties: VAT; levies; duties

Contingencies: Physical:10–15%; price: inflation trend

Staff remuneration: Professional staff; supporting staff; experience;qualifications; location; risk; difficulty of assignment

Figure 2.Rudiments of pricingconsultancy services

360

SS30,4

Theoretical perspectives on pricing objectivesPricing perspectives are economic such as demand, cost and competition; wheredemand sets the ceiling, cost sets the floor and competition determines where on thiscontinuum the price falls. Zeithaml (1988) demonstrated pricing within intrinsic andextrinsic attributes of consumers in their perception of quality and value; while Shaw(1992) focused on the strategic, marketing management and managerial perspectives.Tellis (1986) opined that consumers differ with respect to information costs (e.g. time,effort, search costs), price sensitivities, and transaction costs (e.g. obtaining funds,uncertainty and switching costs). According to Roth (2001), a thorough understandingof product attributes and the market is key to pragmatic pricing and further, thatpricing objectives must synergize with business goals. Oxenfeldt (1983) assertedthat pricing objectives are directions for action (see also Tzokas et al., 2000a, b). Otherobjectives demonstrated in the literature include partial cost recovery, profit marginmaximization, profit maximization, revenue maximization, quality leadership, quantitymaximization, status quo and survival (cf. Channon, 1986; Cannon and Morgan, 1990;Bonnici, 1991; Payne, 1993; Palmer, 1994; Bateson, 1995; Woodruff, 1995; Drake andLlewellyn, 1995; Ansari et al., 1996; Lovelock, 1996; Meidan, 1996; Zeithaml and Bitner,1996; Hoffman and Bateson, 1997; Langeard, 2000).

Avlonitis and Indounas (2005) linked pricing/business objectives with achievement.For example: market share increase leads to cost coverage, return on investmentprovides return on asset and price differentiation achieves service quality leadership(list not definitive). They also revealed that quantitative pricing objectives arerelated to profit, sales, market share and cost recovery; and qualitative objectivesare related to matters such as relationship with customers, long-term survival of thefirm and achievement of social goals. Objectives can also endeavour to maximizeresults (profits and sales) vis-a-vis those that pursue satisfactory results (Avlonitisand Indounas (2005)). Several authors have criticized maximization as beingunachievable (cf. Boone and Kurtz, 1980; Bagozzi et al., 1998; Keil et al., 2001).

With reference to time, Avlonitis and Indounas (2005) identified that pricingobjectives may be either short- (p12 months) or long term. Moreover, Boone and Kurtz(1980), Bagozzi et al. (1998) and Keil et al. (2001) all suggested that emphasis onshort-term objectives may risk attainment of long term ones. Schlissel (1977) confirmedthat the most popular objective is profit maximization, with achievement ofsatisfactory profit next most popular. Morris and Fuller (1989) investigated 71accounting companies and found that achievement of satisfactory short-term profitwas the most popular pricing objective; while an investigation of pricing practicesamong 45 building societies (Meidan and Chin, 1995) concluded that 480 per centranked cost objectives most important.

The dilemma: under-pricing and overpricing syndromesMa (2005) pointed out that under-pricing means a product being positioned belowintrinsic (market) value. Loughran et al. (1994) in their study of 25 countries foundunder-pricing a global phenomenon. The theory of information asymmetry offersone explanation to under-pricing (Certo et al., 2001). This involves pricing based onconsumers’ lack of information about product value and is used to induce them (Rock,1986). Biener (2011) suggested under-pricing can occur when a monopolistic firmreduces a product price for which (competitive) substitutes exist and that propensityto under-price means a seller is ready to absorb losses and may become a hazard tocompetitors (Baron, 1982). Nonetheless, under-pricing may be used as a vehicle to

361

The consultancypricing paradox

acquire reputation (Neus and Walz, 2002). Paradoxically, some suggest it is also a signof quality (Grinblatt and Hwang, 1989; Allen and Faulhaber, 1989), but the assertionsthat it is a means of compensating for limited experience of new entrants to a market(Neus and Walz, 2002) and is employed for price discrimination by a monopolist(Biener, 2011), seem easier to interpret. Under-pricing may also be directed towardsnear-term goals such as achieving media attention. That is, “signalling effects” of suchstrategy can be directed at the financial press and general media, to attempt valuablepublicity for a company (Biener, 2011).

Empirical evidence suggests theoretical development of overpricing throughthe decades. For instance, Wang et al. (1992) found overpricing in a sample of real estateinvestment trusts; Datta et al. (1997) found overpricing of investment gradebonds; while Cooper et al. (1998) and Hand (2000) documented irrational overpricingof “internet” shares. Research has shown that an initial public offering (IPO)may be overpriced in equilibrium to its expected market price and that IPOs could beboth overvalued and under-priced simultaneously (Purnanandam and Swamination,2004).

The under-pricing/overpricing syndrome has placed consultancy providers in adilemma. Gao (2010) contains empirical evidence that under-pricing may not reflecta fair value for services, while Ritter (1991) and Daniel (2002) support this by empiricaldemonstration. Gao (2010) confirmed the potential for financial losses from under-pricing while Nelson and Economy (1997), opined that mispricing can cause thefailure of consultants. According to Harshaw (2008) overpricing can result in self-offense when the actual price of a product’s real worth becomes later known;while under-pricing fails to achieve income commensurate with the consultant’sservices. AWA (2010) confirmed the dilemma of mispricing insofar as under-pricingleads to over consumption and vice-versa while overpricing services producesextraordinary profits and abuses a monopoly. In a perfect, free market, overpricing willlead to loss of trade and profit to realistic priced products. Skitmore and Smyth (2006)described pricing as an optimization problem, while Gordon et al. (1980) confirmed:

Setting a price too high can indirectly reduce profits via a reduction in the firm’s market share,while setting a price too low can directly reduce a firm’s profits through low profit margin.

Mispricing holds implications for delivery of quality services. According to Sappington(2003), empirical service quality research has focused on the speed and reliabilitywith which new service is installed, the number of problems reported by customers,the speed with which problems are resolved, and overall customer satisfaction.Sappington (2003) further asserted that competition is an important determinant ofservice quality that varies with time and geographical location (see also Clements,2001). Iwarere (2010) suggested that increased global competition calls for improvedservice quality and cost reductions – to achieve both customer satisfaction andenhanced organizational value. Iwarere and Fakokunde (2011) later made the case thatproduct quality has considerable linkage to profit such that improved quality resultsin both production and product reliability, increased productivity lowers cost andincreased product reliability leads to a higher price. Service quality inures to servicereliability thereby underpinning realistic pricing whereas under-pricing leads to underrecovery and the inability of service providers to research, innovate and improvequality. Consequently, product pricing is an aspect of profit planning – qualityinfluences price and so a balancing act is called for to achieve “price attractiveness” fornew customers while maintaining present ones (Iwarere and Fakokunde (2011)).

362

SS30,4

Qualitatively, consumers will normally acknowledge “higher prices” rather than“overpricing” because they are unaware of a product’s price ceiling. The “recognized”medium of overpricing acknowledgement is via regulators like statutory governmentswho intervene with price control; this being more typical in a socialist economyand much less so in a free market economy where economic forces determine priceequilibrium. Overpricing remains under-researched so questions remain such as:“When is a service adjudged to be overpriced? “What is the acceptable price of aproduct? And, “Is there an empirical limit to service price?”

