The hidden logic of candidate selection for Chilean parliamentary elections

21
The Hidden Logic of Candidate Selection for Chilean Parliamentary Elections Author(s): Peter Siavelis Source: Comparative Politics, Vol. 34, No. 4 (Jul., 2002), pp. 419-438 Published by: Ph.D. Program in Political Science of the City University of New York Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4146946 Accessed: 07/12/2009 11:13 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=phd. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Ph.D. Program in Political Science of the City University of New York is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Comparative Politics. http://www.jstor.org

Transcript of The hidden logic of candidate selection for Chilean parliamentary elections

The Hidden Logic of Candidate Selection for Chilean Parliamentary ElectionsAuthor(s): Peter SiavelisSource: Comparative Politics, Vol. 34, No. 4 (Jul., 2002), pp. 419-438Published by: Ph.D. Program in Political Science of the City University of New YorkStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4146946Accessed: 07/12/2009 11:13

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available athttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unlessyou have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and youmay use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained athttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=phd.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printedpage of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range ofcontent in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new formsof scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

Ph.D. Program in Political Science of the City University of New York is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize,preserve and extend access to Comparative Politics.

http://www.jstor.org

The Hidden Logic of Candidate Selection for Chilean Parliamentary Elections

Peter Siavelis

The political consequences of Chile's two member district (binominal) parliamentary electoral system have been the subject of much academic and political debate.' Most

analyses of the electoral formula have focused on its consequences for the country's party system.2 Nonetheless, little has been written on how the system affects parlia- mentary candidate selection and electoral list composition.

The process of candidate selection is little understood by Chileans and students of Chilean politics alike. Very little has been written on internal party processes in Chile or in Latin America generally. In addition, most studies of candidate selection focus on European parliamentary governments or the United States and are less rele- vant to Latin America's predominantly multiparty, presidential systems.

This article makes some preliminary generalizations concerning the process of par- liamentary candidate selection in Chile. It sets out the context of electoral reform and its connection to candidate selection and goes on to suggest some of the impediments to

understanding the process in Chile. It then explores the actual mechanisms of candidate selection for legislative elections on three interrelated, yet analytically distinct, levels. First, it suggests what makes candidates attractive to political parties and analyzes how

parties choose candidates. Second, it explores the rationale of party elites in forming pacts and coalitions and discusses the most important variables that determine which of the subpacts' constituent parties are awarded candidacies in which districts. Third, it

analyzes the incentives that shape candidate selection within major coalitions and the

way these coalitions determine the composition of national lists. It establishes generally applicable rules that govern candidate selection within coalitions and provides a schematic diagram of these rules. The final section provides evidence of these rules

through empirical discussion of the candidate selection process, underscoring some of the paradoxes in candidate choice produced by this unique electoral system.

Contrary to simplistic assumptions concerning the desire of parties and coalitions to maximize votes, a much more complex constellation of variables influences where and with which coalition partners candidates run. Leaders attempt to achieve a series of discrete objectives, many of which are contradictory and some of which are not

particularly well thought out in terms of their political consequences. Maximizing

419

Comparative Politics July 2002

electoral advantage is a desired end for parties, but often politicians must settle for less in order to take care of other goals related to subpact alliances, national coali- tions, and presidential candidacies. Moreover, national coalitions may place candi- dates in districts even though different combinations of candidates would often bet- ter maximize the total coalition vote in the districts. The sum interaction of different sets of groups, subgroups, and individual leaders in simultaneously dealing with

challenges emerging on all of these levels determines who runs where, and under what circumstances, in Chilean parliamentary elections.

Democratization and Electoral Engineering in Chile

For most of its democratic history Chile employed a permissive, multimember dis- trict proportional representation (PR) system for house of deputies and senate elec- tions. Following an almost seventeen-year interregnum of authoritarian rule led by General Augusto Pinochet, military authorities imposed a series of constitutional and electoral changes. These reforms were aimed at party system transformation, in an effort to remedy what military authorities perceived as the unhealthy nature of polar- ized and ideological party competition during the country's long experience with

democracy. The most important of these reforms was the adoption of an electoral formula with two member districts, or a binominal system. The electoral formula was designed both to temper the negative consequences of the often fractious and ideological party system and to provide an advantage for the parties of the right.3 Reformers also hoped the system would contribute to the military's long-standing goal of eradicating the left by marginalizing it electorally.

Military reformers assumed that a reduction in district magnitude would lead to a reduction in the number of parties and moderate competition. Relying on theoretical assumptions concerning the reductive effect of small magnitude systems, they hoped the electoral formula would lead to the consolidation of moderate multipartism and at best to the formation of a two party system.4

The binominal electoral law provides that each party or electoral alliance can pre- sent two candidates for election to the chamber of deputies in each of the country's sixty electoral districts. The binominal system is also employed for senate elections, within nineteen circunscripciones (senatorial districts). Voters opt for a single candi- date from a series of two candidate open lists. The individual garnering a plurality wins the first seat in each district, but in practice that individual's coalition is unlike-

ly to win the second seat. Given the operational characteristics of the D'Hondt pro- portional representation system in two member districts, in order for a party or coali- tion to win both seats it must double the vote of the nearest competing list.

A concrete example clarifies this description and points to some of the system's

420

Peter Siavelis

counterintuitive results. The 1989 electoral returns from congressional district nineteen appear in Table 1. Although both Concertaci6n candidates individually received more votes and a higher percentage of votes than any of the Democracia y Progreso candi- dates, the rules of the electoral system mandated that the winners be Concertaci6n can- didate Mario Hamuy and Democracia y Progreso candidate Cristiain Leay, because the

Concertaci6n list did not double the total list vote of the Democracia y Progreso list. Thus, the electoral system establishes certain thresholds. In each district, to

obtain one seat a party or coalition must have at least 33.4 percent of the votes of the two largest parties or coalitions, and to win both seats it must win 66.7 percent. Of course, with different numbers of coalitions this dynamic and these thresholds change. Nonetheless, reformers were aware of the probable physiognomy of postau- thoritarian party competition and designed the system with a two list format in mind. Military reformers and their civilian allies doubted that the electoral list of the democratic opposition would be able to muster 66.7 percent of the vote across dis- tricts nationally. They also knew from public opinion data and the returns from the 1988 plebiscite that the right would likely garner 35-40 percent of the vote. The electoral formula would thus enable the right to win one of the two seats in each dis- trict (or 50 percent of the seats) with a little over 33 percent of the vote.

Such strong electoral thresholds also create some interesting incentives for both parliamentary list formation and electoral competition that will be explored in depth below. Briefly, given the high threshold to win two seats, sharing a list with a rela- tively stronger candidate in a district where the coalition can be expected to win under 66.7 percent of the vote is a recipe for defeat. Thus, candidates have incentives to seek pairings with weaker coalition partners in order to allow them to reach the 33 percent threshold but still be able to beat their list partner or extremely strong part-

Table 1 Election Results from District 19 Recoleta, Metropolitan Region of Santiago

Coalition Votes Percent*

Concertaci6n: Maria Hamuy (PDC) 41,876 34.0 Oscar Santilices (PPD) 39,549 32.1 Total 81,425 66.1

Democraciav Prosreso: Cristian Leay (UDI) 34,137 27.7 Mauricio Smok (RN) 7,647 6.2 Total 41,784 33.9

Source: Ministerio del Interior *This figure represents the percentage of the vote of the two largest coalitions. There were, of course, other small parties and lists, but the data is presented this way to make clear the significance of thresholds for the two largest parties.

421

Comparative Politics July 2002

ners in order to allow the electoral list to doblar (to win both seats in the district by crossing the 66.7 percent threshold).

What effect has the electoral system had on the party system? Has party competition been fundamentally transformed? Since the return of democracy party politics have been dominated by two multiparty coalitions: the center-left Concertaci6n de Partidos por la Democracia (the Concertacidn) and the center-right Union por Chile.5 This pattern of bipolar coalitional competition is unprecedented in terms of the durability and strength of the coalitions. Nonetheless, the party system also bears some striking resemblances to its preauthoritarian multiparty counterpart. Most evidence suggests that, despite the exis- tence of two broad coalitions, just as in the preauthoritarian period there are currently four or five significant political parties and none can claim majority status.6

Thus, the continued existence of an ingrained multiparty system is at odds with the majoritarian characteristics of the electoral system. Only two candidates can be

presented in each district from either major coalition, and coalitions must be formed in order for a party to be successful. At the same time four or five major parties and several minor parties continue to exist. Thus, party leaders are forced to engage in elaborate and time-consuming negotiations to assemble two candidate parliamentary lists. That these negotiations have succeeded in the last three parliamentary elections in 1989, 1993, and 1997 is a testament to both the tenacity of the country's party system and the negotiating ability of Chilean party leaders. How have candidate selection and coalition formation procedures been transformed in order to accommo- date the existing party system within the framework of electoral majoritarianism?

Impediments to Understanding Parliamentary Candidate Selection in Chile

Before discussing the actual process and incentives behind candidate selection in Chile, it is important to set out some of the impediments to understanding the process of list composition. First, though parties have coalesced into two major coalitions, there is also a number of subpacts within each coalition representing different ideological tenden- cies. The subpacts are clustered around major anchor parties, and their composition is discussed below. Thus, when assembling national candidate slates, parties must negoti- ate to ensure equity in the distribution of seats not only within the two major coalitions, but also among the various parties and subpacts within the coalition. Figure 1 provides a breakdown of the composition of coalitions, subpacts, and their anchor parties for the 1989, 1993, and 1997 elections and a key to party labels that is useful in understanding the discussion that follows. Second, the process of candidate selection has changed in each of the three parliamentary elections since the return of democracy. Thus, the sum of the designation processes is the total number of parties multiplied by three, produc- ing a confusing array of methods and possibilities. Finally, election slate composition

422

Peter Siavelis

has been shaped profoundly by the transition process and is itself in transition. After more than sixteen years of authoritarian rule there were few recent and concrete mea- sures of the actual level of support for parties prior to the first election. Parties had little hard data to employ as leverage in the negotiation process. With access to more infor- mation in recent elections, the mechanisms for candidate designation have become more formalized.