Strategies to achieve service pricing qualityMany factors must be considered to develop optimal pricing strategy (Parece et al.,2002). Strategy decisions will impact geographic, product, and/or customer segmentsand determine opportunities for pricing adjustments (Kutsuna et al., 2006). Strategiesaffect not only revenue and profitability streams, but also volumes and continuation(or severance of) client relationships (Forman and Hunt, 2005). Strategyimplementation and resulting impact on the customer relationships calls for periodicvaluation analyses ( Jain et al., 2008) – helping understand the impact of pricingdecisions (Bitran et al., 2008). It facilitates a proactive approach in managing valuecreation (Mario, 2007) while providing insights regarding the timing/pace of strategyand highlighting opportunities to reprioritize (Jain et al., 2008). Different strategiesmight be employed over time to fit with changes to market conditions or product lifecycle (Roth, 2007). Some pricing strategies are as follows.

Competitive pricing is based on competitors’ prices and can be useful fordifferentiation (Shapiro, 1996). It can help either survival or maintain a status quo(Sahir, 2008). Good, better, best pricing relates price to production input (Roth, 2007)where the product is offered in different formats; the price of each rising abovethat of the previous (HSBC, 2010). Loss leader pricing “lures” customers with lowprice in the expectation that they will subsequently make additional purchases withlarger margins (Schoonveld and Timmerberg, 2005). It should be paired with eitherquantity maximization or partial cost recovery objectives (Schoonveld andTimmerberg, 2005). Multiple pricing seeks to maximize sales (DeGraba, 2003) andworks well with profit- and quantity-maximization objectives (Anderson and Simester,2008). Optional pricing has revenue maximization as its objective (Winter andSundqvist, 2009), while penetration pricing seeks to gain new markets and enticecustomers (Kowalski, 2006). Premium pricing is employed when a product is unique(CIM, 2004), its advantage being a larger margin to make up for the small number ofitems sold (Young, 2009). Product bundle pricing groups several products together andis useful for complementary overstock (Roth, 2007) – it can be matched with revenue orquantity maximization objectives (Reynolds, 2005). Product line pricing is optimalwhen products complement each other and can be packaged to reflect increased value(European Commission, 2000; Jensen, 2008). Skim pricing is similar to premiumpricing, but the price will have to be lowered as competitors enter the market (Hart andMilstein, 2003; Holcombe, 2009). Table I summarizes these pricing strategies, theirunderlying philosophies and trade-offs.

Overcoming shortcomings through systematic pricingThere are shortcomings inherent in the pricing strategies of service providers. Breidertet al. (2006) pointed out that in spite of advances in pricing research; companies oftenmake pricing decisions without a clear understanding of their customers or, their

363

The consultancypricing paradox

Str

ateg

yU

nd

erly

ing

ph

ilos

oph

yT

rad

e-of

fsC

onte

xt

ofap

pli

cati

onL

iter

atu

re

Com

pet

itiv

ep

rici

ng

Su

rviv

alor

stat

us

qu

oC

ost

reco

ver

yan

dp

rofi

tW

hen

dif

fere

nti

atin

gp

rod

uct

sis

dif

ficu

ltS

hap

iro

(199

6),

Sah

ir(2

008)

Goo

d,

bet

ter,

bes

tT

he

mor

eat

ten

tion

giv

ena

pro

du

ct–

hig

her

its

pri

ceQ

uan

tity

max

imiz

atio

n,

inab

ilit

yto

mar

ket

lead

Pac

kag

ing

,so

rtin

gR

oth

(200

7)

Los

sle

ader

Lu

recu

stom

ers

toth

eb

usi

nes

sP

rofi

t,co

stre

cov

ery

Qu

anti

tym

axim

izat

ion

Rot

h(2

007)

,S

choo

nv

eld

and

Tim

mer

ber

g(2

005)

Mu

ltip

lep

rici

ng

Cu

stom

ers

tob

uy

ing

reat

erq

uan

tity

Som

ep

rod

uct

sla

ckat

ten

tion

Pro

fit

and

qu

anti

tym

axim

izat

ion

DeG

rab

a(2

003)

,A

nd

erso

nan

dS

imes

ter

(200

8)O

pti

onal

pri

cin

gQ

ual

ity

lead

ersh

ip,

rev

enu

em

axim

izat

ion

Win

ter

and

Su

nd

qv

ist

(200

9)

Pen

etra

tion

pri

cin

gE

nti

cem

axim

um

nu

mb

erof

cust

omer

sP

rofi

tan

dco

stre

cov

ery

inth

esh

ort

term

To

gai

nen

try

into

an

ewm

ark

etK

owal

ski

(200

6)

Pre

miu

mp

rici

ng

For

pro

du

cts

orse

rvic

esof

ver

yh

igh

qu

alit

yQ

uan

tity

max

imiz

atio

nT

ose

lla

size

able

amou

nt

ofp

rod

uct

CIM

(200

4)

Bu

nd

lep

rici

ng

Gro

up

ing

item

sfo

rsa

leP

rofi

tm

axim

izat

ion

Sel

lin

gol

der

pro

du

cts

Rot

h(2

007)

Sk

imp

rici

ng

Ch

arg

ing

hig

her

pri

cefo

rp

rod

uct

san

dse

rvic

esL

ower

pri

ces

inth

elo

ng

run

Pro

fit

max

imiz

atio

nH

olco

mb

e(2

009)

,R

oth

(200

7)

Table I.Summary of pricingstrategies

364

SS30,4

competition. Other studies have demonstrated that between only 8 and 15 per cent ofcompanies develop pricing strategies based on buyer response behaviour (Monroe andCox, 2001). According to Nagle and Holden (1995), pricing shortcomings can occurwhere marketing mix and/or complex dimensions of cost are not fully understood.Other shortcomings include not taking account of changes in market conditions,competitor behaviour or capacity levels (Skitmore and Smyth, 2006). A lack of reliablepricing models also presents a challenge (Hoffman et al., 2002), as reinforced byHogan and Nagle (2005) who confirmed shortcomings from “resorting” to ad hocmethods. Many agree on the need to estimate customers’ WTP as a panacea to pricingchallenges (see Nagle and Holden, 2002; Monroe, 2003). Price-setters should be awarethat low prices do not always stimulate sales (Skitmore and Smyth, 2006) and thatempirical methods of price determination – to determine what will stimulate sales –may be useful (Olshavsky et al., 1995; Smyth et al., 2006). Noteworthy here, Raftery(1991) confirmed that price models can be based on loose concepts anddo not necessarily require “mathematical precision”.

According to BHP (2011) price setting must accord with product value, costs ofproduction and the price that competitors charge. It is important to communicatethe value and features of products to prospective customers through effective valuecommunications – especially regarding how the product will satisfy unmet customerneed:

[y] as the doctor is trained to look beyond a patient’s symptoms to diagnose underlyingdiseases, it is imperative that price-setters look beyond the pricing symptoms to diagnose theflaws in pricing strategies (Hogan and Nagle, 2005).