It is therefore difficult to nail down concrete rules. The Chilean expression, en el camino se arregla la carga, perhaps best describes changes in the processes regulat- ing both candidate selection and the composition of electoral lists.7 When met with pressures for increased democratization, or when threats to coalition maintenance have emerged, parties have adjusted candidate selection processes. How have Chile's two coalitions reconciled the demands of their member parties in order to cobble together two candidate lists in sixty districts every four years?8

The Composition Of Electoral Lists

In the simplest terms, the goal of any candidate in an election is to maximize votes. It follows that coalitions should seek to choose the two candidates capable of garner- ing the highest total number of votes in a particular district. Nonetheless, when pacts and subpacts also have goals distinct from those of individual candidates, important decision-making actors also seek to maximize votes of their subpacts and coalitions and to strengthen the coalition for presidential elections and future races. These con- siderations may lead and in practice have led to situations in which leaders do not always choose or have the capacity to place on a list the candidate they believe capa- ble of garnering the highest number of votes in a particular district.

There are three levels on which the most important decisions determining candidate choice are made. First, there is the difficult process of internal decision making within individual parties. Second, negotiations take place within each of the subpacts to deter- mine the number of candidates that each will have on larger coalition lists (and the number of slates that each anchor party will cede to smaller parties). Third, each nation- al coalition engages in internal bargaining to determine which candidates from which subpacts and parties will run in each district. These processes are connected and often occur simultaneously. They are separated here only for analytical purposes.

Candidate Selection by Individual Parties

In preauthoritarian Chile candidate selection was controlled almost entirely by party elites, though its large magnitude open list system did provide the voter more control

423

Comparative Politics July 2002

Figure 1 Coalitions, Subpacts, and Parties in Chilean Parliamentary Elections, 1989, 1993, 1997

Center-Left 1989

Coalition Concertaci6n

Subpact PDC* PS-PPD V V

PR, SD, PAC IC, PH, PV, IND

1993

Coalition Concertaci6n

Subpact PDC PS-PPD V V

PR, SD, PAC, IND PDI. IND

1997

Coalition Concertaci6n

Subpact PDC PS-PPD V V

RSD, IND IND

Center-Right 1909

Coalition Democracia y Progreso

Subpact RN UD V V

IND IND

1993

Coalitlon Uni6n por el Progreso

Subpact RN UCC UDI V V

IND PN, PDS, IND

1997

Coalition Uni6n por Chile

Subpact RN

UDI V V

IND PDS, IND *ANCHOR PARTIES IN BOLD PARTY KEY: IC-- Izquierda Cristiana (Christian Left), INO-tndependents Associated with Sub-pacts, PAC--Partido Alianza de Centro (Center Atiance Party), PDC--Partido Democr&ta Crstiano (Christian Democratic Party), PDI-Partido Democrtico de Izquierda (Democratic Party of the Left), PH-- Partido Humanista (Humanist Party) PDS-Partido del Sur (Party of the South). PN--Partido Nacional, PR--Partido Radical (Radical Party), PV-Partido Verde (Green Party),SD-Social Democracia (Social Democracy), RN--Renovacibn Nacional (National Renewal), RSD-- Radical Socialdemocrata. UCC.-Unt6n de Centro Centro (Center Center Union), UDI-UniCn Democritica Independiente (independent Democratic Union)

424

Peter Siavelis

over ultimate candidate selection. In postauthoritarian Chile there has been an effort to decentralize and democratize candidate selection processes in the overall spirit of democratization. However, in most parties elites still exercise de facto control.

Article 19, number 15 of the Chilean constitution states that party "by-laws must provide for norms ensuring effective internal democracy within political parties," though nothing is said concerning candidate selection per se. Expanding on these guidelines, however, the Ley Orgdnica de Partidos Politicos (Organic Law of Political Parties, Law 18603) sets rules for the selection of candidates. It states: "The statutes of political parties will contain guidelines maintaining that the designation of and support for Deputy and Senate candidates will be made by the National Party Council [Consejo General], as proposed by the Regional Council [Consejo Regional]."9 How do parties act within these general legal guidelines?

In the major parties central committees meet with large lists of potential candi- dates paired with their districts. Parties attempt to put forth the candidate with the best "packaging" who can simultaneously appeal to party bases and the regional and national councils. Each candidate is discussed in turn until a final list of between sixty and 120 candidates is determined, taking into account the recommendations of regional councils. The size of the list is determined by the party's estimation of its overall strength, negotiating strategy, and the number of slates the party expects. By this time parties are usually aware of the approximate number and location of dis- tricts in which they will run (the process of determining this number is discussed below). Candidates are also ranked in terms of how willing the party is to cede their slates in negotiations with other parties (this ranking is, of course, confidential). In minor parties a smaller list of candidates is assembled, and leaders discuss negotiat- ing strategies to best place their candidates on major lists.

Parties then move to internal party consultations to determine the ultimate lists of candidates. The few academic studies of candidate selection suggest that there are two extremes in the locus of control.10 On one extreme is the simple selection of candidates by the party leader alone, and, on the other, the selection of candidates by registered party members or even party supporters. In most cases power lies at a point between these extremes, involving some pattern of party constituency consultation. Chile is no exception to this generalization, though parties differ in the extent of party activist par- ticipation. Popular participation was almost nonexistent for the 1989 election, when par- ties had little time, information, or bargaining leverage to provide formalized structures for candidate selection. Party elites simply decided who would run where and against whom. The process of candidate selection has become more open and democratic across the party spectrum with each subsequent election. By 1997 each of the anchor parties had instituted some form of party activist primary.

However, the process is not simply in the hands of party activists. In practice, an almost natural consensus emerges in most parties. The regional councils recognize candidates who the national councils feel have the greatest potential to win and often

425

Comparative Politics July 2002

support them. Activists generally turn out for the candidate preferred by the national party because that candidate is likely to fare better in the general election with the support of party elites. In addition, in most parties central committees and/or nation- al councils propose the initial lists of candidates, in essence setting out the terms of debate for activists and the regional councils." Where there is no opposition to a candidate, primaries are not held. In a system in which national party councils are so powerful, a good many candidatures are in effect determined by party elites.

Local activists who fail to elect the candidate favored by party leaders usually have the final word, though in some cases national councils have overturned the results of party primaries. Also, if parties decide to cede a slate to another party later in negotiations in the interests of coalition unity, the decision of local activists is overridden. Such overriding is common, often leading to disgruntled candidates who feel like sacrificial lambs on the altar of coalition unity.

What variables enhance the attractiveness of potential parliamentary candidates for the national and regional party councils? As is the case in most well-institutional- ized party systems, there is some degree of regularity in party representation in con- gress, and incumbency is a strong predictor of renomination.12 For the 1993 and 1997 elections 74 percent of deputies were renominated, either in their own district, in another district, or for the senate. Of those renominated, 81.5 percent were reelect- ed.13 Interviews with leaders across the party spectrum confirmed that incumbents are understood to have the right to renomination, barring extreme lack of party disci- pline.

In addition, nationally known candidates are attractive to both national party councils and regional councils. A former minister or a prominent party leader is more influential in parliament, a perceived benefit to regional party councils that are interested in the ability of deputies to provide pork. This preference was very clear in the Fifth Senatorial District (Cordillera), where the former minister of economy, Carlos Ominami, easily obtained the nomination of the Socialist Party (beating Isabel Allende, the former president's niece) in a competitive internal election and went on to win a senate seat in 1993.

Finally, as the above reference suggests (and despite Allende's loss), in Chile fam- ily name enhances the attractiveness of candidates. Having the right apellido (sur- name) can help significantly in the quest for a parliamentary candidacy. The senate in the 1993-1997 period contained an Alessandri, two Freis, a Letelier, and two Zaldivars, all traditionally important names in Chilean politics. Similarly, one Allende, two Alessandris, and two Leteliers count among the membership of the house of deputies for the 1997-2001 period.

Once each party determines a preliminary slate of candidates, it must be recon- ciled with the overall agreement worked out by subpacts and national coalitions. This process is usually completed by the time internal party decision-making processes are concluded.

426

Peter Siavelis

Subpact Negotiation

The entire process of candidate selection becomes much more complicated once it ceases to be a single party affair. As noted, parties with an ideological bond, yet with

programmatic differences, have joined in Chile to form subpacts (see Figure 1 for a

breakdown). For example, the PDC leads a subpact composed of center parties with- in the Concertacirn. The parties of the left within the Concertacion have formed a second subpact led jointly by the PS and the PPD. Both parties have similar roots within the traditional Chilean Socialist Party. Nonetheless, continued programmatic, ideological, and personal divisions prevented their fusion during the transition

process. They have, however, formed a subpact in an effort to provide a unified party voice on the left. The center-right Uni6n por el Progreso alliance is also made up of two subpacts, anchored by each of the two major parties of the right (RN and UDI).

There is a great deal of evidence that the binominal system has not succeeded in

reducing the number of small but historically and politically significant parties.14 However, rather than simply fuse with larger parties, these parties have also joined one of the subpacts with which they have some ideological affinity. The Radical

Party, the Social Democratic Party, the Green Party, and others have each joined one of the two subpacts within the Concertacirn. Because of the exclusionary character- istics of the electoral system, small parties know that the only way to win legislative seats is to negotiate to join a larger coalition.

What incentives do larger parties have to allow smaller parties on board? Large parties are willing to share in the allocation of a small number of electoral slates in

exchange for the extra anticipated votes that can help electoral alliances cross one of the crucial thresholds. Equally important, allowing a small party into the coalitional fold helps to avoid additional small party presidential candidacies that can erode

support for major coalition presidential candidates. The importance of unified presi- dential candidacies was driven home by the razor-thin plurality received by Socialist President Ricardo Lagos in the 1999 first round election, where the distance separat- ing the top two polling candidates was one-half of one percent.

Subpacts must now decide how many candidates will be allocated to each party before going into negotiations for the national coalition list. The behavioral dynamic of each party in subpact negotiations varies according to party size. For example, because the subpact of the left within the Concertacirn includes two major parties (the PS and PPD) with about an equal level of national support, each begins with the

assumption that it should have one-half of the subpact's allocation of seats. The par- ties then use public opinion data and the returns from municipal elections to attempt to increase their influence and to win more election slates, before entering into nego- tiations with the subpact of the center to form Concertaci6n's electoral lists.

Smaller parties also use the potential votes that they can add to a subpact to extract as many seats as possible from subpact anchor parties. For example, in prepa-

427

Comparative Politics July 2002

ration for the 1997 elections the small PRSD effectively declared its free agency, informing both the PS-PPD and the Christian Democratic subpacts that it would join with the one that offered it the best deal in terms of candidacies. Smaller parties can, thus, use their leverage (often quite well, especially in the case of the Radical Party) to create bidding wars among larger parties that lead subpacts.ls Nonetheless, this game is dangerous; bidding will go only so high before the costs of acceding to the demands of a particular party exceed the electoral benefits it can provide.