Empirical studies suggest that systematic pricing must conform to marketingparadigms, especially, marketing mix (Borden, 1964) and relationship marketing(Berry, 1995). The former encompasses product, place, promotion and price (McCarthy,1964); while relationship marketing encourages business-to-business relationships(Gronroos, 2000; Gummesson, 2001; Ford et al., 2003). Prices cannot be set so high asto damage relationships but must generate profit (Ford et al., 2003) and to this end,Gronroos (2000) emphasized four approaches: service perspective (valuingrelationships), core perspective (core solutions with excellence), price perspective(related to marketing mix) and image perspective (perceived value in which pricesare set considerably above costs). Skitmore and Smyth (2006) meanwhile suggestedthat relationships are critical to “add value or to be of intrinsic value”. Conceptually,relationship marketing is suitable for consultancy services pricing because services arerendered at business-to-business levels and represent “one-off products”.

Towards conceptualization of price and valueRamirez (1999) pointed out that “value” earned its measurable connotation in thethirteenth century, to mean what something is worth. By the sixteenth century it wasassociated with a measurable unit and in the seventeenth century, became known asthe price of something. The idea of value being subjective arrived in the nineteenthcentury and its contemporary meaning is accepted as a personal judgement (Ramirez(1999)). Research has targeted the concept; leading to various definitions. Rhett et al.(2006) suggested it is calculated with reference to perceived quality of results balancedagainst costs. Holbrook (1994) opined that value can be characterized along acontinuum anchored by two extremes (subjectivism and objectivism). For the former,it is regarded as “beauty” – an entirely individual assessment (Perry, 1954; Moore,

365

The consultancypricing paradox

1957; Osborne, 1933). In consonance with this is the belief that value representsa personal preference compared to similar objects (Holbrook, 1994). In contrast,several empirical studies have asserted that objectivism of value is intrinsic or innateto an object and therefore exists as a priori to the process of valuation (Osborne, 1933;Lewis, 1946; Hartman, 1967; Frondizi, 1971; Adler, 1981). According to Ulaga (2001),value is a ratio of benefits versus burdens while Flint et al. (1997) suggested it isa trade-off between benefits and sacrifice. According to Porter (1985) it is simply theamount buyers are willing to pay and in monetary terms, value has been expressed asthe functionality of a product in a given customer application (Anderson et al., 1993;Anderson and Narus, 1998, 1999). Researchers argue that perceived value is thecustomer’s overall assessment of the utility of a product (Zeithaml, 1988). Similarly,Rhett et al. (2006) opined that value is a subjective judgement, while Forsstrom pointedout that it does not include the idea of a measurable unit so much as it is a perception ofwhat can be gained when weighted towards what is given away. Holbrook (1994) statedthat value can be classified into four quadrants as intrinsic/extrinsic sources on oneaxis and the active/reactive sources on the other.

Proponents believe the consumer may experience this return as economic utility(the perception of affordable quality) (Thaler, 1985; Yadav and Monroe, 1993) andutility in turn will be derived from the efficiency of an exchange encounter (Zeithaml,1988; Holbrook, 1994). Within the literature, reactive extrinsic sources of valueencompass service excellence (Holbrook, 1994). Oliver (1999) suggested this dimensionof value serves as an ideal against which quality judgements are formed. Value derivedfrom perceived service excellence reflects generalized consumer appreciation of aservice provider to deliver through expertise and performance Zeithaml (1988); whilereactive sources of intrinsic value largely border on aesthetics (Olson, 1981; Veryzer,1993).

In business studies, value constructs have been variously used. For instance, Porter(1985) used the value chain framework in which economic implications of differentactivities were studied at the firm level. Similarly, Schumpeter (1934) addressedvalue creation through technology change and innovation while Barney (1991) used theconcept of value in a resource-based view of the firm. Lorenzoni and Lipparini (1999)used it in governance mechanisms for value creation; (Gulati et al., 2000) used theconcept in studying the importance of resources for value creation; and Moller andTorronen (2003) pointed out that a value system can be used to create strategicnetworks. There are two broad divisions in conceptualizing value, first, the substantivevalue dealing with reduced costs, increased revenues, enhanced transaction efficiency,improved coordination, profit, volume and economies of scale. Second, there iscognitive value that deals with new products through innovation, competence andsocial rewards.

It is equally important to conceptualize price which according to Noble and Gruca(1999) is quantification of value defined by where the supply and demand curves meetand exchange occurs. Dodds et al. (1991) asserted that price is not only a monetarysacrifice but also a signal of product quality; it can confer an aura of prestige and thushigher price signals higher quality. According to Harrison et al. (2002) pricing is aninteractive matter and there are several approaches in this respect, while Hinterhuber(2008) identified several, namely, cost-based, cost-plus, target, breakeven, targetcontribution margin, competition-based, penetration, price skimming, average market,customer-based, perceived-value, performance and customers’ WTP. Empiricalstudies have demonstrated how each may be appropriate to a particular condition.

366

SS30,4

For instance cost-oriented pricing is suitable for insurance transactions (Erdonmez andNutzenadel, 2006); while for industrial equipment, competition-based pricing is used(Buschken, 2001) and is equally suited to construction projects (Mochtar and Arditi,2001) and, industrial manufacturers (Forman and Lancioni, 2002). Researchersempirically interpret value as a trade-off between quality and price (Dodds andMonroe, 1985; Yadav and Monroe, 1993) and some have strongly asserted that priceextends far beyond money to include investment of time and effort (Zeithaml, 1988;Bolton and Drew, 1991; Babin et al., 1994). Table II summarizes the conceptualdefinitions of price and value identified in this review.

A future research agendaThe following discusses research paradoxes as far as pricing of services is concernedand other issues pertinent to this study. Research gaps are highlighted and suggestedfuture areas for exploration are given.

Price and valueNumerous works have targeted value but its measurement is less researched.Hanemann (2005) argued that economic value is different from price and that itemswith no market price can still have an economic value. Hanemann agrees with Hayek(2008), that price level and production volume are correlated and demand and supplydetermine market or “fundamental price”. The measure of value is what an item isworth to an individual not the cost of acquiring it so if consulting services are valuableto clients, they will be ready to pay good prices for them. The challenge is making

Item Definition Literature sources

Price Is where demand and supply meet and exchange takes placeIs a quantification of value

Noble and Gruca (1999)

Is a signal of quality Dodds et al. (1991)Is only an aspect of the economic outcome of a relationship Harrison et al. (2002)

Value Is what something is worthIs the price for somethingIs something based on personal judgement

Ramirez (1999)

Is an equation calculated with reference to the perceivedquality of results

Rhett et al. (2006)

Is regarded as “beauty” Moore (1957), Osborne(1993)

Represents personal preference formed as a consequenceof interaction between a subject and an object with referenceto other comparable objects

Holbrook (1994)

Is intrinsic or innate to an object and therefore exists as apriori to the process of valuation

Lewis (1946), Hartman(1967), Frondizi (1971)

Is a ratio of benefits versus burdens endured by thecustomer

Ulaga (2001)

Is a trade-off between benefits and sacrifice Flint et al. (1997)Is the amount buyers are willing to pay Porter (1985)Is the total functionality or performance of a productoffering in a given application

Anderson et al. (1993),Anderson and Narus (1998)

Is the primary motivation for entering into business ormarketing relationships

Holbrook (1994), Babinet al. (1994), Peterson (1995)

Table II.Price and value

constructs

367

The consultancypricing paradox

consulting services valuable, attracting a realistic price and demonstrating that theconcept of economic value can be applied “to (such) non-market” intangible items.According to Hanemann (2005), economic valuation is the monetary valuationof products that people are concerned about and non-market valuation refersto the valuation of items that are not sold in the market. Drawing on this, futureresearch on the measurement of value in relation to consultant services could helpascertain the willingness of clients to accept what is on offer. It is therefore,hypothesized that:

H1. The worth of a consultant service is significantly dependent on: (H1a) itsmeasure of economic value and (H1b) the ability of consultants to demonstratepotential value of their services by realistic pricing.