Coalition List Formulation

While each of the individual parties chooses candidates and subpacts hammer out preliminary list proposals, a third and simultaneous process is taking place. Representatives from each subpact negotiate to determine the number of party slates that each will receive on national coalition lists. This process is characterized by elite negotiations carried on both within and outside of formal party and alliance struc- tures.16 While many aspects of the Concertaci6n alliance are highly structured, the process of candidate selection between the major parties is not. Nor is the process any more structured on the center-right. Across the party spectrum high-level party activists and their electoral experts participate in the negotiations, though final agreements must be approved by each of the parties' national councils.

At this phase of the candidate selection process, the most complex and pressing questions for the coalitions are the following. How will seats be divided between the major subpacts in each coalition? How many seats will be ceded to smaller subpact partners? How will candidacies be distributed in individual districts?

The Four Rules of Intracoalitional Candidate Selection The answers to these questions are fundamentally conditioned by the existence of the electoral thresholds discussed above. All parties and subpacts realize that it is very difficult for coalitions to gain a two seat victory in a particular district. To do so entails garnering a total list vote of over 66 percent. Thus, it is likely that at least one of the two candidates on a particular coalition slate will lose. The key to victory, then, is for subpacts and par- ties to place their candidates on the same list either with an extremely strong candi- date (who will help achieve the unlikely 66 percent two seat victory) or a weak can- didate (who will help pass the 33 percent threshold but not outpoll their candidate). This basic reality conditions both the alliance formation process and the placement of candidates. Interviews with leaders charged with candidate selection in every major political party in 1999 and 2000 and empirical examples suggest a consistent logic in the candidate selection process that can be boiled down to at least four gen- eral rules. Though not an exhaustive list, these rules are the most important ones guiding subpact behavior in intracoalitional list formation. For the purposes of the

428

Peter Siavelis

discussion, rank refers to national levels of support based on public opinion data and support in previous elections. An anchor party is the largest party around which the subpact coalesces (the PDC and PS/PPD in the Concertaci6n and RN and UDI in the Union por Chile), and a minor party is any other smaller subpact partner.17

Rule 1 The anchor party within first ranked subpacts will seek at least one seat in each district, though it may surrender a small number of seats to minor subpact partners in the interests of coalition maintenance and unified presidential candidacies.

Rule 2 The anchor party in second-ranked subpacts will seek to be placed (or negotiate into) districts where anchor parties of the first-ranked subpact are not running, and will ideally secure both of the slates in the district or be paired with a candidate from a minor party.

Rule 3 The anchor party in second-ranked subpacts that is forced to share a list with an anchor party from the first-ranked subpact will seek coalition partners with one of two profiles: an extremely weak candidate that its candidate can beat or a very strong candi- date that will give the coalition sufficient votes to doblar (win both seats in the district) and carry its candidate over the top.

Rule 4 Minor parties in each subpact and parties of third and lower ranked subpacts will also seek to pair with very weak or very strong list partners, but success in doing so is tied to their relative size and their potential contribution to the coalition's total vote and impact on presidential elections.

However, empirical evidence also suggests an additional crucial variable that affects the rules of intracoalitional bargaining: the relative strength of major subpacts and parties within them. For example, anchor parties in subpacts act differently depending on whether or not the subpact they lead enjoys a level of support similar to other major subpacts in their coalition. Again, because of the electoral system's thresholds two subpacts will be willing to divide seats equally in a situation where they enjoy relatively the same level of support throughout the country. However, if a subpact consistently trails another nationwide, it will be loathe simply to divide dis- tricts with a strong subpact, as this division is a recipe for defeat across districts nationally. The strategic preference ordering of parties is thus also affected by the relative strength of their subpact. Figures 2 and 3 systematize these choices. They apply the four rules of intracoalitional bargaining and show variations in the prefer- ence ordering of parties depending on the relative strength of their subpact. Figure 2 represents these choices in intracoalitional bargaining where the two major subpacts have relative parity in terms of support, while Figure 3 demonstrates the incentives of the system where there is disparity in the level of support for the two subpacts in a coalition. Numbers within the figures represent the rank order of preferences for parties. Figures 2 and 3 demonstrate that, when subpacts have different levels of sup-

429

Comparative Politics July 2002

Figure 2 Party Preferences for Intracoalition Negotiation in a Situation of Subpact Parity (First and Second Ranked Subpacts Roughly Equal in Support)

Preference Ranking

Anchor Parties in Both Ist Divide candidate slates evenly between anchorparties

Subpacts2nd• Surrender equal number of slates to small parties in respective sub-pact for coalition unity

Preference Ranking

ist Seek candidates of minor parties as partners

Minor Parties in Both Subpacts And All Parties in 2nd Seek very weak candidates fronm anchor party in either Third and Lower Ranked sub-pact as partners Sub-pacts

3rd Seek very strong anchor party partners with the potential to carry two seats (doblar)

port, the preference ordering of parties within subpacts changes and the nature of intracoalitional bargaining is likely to be different.

The Four Rules of Candidate Selection and Preference Rankings in Practice The candidate selection process in the first three postauthoritarian elections sheds light on how these general rules function in practice. For the first postauthoritarian democratic election in 1989 the candidate selection process was complicated by an essentially blind negotiation, because of the lack of any recent public opinion polls or electoral returns on which parties could base their projections of support. At the same time, the stakes were extremely high, because the distribution of candidacies would in part determine how much national support a party would receive in the elections and thus would influ- ence both the relative power of parties and candidate choices made in future races.

In the Concertaci6n parties quickly realized the absurd competitive dynamic of the system and understood that two seat victories were unlikely. Nonetheless, run- ning separate lists on the center and the left would have both handed the right a vic- tory and diminished the probability of a Concertaci6n president. The urgency of the situation and the overall goal of defeating candidates tied to the previous government produced a spirit of give and take that would not be present in 1993 and 1997 and that was absent on the center-right during all three elections.

The process of list formation was not completely without conflict in the

Concertaci6n. As the negotiating process began, the parties of the left (PS-PPD) were in a strong position to extract concessions from the Christian Democrats and their subpact (PDC-PR-SD-PAC). Nonetheless, the emergence of a parallel coalition on the Left (Partido Amplio de la Izquierda Socialista, PAIS) composed of parties that refused to participate in the Concertaci6n (including the Communists and dissi- dent Socialists) complicated the bargaining situation. On the one hand, the splinter-

430

Peter Siavelis

Figure 3 Party Preferences for Intracoalitional Negotiation in a Situation of Subpact Disparity (First and Second Ranked Parties with Differential Levels of Support)

Preference Ranking

lst Seek a minimum of one seat in each district; force Anchor Party in First Ranked coalition partner to code seats Sub-pact

2nd Surrender limited slates to small parties in sub-pact for coalition unity, with coalition partner also ceding seats

Preference Ranking

st Seek to negotiate some two slate districts to avoid competition with anchor party in first ranked sub-pact.

Anchor Party in Second 2nd Seek very weak partners from first ranked sub-pact Ranked Sub-pact

Seek very strong partners fromn first-ranked sub-pact 3rd with potential to carry two seats (doblar)

Preference Rankiag

Seek candidates of minor parties as partners Minor Parties in Both

Third and Lowelr Ranked s in Seek very weak partners of an anchor party in either

Sub-pacts sub-pact

3rd Seek very strong patters from an anchor party in first or second ranked sub-pact with the potential to carry two seats (doblar)

ing of the left provided the PDC with ammunition to contend that the sector had indeed divided and should thus be entitled to fewer seats on the Concertaci6n list. On the other hand, the PDC had to hold out the promise of providing the left with sufficient seats to stem the possibility of a complete breakdown of the Concertaci6n, with the moderate left jumping the coalitional ship to join the PAIS list. In the worst

case, the left would have run a separate presidential candidate.

Ultimately the parties of the Concertaci6n agreed that districts would be shared

equally between the subpacts of the left and center, with some minor adjustments on the basis of each subpact's willingness to accommodate smaller parties. There was also a tacit agreement between the PS-PPD subpact, the PDC subpact, and the PAIS. The Concertaci6n would divide candidacies evenly between its two subpacts except where the PAIS was fielding a list. In those districts, two candidates of the center would be fielded in order to avoid dividing support on the left. Moreover, the PAIS list agreed to support Concertaci6n candidates where it had no competing list. The

PDC, as the subpact anchor party, took advantage of the allocation of two seats to it in some districts to distribute the second to its minor party partners to satisfy them. Even so, the PDC knew that its higher level of national support would likely guaran-

431

Comparative Politics July 2002

tee victory in the districts where its candidates were matched with small parties of the subpact.

With the passage of time and elections and the evaporation of the forced consen- sus produced by the democratic transition, the candidate selection process has become less harmonious and more complex. In 1993 the leaders of the Concertacidn had information from two elections on which to base negotiations. The successful performance of the PDC in the 1989 congressional and 1992 municipal races gave it additional negotiating weight.

Ultimately in 1993 the Concertaci6n agreed upon an arrangement similar to that of 1989. The PS-PPD and Christian Democratic subpacts agreed again to split the list but as in 1989 to make a few minor adjustments to it. The PDC pointed to its successful performance in government and elections as rationale for an increased number of parliamentary candidacies. The PS-PPD subpact agreed to cede five dis- tricts to the Christian Democratic subpact, if the party would agree to use these five seats and an additional five seats of its own to field minor party candidates. Thus, the Christian Democrats would run fifty-five candidates, their smaller subpact list partners (the PR, SD and PAC) would run ten, and the PS-PPD would run fifty-five, for a total of 120.18 After determining the overall number of seats for allocation to the subpacts, each undertook a series of adjustments that ultimately transferred a few more seats to minor parties.19

An additional important variable factored into list composition is the combination of candidates on each individual district list. Because the electoral system's threshold makes it so difficult to doblar, it is clear to both coalitions that in most districts one candidate will win and one candidate will lose. (In 1989 the Concertaci6n took both seats in only eleven of 120 districts, and the center-right failed to do so in any dis- trict. In both 1993 and 1997 the Concertaci6n garnered eleven two-seat victories, and the parties of the center-right one).