Nature of serviceDe Chernatony and McDonald (1998) argued that notwithstanding research on productmarketing, the classification of services requires research because many of theemergent types, do not conveniently fit with previous designations. Kotler (1991)categorized four services varying from “pure product” to “pure service” while Payne(1993) identified the continuum of tangible-intangible and demonstrated that an offerof services is highly intangible. For instance, computer hardware and programmesare highly tangible commodities but the service elements of user training andtroubleshooting are intangible. Vandermerwe and Rada (1988) coined the term“servitisation” to represent a combination of training, consultancy, service contracts,troubleshooting, financing, delivery, guarantees, stockholding and computer links.

One notable theoretical development is the services classification scheme (Bowen,1990; Gronroos, 1990) which yielded strategic insights in response to questions: what isthe nature of the “service” act?, What style of relationship does the service organizationhave with its customers?, How much room is there for customization and judgement?and What is the nature of supply and demand for the service? It is imperative toaccurately classify consultant services in order to inform consultancy pricing so anempirical study, especially of emerging consultancy services, will be timely. It ishypothesized:

H2. The classification of services is significantly dependent on the nature of: (H2a)demand for emerging services and (H2b) supply of those services.

CompetenceCompetence in service delivery is at the core of effective pricing. Djaloeis et al. (2010)pointed out that consultant competence is paramount to quality service delivery. Theyfurther argued the need for professional competence to remain at the “cutting edge”.A theoretical competence model was proposed considering fields of activity, areas ofcompetence and levels of reflection. The competence of the consultant will inure to thebenefit of both parties of the (consultancy) contract in the sense that there will beinnovation, knowledge transfer and fairness in its discharge. Competence aids realisticservice pricing and research to develop a framework for measuring competence wouldbe of benefit, in the context of:

H3. The competence of consultants is significantly dependent on their ability to(H3a) transfer knowledge, (H3b) price innovatively, (H3c) successfullyimplement solutions and (H3d) innovatively manage the assignment.

368

SS30,4

Service brandingA brand creates a relationship personified by organizational name – it is important inconsultancy in influencing price levels. De Chernatony and McDonald (1998)stated that a successful brand is an identifiable product that the buyer perceivesrelevant and value adding. Successful brands conform to criteria including aname, logo or design which identifies the organization with a product. Just likeany asset, a successful brand will depreciate without further investment. A brandcreates perception in the mindset of consumers, so perceptions must be consistent,positive and shared. To improve brand strength means to constantly shape theseperceptions so that consumers remain positive, but this can be complex. For instance,in the financial sector, few brands have created complete consumer perception (Denby,1995).

De Chernatony and McDonald (1998) asserted that the “deregulation” of manypublic corporations around the world, especially in the UK and other Europeancountries, has led to the creation of brands that “edge out” competitors. Service-basedbrands (vis-a-vis product based) involve multiplicity of interface with the consumer(Shostak, 1977). Levy (1996) contends that application of product-based brandingprinciples to service-based provision without adaptation is unlikely to be effective. It iscontended here, that an empirical basis for the adaptation of product-based branding toservice-based branding will be a novel approach. Hence:

H4. The success of service branding is significantly dependent on: (H4a) name,(H4b) logo and (H4c) relevant value adding.

H5. The strength of service branding is significantly dependent on the customerperception of services offered.

Summary of outcomesIn exploration of key issues that affect the pricing of consultancy services, the conceptsof price and value have been thoroughly examined and important issues underlinedand conceptual explanations have been summarized (cf. Table I). Various forms ofvalue have been identified: intrinsic, extrinsic, substantive, cognitive and monetary.Perceived value is critical to successful pricing.

Approaches to pricing and their interrelationship with supply and demandwere explored and fundamental pricing objectives are cost recovery and profitmaximization. Pricing objectives have been categorized as those that seekmaximization or, satisfaction. Under-pricing and overpricing philosophies wereexamined and found key in that they can edge out the consultant in a free market.Innovative ways of overcoming the shortcomings of these syndromes consist of theestimation of WTP, use of empirical methods of price determination and employmentof realistic methods to determine price stimulants.

The rudiments of consultancy services pricing were thoroughly examined in whichall the components of consultancy price were identified and synthesized. Resultantlya conceptual framework which considers all the critical issues bordering consultancypricing is shown in Figure 3.

Conclusions and recommendationsThe study confirms need for removal of the consultancy service pricing paradox. Thetheoretical framework proposed can serve as a paradigm for service pricing in future,

369

The consultancypricing paradox

especially, given emerging consultant services. The following are some of the keyfindings relating to the pricing paradox:

. value is key to price determination and they are symbiotically related hencecannot be separated, though one can represent a trade-off with the other andprice is the quantification of value;

. service branding is critical to successful pricing, under-pricing is more prevalentthan overpricing;

. consumers differ as a result of information costs such as effort and search costs,time, price sensitivities and transaction costs such as obtaining funds and thecost of uncertainty;

. the ability to estimate the client’s WTP is a panacea to numerous failings ofpricing strategies; and

. consultant pricing must accord with service value, cost of production andcompetitors, yet ultimately, is an interaction between the consultant and client.

The main hypotheses formulated in signposting a future research agenda centre onthe: worth of consultancy services, classification of consultancy services, competenceof consultants and strength of services branding.

Demand/supply

EquilibriumPricing

syndromes

• Under-pricing• Over-pricing

Pricingapproaches

• Competitive• Good, better, best• Loss leader• Optional, etc.

Pricingobjectives

• Maximization• Satisfaction

Pricingfactors

• Cost• Demand• Location• Regulation

Consultancy

Pricing

• Profitability• Win-win• Price sustainability

• Name• Logo/symbol• Personification

Services branding

• Innovation• Knowledge transfer• Fairness

Competence

• Methods• Models

Price determinants

• Efficiency• Value for money• Optimization• Productivity, etc.

Quality service delivery

• Type and character• Relationships• Retainability• Contract details• Time frame• Servitisation

Nature ofservices

Value• Substantive value• Cognitive value

Figure 3.A conceptual model ofconsultancy servicespricing

370

SS30,4

References

ACENZ (2004), Guideline on the Briefing and Engagement for Consulting Engineering Services,The Association of Consulting Engineers NZ, Wellington.

Adler, M.J. (1981), Six Great Ideas, Macmillan, New York, NY.

Adner, R. (2004), “A demand-based perspective on technology life cycles”, Advances in Strategicmanagement, Vol. 21, pp. 25-43.

Allen, F. and Faulhaber, G.R. (1989), “Signaling by under-pricing in the IPO market”, Journal ofFinancial Economics, Vol. 23 No. 2, pp. 303-23.