This situation has led to suggestions in the press and in popular discussions of the electoral system that coalitions would be well advised to pursue a weak-strong strat- egy, that is, to run a candidate capable of garnering enough votes to pass the first electoral threshold and to match this candidate with a weaker one whose votes will simply ensure that the first candidate passes the threshold but who has little possibil- ity of winning a seat. While logical, there is little evidence that this strategy is pur- sued. If single parties were putting together individual lists, there might be more of an incentive to pair weak candidates with strong ones, especially in districts where parties can not expect to approach the 66 percent threshold. There is also a grain of truth to this suggested logic, in that alliances may avoid running two extremely pop- ular candidates in the same district to avoid wasting votes.20 However, one can not speak of a generalized strategy. The pairing of candidates depends on the importance of the district to the party (two very strong candidates may be paired in Santiago, Valparaiso, and Concepci6n for example), the expected vote in the district, any

432

Peter Siavelis

regional ties candidates might have to the constituency, and the logic of coalition negotiation itself.

Party leaders also seek to pair candidates who will not engage in internecine con- flict. In situations where the vote expected by two members of a coalition is relative- ly close, there is an incentive to engage in intralist competition. Such competition is rare; candidates prefer cooperation to confrontation in campaigning.21 However, can- nibalistic competition occurs. It was quite obvious in the 1989 elections in one important Santiago district, where RN candidate Sebastian Pifiera was often publicly at odds with the UDI's Herm6genes Perez de Arce, his presumed list partner.

Intralist competition is not a simple matter of preference but rather depends on a few determining variables. If candidates go into the election relatively close in public opinion polls, intralist competition is more likely. It is especially likely when it appears that only one of the candidates from the list will be elected. Even in districts where there are sufficient votes to doblar, receiving the primera mayoria (first majority) enhances a candidate's attractiveness and bargaining power in future elec- tions. Nonetheless, candidates often engage in a different game of veiled electoral cannibalism by suggesting their list partner has sufficient votes and that voters should attempt to provide the entire coalition ticket with a "balanced victory."

The combination of candidates on each list is also important in other ways. In the 1993 elections, the Unidn por el Progreso performed best in districts where it ran a candidate from each of the anchor parties of its two major subpacts (RN-UDI), rather than two candidates from the same party or a representative of one anchor party matched with an independent. In the sixteen districts where candidates of the two anchor parties ran, they received 43.4 percent of the overall vote (6.8 percent higher than they received nationally and 7.9 percent higher than the presidential can- didates of the right received in these districts). Similarly, on the center-left in dis- tricts where members of the Social Democrats (SD) and Radical Parties (PR) were paired with the PS-PPD candidates, the smaller parties were unsuccessful in winning seats. In the eleven districts with this combination, there was an average of 18.7 per- cent separating the vote of the SD-PR candidates and the PS-PPD candidates.22 Lists composed of major anchor parties appear more successful than those in which a smaller minor party is a member.23 Nonetheless, small parties still make it onto national coalition lists, even though lists made up of only major anchor party candi- dates would better maximize total list vote in individual districts. In essence, large parties pay the price of lower national vote totals for the benefit of coalition mainte- nance and unified presidential candidacies.

Subpact Size and the Dynamics of List Competition Perhaps more important than these variables, the binominal system also produces a particular logic of negoti- ation, depending on the relative size of the subpacts (with size understood as nation- al levels of support). This logic affects both negotiations and the nature of trade-offs

433

Comparative Politics July 2002

between different goals. If the two subpacts in the same coalition are about the same size, seat negotiations are much less conflictual. If both can expect to obtain about 50 percent of the vote, coalitions will seek to place one candidate from a major party in each subpact in every district and simply allow voters to decide. However, if one major subpact is at or about 60 percent and the other can count on about 40 percent of the coalition vote, the latter could expect to lose in every district. The name of the game for second place subpacts in these situations is to get candidates from popular parties of the largest subpact off their lists, that is, to be paired on coalition lists with weaker parties. Thus, small parties not only negotiate to seek candidatures on major lists; they also seek to run on lists with other smaller as opposed to major parties.

This logic is clear in the evolution of party competition on the right across elec- tions.24 In 1989 the two major subpacts of the right, led by the RN and UDI, agreed simply to divide lists and present one candidate from each subpact. They did so pri- marily because of the uncertainty of each party's level of support and because of the UDI's youthfulness as a party and lack of established structures of political recruit- ment (it actually had difficulty in identifying candidates to fill the slots on every electoral list). In the 1989 election it became clear that the RN had achieved predom- inance on the right. In the elections for the chamber the RN garnered 18.3 percent of the vote to the UDI's 9.8 percent.25 This result gave the RN the upper hand going into negotiations for the following election.

Nonetheless, negotiations for the 1993 election were complicated by the entry of a new player on the right. The then relatively new UCC (Union del Centro Centro) gar- nered roughly 7 percent of the vote in the 1992 municipal elections and was perceived to have the capacity to play a spoiler role on the right by stealing votes from the center- right coalition and pulling it below the 33 percent electoral threshold.26 There was also an incipient UCC presidential candidacy that would undermine the right's performance in the presidential election. The RN and UDI recognized the damage that an additional presidential candidacy on the right would cause. They also knew that they might need the UCC to raise the coalition's overall list totals to pass crucial thresholds nationally. The UCC began to market itself as a forceful option that could add significantly to the national vote totals of the right's parliamentary lists.