Anderson, E.T. and Simester, D.I. (2008), Price Cues and Customer Price Knowledge, MIT SoloanSchool of Management, Massachusetts, MA.

Anderson, J.C. and Narus, J.A. (1998), “Business marketing: understand what customers value”,Harvard Business Review, Vol. 76, November-December, pp. 53-65.

Anderson, J.C. and Narus, J.A. (1999), Business Market Management: Understanding, Creating,and Delivering Value, Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River, NJ.

Anderson, J.C., Jain, D. and Chintagunta, P. (1993), “Customer value assessment in businessmarkets: a state-of practice study”, Journal of Business-to-Business Marketing, Vol. 1 No. 1,pp. 3-29.

Ansari, A., Siddarth, S. and Weinberg, C.B. (1996), “Pricing a bundle of products or services: thecase of nonprofits”, Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 33 No. 1, pp. 86-93.

APEGGA (2005), Development of Consulting Rate Structures and Contracts, APEGGA, Alberta.

Appelbaum, S.H. and Steed, A.J. (2003), “The critical success factors in the client-consultingrelationship”, Journal of Management Development, Vol. 24 No. 1, pp. 68-93.

Avlonitis, G.J. and Indounas, K.A. (2005), “Pricing objectives and pricing methods in the servicessector”, Journal of Services Marketing, Vol. 19 No. 1, pp. 47-57.

AWA (2010), “Cost-reflective pricing”, Position Paper, AWA, available at: www.awa.asn.au/uploadedFiles/Position%20paper%20cost%20reflecting%20prices.pdf (accessed July2012).

Babin, B.J., Darden, W.R. and Griffin, M. (1994), “Work and/or fun: measuring hedonic andutilitarian shopping value”, Journal of Consumer Research, Vol. 20 No. 4, pp. 644-56.

Bagozzi, R.P., Rose, J.A., Celly, K.T. and Coronel, F. (1998), Marketing Management, Prentice-Hall,Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

Barney, J.B. (1991), “Firms resources and sustained competitive advantage”, Journal ofManagement, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 99-120.

Baron, D.P. (1982), “A model of the demand for investment banking advising and distributionservices for new issues”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 37 No. 4, pp. 955-76.

Bateson, J.E.G. (1995), Managing Services Marketing: Texts and Readings, 3rd ed., The DrydenPress, Orlando, FL.

Berry, L.L. (1995), “Relationship marketing of services – growing interest, emergingperspectives”, Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science., Vol. 23 No. 4, pp. 236-45Springer, London.

BHP (2011), Pricing Your Product or Service, BHP Information Solutions Ltd, London.

Biener, C. (2011), “Pricing in micro-insurance markets”, working papers on Risk Managementand Insurance, No. 106, University of St Gallen, available at: www.ivw.unisg.ch/Forschung/Grundlagenforschung/B/media/Internet/Content/Dateien/InstituteUndCenters/IVW/WPs/WP106.ashx (accessed July 2012).

Bitran, G.R., Oliveira, P.R. and Schilkrut, A. (2008), “Managing customer relationship throughprice and service quality”, Working Paper No. WP-750. IESE Business School, University

371

The consultancypricing paradox

of Navarra, available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id¼ 1264933(accessed July 2012).

Bolton, R.N. and Drew, J.H. (1991), “A multistage model of customers’ assessment of servicequality and value”, Journal of Consumer Research, Vol. 17 No. March, pp. 375-84.

Bonnici, L.H. (1991), “Pricing dimensions in health-care service”, Journal of Professional ServicesMarketing, Vol. 8 No. 1, pp. 92-8.

Boone, L.E. and Kurtz, D.L. (1980), Pricing: How Not to Succeed, 3rd ed., The Dryden Press,Orlando, FL.

Borden, N. (1964), “The concept of the marketing mix”, Journal of Advertising Research, Vol. 4,June, pp. 7-12.

Bowen, J. (1990), “Development of a taxonomy of services to gain strategic marketing insights”,Journal of the Academy of Marketing Sciences, Vol. 18 No. 1, pp. 43-9.

Breidert, C., Hahsler, M. and Reutterer, T. (2006), “A review of methods for measuringwillingness-to-pay”, Innovative Marketing, Vol. 2 No. 4, pp. 8-32.

Buschken, J. (2001), “Umfrage zum Status Quo der Nutzung von Preisstrategien in Deutschland”,working paper, Katholische Universitat Eichstatt, Eichstatt.

Cannon, H.M. and Morgan, F.W. (1990), “A strategic pricing framework”, Journal of ServicesMarketing, Vol. 4 No. 2, pp. 19-30.

Certo, S.T., Covin, J.G., Daily, C.M. and Dalton, D.R. (2001), “Wealth and the effects of foundermanagement among IPO-stage new ventures”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 22Nos 6/7, pp. 641-58.

Consulting Engineers South Africa (CESA) (2009), Procurement of Consulting EngineeringServices in the Construction Industry: A Guide for Consulting Engineering Firms, CESA,Johannesburg.

Channon, D.F. (1986), Bank Strategic Management and Marketing, Chapter 8, John Wiley & Sons,Chichester.

CIM (2004), “Unique selling proposition”, available at: www.cim.co.uk (accessed 10 November2011).

Clements, M. (2001), “Local telephone quality of service: the impact of regulation andcompetition”, PhD dissertation, Ohio State University, Ohio.

Cooper, A.C., Woo, C.A. and Dunkelberg, W. (1998), “Entrepreneurs’ perceived chances forsuccess”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 3 No. 2, pp. 97-108.

Daniel, K. (2002), “Why don’t issuers get upset about leaving money on the table in IPOs?”, TheReview of Financial Studies, special edition on Market frictions and behavioural finance,available at: http://www.columbia.edu/Bkd2371/papers/published/RFS_02.pdf (accessedJuly 2012).

Datta, S., Iskander-Datta, M. and Patell, A. (1997), “The pricing of initial public offering ofcorporate straight debt”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 52 No. 1, pp. 379-96.

Davidson, A. and Simonetto, M. (2005), “Pricing strategy and execution: an overlooked way toincrease revenues and profits”, Strategy & Leadership, Vol. 33 No. 6, pp. 25-33.

de Chernatony, L. and McDonald, M. (1998), Creating Powerful Brands, 2nd ed., Butterworth-Heinemann, Oxford.

DeGraba, P. (2003), Volume Discounts, Loss Leaders, and Competition for More ProfitableCustomers, Federal Trade Commission, Washington, DC.

DeLozier, M.W. and Woodside, G. (1976), “Pricing and marketing communications: thenoneconomic factors”, Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, Vol. 4 No. 4,pp. 814-24.

Denby, J. (1995), “Retail banking: mind the gap”, The Banker, Vol. 145 No. 828, pp. 66-9.

372

SS30,4

Djaloeis, R., Martin, F., Heinen, S. and Schlick, S.M. (2010), “Measurement of competence andprofessionalism in energy consulting”, Proceedings of the 1st UPI International Conferenceon Technical and Vocational Education and Training, Bandung, 10-11 November.

Dodds, W., Monroe, K. and Grewal, D. (1991), “Effects of price, brand, and store information onbuyers product evaluations”, Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 28 No. 3, pp. 307-19.

Dodds, W.B. and Monroe, K.B. (1985), “The effect of brand and price information on subjectiveproduct evaluations”, Advances in Consumer Research, Vol. 12, pp. 87-90.

Drake, L. and Llewellyn, D.T. (1995), “The pricing of bank payments services”, InternationalJournal of Bank Marketing, Vol. 13 No. 5, pp. 3-11.

Erdonmez, M. and Nutzenadel, C. (2006), “Pricing-strategien in der Motorfahrzeug-Versicherung”, presentation at the University of St. Gallen, May, available at:www.solutionproviders.com/desktopdefault.aspx/tabid-86/76_read-124/ (accessed July2012).

European Commission (2000), Guide to the Implementation of Directives Based on the NewApproach and the Global Approach, Office for Official Publications of the EuropeanCommunities, Luxembourg.

Falch, M. (2004), “Cost based interconnection charges, competition and investments”, DiscussionPaper No. WDR 0308, WDR Dialogue Theme 2003, WDR, available at: www.ictregulationtooolkit.org/en/Publication.2918.html (accessed July 2012).

Flint, D.J., Woodruff, R.B. and Gardial, S.F. (1997), “Customer value change in industrialmarketing relationships: a call for new strategies and research”, Industrial MarketingManagement, Vol. 26 No. 2, pp. 163-75.

Ford, D., Gadde, L-E., Hakansson, H. and Snehota, I. (2003), Managing Business Relationships,Wiley, Chichester.

Forman, H. and Hunt, J.M. (2005), “Managing the influence of internal and external determinantson international industrial pricing strategies”, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 34No. 2, pp. 133-46.

Forman, H. and Lancioni, R. (2002), “The determinants of pricing strategies for industrialproducts in international markets”, Journal of Business-to-Business Marketing, Vol. 9 No. 2,pp. 29-62.

Frondizi, R. (1971), What is Value? An Introduction to Axiology, 2nd ed., Open Court, La Salle, IL.

Gao, Y. (2010), “What comprises IPO initial returns: evidence from the Chinese market”,Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, Vol. 18 No. 1, pp. 77-89.

Gordon, L.A., Cooper, R., Falk, H. and Miller, D. (1980), The Pricing Decision, The NationalAssociation of Accountants and The Society of Management Accountants of Canada,New York.

Greiner, L.E. and Metzger, R.O. (1983), Consulting to Management, Prentice-Hall, EnglewoodCliffs, NJ.

Grinblatt, S.I. and Hwang, C.Y. (1989), “Signalling and the pricing of new issues”, Journal ofFinance, Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 393-420.

Gronroos, C. (1990), Services Management and Marketing, Lexington Books, Lexington, MA.

Gronroos, C. (2000), Service Management and Marketing, John Wiley and Sons, London.

Gulati, R., Nohria, N. and Zaheer, A. (2000), “Strategic networks”, Strategic Management Journal,Special Issue, Vol. 21 No. 3, pp. 203-15.

Gummesson, E. (2001), Total Relationship Marketing, Butterworth-Heinemann, Oxford.

Hand, J. (2000), “The role of accounting fundamentals, web traffic, and supply and demand inthe pricing of US internet stock”, working paper, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill,NC.

373

The consultancypricing paradox

Hanemann, M. (2005), The Value of Water, University of California, Berkeley, CA.

Harrison, D., Hakansson, H. and Gadde, L. (2002), “Pricing in business-to-business research: priceas an empirical phenomenon”, available at: www.impgroup.org/paper_view.php?viewPaper¼448 (accessed July 2012).

Harshaw, R. (2008), Business Valuation, Lodestar Consulting Systems Inc, Arizona.

Hart, S.L. and Milstein, M.B. (2003), “Creating sustainable value”, Academy ManagementExecutive, Vol. 17 No. 2, pp. 56-67.

Hartman, R.S. (1967), The Structure of Values: Foundations of Scientific Axiology, SouthernIllinois University Press, Carbondale, IL.

Hayek, F.A. (2008), Prices and Production and Other Works, Ludwig von Mises Institute,Auburn, AL.

Hinterhuber, A. (2008), “Value delivery and value-based pricing in industrial markets”, Creatingand Managing Superior Customer Value Advances in Business Marketing and Purchasing,Vol. 14, pp. 381-448.

Hoffman, K.D. and Bateson, J.E.G. (1997), Essentials of Services Marketing, The Dryden Press,Orlando, FL.

Hoffman, K.D., Turley, L.W. and Scott, W.K. (2002), “Pricing retail services”, Journal of BusinessResearch, Vol. 55 No. 12, pp. 1015-23.

Hogan, J. and Nagle, T. (2005), “What is strategic pricing?”, SPG Insights, Summer, available at:http://pricing2b.com/web_documents/what_is_strategic_pricing.pdf (accessed July 2012).

Holbrook, M.B. (1994), “The nature of customer value: an axiology of services in the consumptionexperience”, Service Quality: New Directions in Theory and Practice, in Rust, R.T. andOliver, R.L. (Eds), Sage, Newbury Park, CA, pp. 1-21.

Holcombe, R.G. (2009), “Product differentiation and economic progress”, The Quarterly JournalOf Austrian Economics, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 17-35.

HSBC (2010), “Growth of Hong Kong private sector economy sustained for sixth successiveMonth”, compiled by Markit, HSBC, available at: www.hsbc.com/1/PA_esf-ca-app-content/content/assets/emi/2010/1001_pmi_report_hongkong_manufacturing_en.pdf (accessedJuly 2012).

Iwarere, H.T. (2010), “How far has the manufacturing industry achieve total quality managementin Nigeria”, European Journal of Social Sciences, London, United Kingdom, Vol. 15 No. 2,pp. 34-43.

Iwarere, H.T. and Fakokunde, T.O. (2011), “Consumers’ perception of product and service qualityand price in the Nigerian fast food industry: a case of selected outlets in Ekiti State,Nigeria”, European Journal of Social Sciences, Vol. 19 No. 2.

Jain, A., Gil, J. and Sims, C. (2008), “Applying customer relationship valuation”, The Journal ofProfessional Pricing, Vol. 19 No. 3, pp. 18-20.

Jensen, R. (2008), Value Maximization and the Corporate Objective Function, Negotiations,Organizations and Markets Units, Harvard Business School, Boston, Cambridge, MA.

Keil, S.K., Reibstein, D. and Wittink, D.R. (2001), “The impact of business objectives and the timehorizon of performance evaluation on pricing behavior”, International Journal of Researchin Marketing, Vol. 18 Nos 1/2, pp. 67-81.

Kiesling, M.K. and Hansen, M. (1993), “Integrated air freight cost structure: the case of federalexpress”, working paper, UCTC No. 400, The University of California TransportationCenter, available at: www.uctc.net/papers/400.pdf (accessed July 2012).

Kotler, P. (1991), Marketing Management: Analysis Planning and Control, 7th ed., Prentice Hall,Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

Kowalski, E. (2006), The Basics of Price Analysis, Financial services Office (FSO), University ofArizona.

374

SS30,4

Kutsuna, K., Smith, J.K. and Smith, R.L. (2006), Public Information, IPO Price Formation, andLong- Run Returns: Japanese Evidence, Graduate School of Business Administration KobeUniversity, available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id¼ 902661(accessed July 2012).

Langeard, E. (2000), “Specificity of the pricing policy in service activities”, Innovations andPerspectives, A paper presented at The International Research Seminar in ServiceManagement, Le Londe Les Maures, June, pp. 243-56.

Levy, M. (1996), “Current accounts and baked beans: translating FMCG principles to the financialsector”, The Journal Of Brand Management, Vol. 4 No. 2, pp. 95-9.

Lewis, C.I. (1946), An Analysis of Knowledge and Valuation, Open Court, La Salle, IL.

Lorenzoni, G. and Lipparini, A. (1999), “The leveraging of interfirm relationships as a distinctiveorganizational capability: a longitudinal study”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 20No. 4, pp. 317-38.

Loughran, Y., Ritter, J.R. and Rydqvist, K. (1994), “Initial public offerings: international insights”,Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, Vol. 2 Nos 2/3, pp. 165-99.

Lovelock, C.H. (1996), Services Marketing, 3rd ed., Prentice-Hall., Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

Luk, W.L. (2009), “Privately owned public space in Hong Kong and New York: the urban andspatial influence of the policy”, The 4th International Conference of the InternationalForum on urbanism (IFoU), 26-28 November, Amsterdam/Delft.

McCarthy, E.J. (1964), “Basic Marketing”, Homewood, I.L.I. (Ed.), Reading in Danish Theory ofMarketing, Forlag, Copenhagen.

Ma, S. (2005), “Why are the first day returns of China’s IPOs so high?”, Faculty of CommercePapers, University of Wollongong, Wollongong.

Mario, O. (2007), “From compliance to value creation: the evolution of enterprise riskManagement”, Enterprise Value Based Management, Algorithmics, available at: http://cours2.fsa.ulaval.ca/cours/gsf-60808/ERM_value_creation_wp100207.pdf (accessed July 2012).

Meidan, A. (1996), Marketing Financial Services, Macmillan Business Press, London.

Meidan, A. and Chin, A.C. (1995), “Mortgage-pricing determinants a comparative investigation ofnational, regional and local building societies”, International Journal of Bank Marketing,Vol. 13 No. 3, pp. 3-11.

Michielse, G. and Thuronyi, V. (2009), “Overview of cooperation on capacity building intaxation”, Committee of Experts on International Cooperation in Tax Matters SixthSession, Geneva, 18-22 October 2010.

Ministry of Finance (2009), Handbook of Guidelines for Consultancy Services, Central TendersBoard, Government of the Republic of Trinidad and Tobago, available at:www.finance.gov.tt/content/pubAB7A24.pdf (accessed July 2012).

Mochtar, K. and Arditi, D. (2001), “Pricing strategy in the US construction industry”,Construction Management and Economics, Vol. 19 No. 4, pp. 405-15.

Moller, K.E. and Torronen, P. (2003), “Business suppliers’ value creation potential – a capability-based analysis”, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 32 No. 2, pp. 109-18.

Monroe, K. (2003), Pricing: Making Profitable Decisions, 3rd ed., McGraw-Hill Irwin, Columbus.

Monroe, K.B. and Cox, J.L. (2001), “Pricing practices that endanger profits”, MarketingManagement, Vol. 10 No. 3, pp. 42-6.

Moore, W. (1957), The Language of Values, Columbia University Press, New York, NY.

Morris, M.H. and Fuller, D.A. (1989), “Pricing an industrial service”, Industrial MarketingManagement, Vol. 18 No. 2, pp. 139-46.

Naarmala, J. and Tuomi, V. (2006), Product Oriented Thinking and Expert Knowledge inConsulting Services, University of Vaasa, available at: http://iceb.nccu.edu.tw/proceedings/2006/defevent/papers/cr1017.pdf (accessed July 2012).

375

The consultancypricing paradox

Nagle, T.T. and Holden, R.K. (1995), The Strategy and Tactics of Pricing, Prentice-Hall,Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

Nagle, T.T. and Holden, R.K. (2002), The Strategy and Tactics of Pricing, Prentice- Hall, UpperSaddle River, NJ.

Nees, D.B. and Greiner, L.E. (1985), “Seeing behind the look-alike management consultants”,Organizational Dynamics, Vol. 13, Winter, pp. 68-79.

Nelson, B. and Economy, P. (1997), Consulting for Dummies, IDG Books, London.

Neus, W. and Walz, U. (2002), Exit Timing of Venture Capitalists in the Course of an Initial PublicOffering, Department of Banking, University of Tubingen, Tubingen.

Niewien, S. and Richter, A. (2004), “The changing balance of power in the consulting market”,Business Strategy Review, Vol. 15 No. 1, pp. 8-13.

Noble, P.M. and Gruca, T.S. (1999), “Industrial pricing: theory and managerial practice”,Marketing Science, Vol. 18 No. 3, pp. 435-54.

OECD (2008), OECD Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Oliver, R. (1999), “Customer value: a framework for analysis and research”, in Holbrook, M. (Ed.),Routledge, London and New York, NY, pp. 43-62.

Olshavsky, R.W., Aylesworth, A.B. and Kempf, D.S. (1995), “The price-choice relationship: acontingent processing approach”, Journal of Business Research, Vol. 33 No. 3, pp. 207-18.

Olson, J.C. (1981), “Symbolic consumer behavior”, in Hirschman, E.C. and Holbrook, M.B. (Eds),Association for Consumer Research, Ann Arbor, NY, pp. 71-4.

Osborne, H. (1933), Foundations of the Philosophy of Value, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Oxenfeldt, A.R. (1983), “Pricing decisions: how they are made and how they are influenced”,Management Review, November, pp. 23-5.

Palmer, A. (1994), Principles of Services Marketing, McGraw-Hill, London.

Parece, A., Rankin, P. and Mehndiratta, S. (2002), “Optimal pricing strategies”, PharmaceuticalExecutive for Global Business and Marketing Leaders, available at: www.crai.com/uploadedFiles/RELATING_MATERIALS/Newsletters/BC/Optimal%20Pricing%20Strategies.pdf (accessed July 2012).

Patsula, P.J. (2007), The Entrepreneur’s Guidebook Series, Patsula Media, Arlington, TX,available at: www.smbtn.com/books/gb54.pdf (accessed July 2012).

Payne, A. (1993), The Essence of Services Marketing, Prentice-Hall, London.

Perreault, W.D. and McCarthy, E.J. (2002), Basic Marketing: A Global Managerial Approach,McGraw-Hill Companies Inc, New York, NY.

Perry, R.B. (1954), Realms of Value, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.

Peterson, R.A. (1995), “Relationship marketing and the consumer”, Journal of the Academy ofMarketing and Science, Vol. 23 No. 4, pp. 478-281.

Porter, M. (1985), Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance, FreePress, New York, NY.

Purnanandam, A.K. and Swamination, B. (2004), “Are IPOs really underpriced?”, The Review ofFinancial Studies, Vol. 17 No. 3, pp. 812-48.

Raftery, J. (1991), Principles of Building Economics, BSP Professional Books, Oxford.

Ramirez, R. (1999), “Value co-production: intellectual origins and implications for practice andresearch”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 20, pp. 49-65.

Reynolds, R.L. (2005), “Alternative/microeconomics-Part II”, Pure Competition, Chapter 12, p. 1,available at: http://web1. boisestate.edu/econ/ lreynol/web/PDF/ short_12_pure_ comp.pdf(accessed July 2012).

376

SS30,4

Rhett, H.W., Lester, W.J. and Sean, L. (2006), “Re-thinking the conceptualization of customer valueand service quality within the service-profit chain”, Managing Service Quality, Vol. 16No. 1, pp. 23-36.

Ritter, J.R. (1991), “The long-run performance of initial public offerings”, Journal of Finance,Vol. 46 No. 1, pp. 3-27.

Rock, K. (1986), “Why new issues are underpriced”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 15Nos 1/2, pp. 187-212.

Roth, S.A. (2001), Understanding Pricing Objectives and Strategies For the Value-Added AgProducer, The Pennsylvania State University, Pennsylvania.

Roth, S.A. (2007), Understanding Pricing Objectives and Strategies for the Value-Added AgeProducer, The Pennsylvania State University, Pennsylvania.

Sahir, A. (2008), State of the Market: Retail Survival Strategies for 2009, Aberdeen Group,A Harte-Hanks Company, Boston.

Sappington, D.E.M. (2003), “The effects of incentive regulation on retail telephone service qualityin the United States”, Review of Network Economics, Vol. 2 No. 4, pp. 355-75.

Schein, E.H. (1990), Process Consultation: Its Role in Organizational Development, Vol. I,Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA.

Schlissel, M.R. (1977), “Pricing in a service industry”, MSU Business Topics, Vol. 25, Spring, pp. 37-48.

Schoonveld, S.W. and Timmerberg, J.L. (2005), “Managing closed long-term care insuranceblocks for profit”, available at: www.google.co.uk/url?sa¼ t&rct¼j&q¼timmerberg%2C%20j.l.% 20%282005%29.%20managing% 20closed%20blocks&source¼web&cd¼1&ved¼0CFIQFjAA&url¼http%3A%2F%2Fwww.soa.org%2Ffiles%2Fpd%2Fannual- mtg%2F2009-boston-schoonveld-110.pdf &ei¼ auMFUNjqDMfP4QTQuPH0CA&usg¼AFQjCNHOtCKPgMxT2hhwKU82XrK- vVYcUA&cad¼ rja (accessed July 2012).

Schumpeter, J. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital,Credit, Interest and the Business Cycle, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.

Shapiro, C. (1996), Mergers with Differentiated Products, Antitrust Division, US Department ofJustice, available at: http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/diversion.pdf (accessed July2012)

Shaw, M. (1992), “Positioning and price: merging theory, strategy, and tactics”, Journal ofHospitality and Tourism Research, Vol. 15 No. 31, pp. 31-9.

Sheedy, T., Ross, C.F. and Rose, E. (2010), The Right Pricing Model For Your Systems Integrationand IT Consulting Projects, Forrester Research Inc, Cambridge, MA, available at: www.forrester.com/TheþRightþPricingþModelþForþYourþSystemsþIntegrationþAndþITþConsultingþProjects/fulltext/-/E-RES56015 (accessed July 2012).

Shostak, G.L. (1977), “Breaking free form product marketing”, Journal of Marketing, Vol. 41 No. 4,pp. 73-80.

Skitmore, M. and Smyth, H. (2006), Pricing Construction Work: A Marketing Viewpoint, School ofConstruction Management and Property Queensland University of Technology GardensPoint, Brisbane.

Smyth, H.J., Morris, P.W.G. and Cooke-Davies, T. (2006), “Understanding project management:philosophical and methodological issues”, Proceedings of Euram 2006, BI ManagementSchool, Oslo, May 17-20.

Sultana, R.E. (2009), “Career guidance policies: global dynamics, local resonances”, University ofMalta, available at: www.derby.ac.uk/files/icegs_global_dynamics_local_resonances.pdf(accessed July 2012).

Tellis, G.J. (1986), “Beyond the many faces of price: an integration of pricing strategies”, Journalof Marketing, Vol. 50 No. 4, pp. 146-60.

377

The consultancypricing paradox

Thaler, R. (1985), “Mental accounting and consumer choice”, Marketing Science, Vol. 4No. 3, pp. 199-214.

Tsiotsou, R. (2005), “Perceived quality levels and their relation to involvement, satisfactionand purchase intentions”, Marketing Bulletin, 16 Research Note 4.

Tzokas, N., Hart, S., Argouslidis, P. and Saren, M. (2000a), “Industrial export pricing practices inthe UK”, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 29 No. 3, pp. 191-204.

Tzokas, N., Hart, S., Argouslidis, P. and Saren, M. (2000b), “Strategic pricing in export markets:empirical evidence from the UK”, International Business Review, Vol. 9 No. 1, pp. 95-117.

Ulaga, W. (2001), “Customer value in business markets – an agenda for inquiry”, IndustrialMarketing Management, Vol. 30, pp. 315-9.

Vandermerwe, S. and Rada, J. (1988), “Servitization of business: adding value by adding service”,European Management Journal, Vol. 6 No. 4, pp. 314-423.

Veryzer, R.W. Jr (1993), “Aesthetic response and the influence of design principles on productpreferences”, in McAlister, L. and Rothschild, M.L. (Eds), Advances in Consumer Research,Vol. 20, association for Consumer Research, Provo, UT, pp. 224-8.

Wang, K., Chan, S.H. and Gau, G.W. (1992), “Initial public offerings of equity securities:anomalous evidence using REITs”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 31 No. 3, pp. 381-410.

WBI (2003), “Public policy for corporate social responsibility”, WBI Series on CorporateResponsibility, Accountability and Sustainable Competitiveness, WBI, 7-25 July, availableat: http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/57434/publicpolicy_econference.pdf(accessed July 2012).

Winter, S. and Sundqvist, S. (2009), “The relationship between network effects, new productpricing strategies and sales performance: a quadratic and interaction effect estimation”,Lappeenranta University of Technology, available at: www.duplication.net.au/ANZMAC09/papers/ANZMAC2009-531.pdf (accessed July 2012).

Woodruff, H. (1995), Services Marketing, Pitman Publishing, London.

(The) World Bank (2002), Consulting Services Manual: A Comprehensive Guide to Selection ofConsultants, Office of the Publisher, Washington, DC.

Yadav, M.S. and Monroe, K.B. (1993), “How buyers perceive savings in a bundle price: anexamination of a bundle’s transaction value”, Journal of Marketing Research, Vol. 30No. 3, pp. 350-8.

Young, M. (2009), “Maximize your screen printing quality and profits”, SGIA Journal, SecondQuarter, available at: http://rh-solutionsllc.com/wp-content/uploads/2011/08/Maximize-Your-Screen-Printing-Quality-Profits-Part-One.pdf (accessed July 2012).

Zeithaml, V.A. (1988), “Consumer perceptions of price, quality, and value: a means-end model andsynthesis of evidence”, Journal of Marketing, Vol. 52 No. 3, pp. 2-22.

Zeithaml, V.A. and Bitner, M.J. (1996), Services Marketing, McGraw-Hill, Singapore.

Zizzo, D.J. and Oswald, A. (2001), Are People Willing to Pay to Reduce Others’ Incomes?Department of Economics, University of Oxford, Oxford.

Corresponding authorDavid J. Edwards can be contacted at: [email protected]

To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: [email protected] visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints

378

SS30,4