Because of the RN's predominance on the right, its leaders contended that it would be appropriate to award one slate to the RN subpact in each district and let the UCC and UDI subpacts negotiate to split the remaining seats between themselves. Both parties objected. Given the RN's electoral dominance, both other parties' candidates would lose if paired with RN candidates. Nonetheless, the RN also knew that without the UDI and UCC and with a divided right its chances of consistently passing elec- toral thresholds would be substantially undermined. The UCC thus focused its ener- gies on getting Renovacirn candidates off particular lists in order to permit competi- tion between the UCC and the UDI or between two candidates of the UCC. Francisco Javier Errizuriz, president of the UCC, contacted leaders of the Renovacidn Nacional

434

Peter Siavelis

directly to engage in negotiations. Erraizuriz contended that the UCC should be "paid" for the 7 percent it was contributing to the overall strength of the right and requested that the party be given eleven districts in which UCC candidates would compete only against each other. Leaders of the Renovacion Nacional agreed that Erraizuriz was perhaps entitled to this number of slates, but certainly not paired together in the com- bination he requested. Summing up the logic that prevails for small parties paired with larger ones, Errizuriz replied: "Don't give me slates; I am asking for seats."27 Indeed, Errizuriz was correct. Ultimately the UCC garnered twenty-one slates. However, UCC leaders convinced the RN and UDI subpacts to cede them both slates in only three districts. The two seats that the UCC ultimately won were from these districts. The party's other nineteen candidates went down to defeat.

Clearly, then, the relative size and support for parties determine how important the list partner is. The right after the 1993 elections makes this point even clearer. The UCC's dismal showing of 3.2 percent and victory in only two districts in 1993 made it much less of a player in 1997. However, the UDI subpact increased its national share of the vote to 12.1 percent in the 1993 elections (despite the fact that the candidate selection process worked against it). At the same time, the RN sub- pact's share of the vote dropped to 16.1 percent, making negotiations much less complex. Because a significant percentage of the vote shifted to the UDI from the RN and the two parties were neck and neck in the polls, they simply split the seats equally between their two subpacts in 1997. This agreement was possible because the leverage each had in negotiations was equalized by their balanced level of national support.

These dynamics are not limited to the right. A similar equilibration of support between the left and center subpacts also made negotiations for the 1997 elections in the

Concertaci6n less complex. While the Christian Democrats far outdistanced the left in the first elections following authoritarian rule, the gap between the two sectors gradual- ly closed; the combined left ultimately garnered 23.7 percent and the Christian Democrats 22.3 percent of the vote in 1993. Negotiations in 1997 were facilitated by the proximity in the level of support for the two subpacts, and a general agreement to divide candidacies was reached. With roughly equal levels of support between major subpacts, the binominal system creates less complex incentives for negotiation.

Conclusions and Perspectives on Candidate Selection in Latin America

The Chilean binominal electoral system helps to produce a process of candidate selection based on several sets of overlapping, complex, and often contradictory incentives. Party elites attempt simultaneously to underwrite their parties' electoral success and to guarantee the cohesion of the coalitions that the binominal system obliges and that is also essential to the success of individual parties.

435

Comparative Politics July 2002

There are also certain paradoxes of competition. At the level of individual compe- tition the most obvious paradox is that the potentially highest-polling candidates are often not placed on electoral lists. A strong candidate may be left by the wayside to be replaced by a weaker minor party candidate in order to enhance subpact or coali- tion unity. Also paradoxical is the candidates' potentially different desired outcomes in terms of their coalition list partner. They want to run in a district with either a very strong or a very weak candidate. Obviously, choosing the two strongest candi- dates would maximize coalition vote. However, individual candidates and subpacts sometimes have a strong incentive to push for a weak list partner.

At the coalition level candidates who are not the highest potential vote-getters may also be selected. Coalitions may be willing to cede seats in particular districts in order to assure that they can reach the thresholds established by the system national- ly. At times, a coalition may also end up receiving fewer votes in some districts than it might have won with a different set of candidates. A party capable of garnering 7 percent of the national vote may seem attractive as a coalition partner in terms of maximizing the overall list vote across districts nationally. However, candidates from parties with this level of support will often do little to attract enough additional votes to an individual district list to make a difference. Coalitions sacrifice the slate to have an additional element of support that can put them over the threshold in other districts where the inclusion of a minor party may increase list vote totals incremen- tally enough to result in victory for the coalition. Coalitions also seek to avoid sepa- rate parliamentary lists or presidential candidacies that can undermine support for the coalition across districts nationwide and in presidential elections.

Moreover, under the rules outlined above, very often two minor parties of a coali- tion are placed on the same list to compete with each other since both resist compet- ing with a major anchor party. Minor parties or lower polling parties will demand two candidate lists of their own parties or a pairing with a minor party as the requi- site price for joining a coalition. Thus, in these districts the overall list vote is likely to be much lower than it might be if two candidates from major parties were running together. However, once again, the coalition is willing to pay this price for unity.

While other countries are unlikely to adopt a binominal system, Chile provides wider theoretical insights into how strategically complex electoral systems affect processes of candidate selection and elections. The analysis provides support for a normative argument against strategically complex electoral systems in terms of rep- resentative capacity. First, strategically complex electoral systems may produce potentially negative, counterintuitive results. Party elites often have incentives to put together electoral lists that may not contain the most popular candidates. In turn, vot- ers face an unpredictable system; they are uncertain whether their vote will con- tribute to the election of their preferred candidate or his or her list partner. In essence, the complexity of the system increases the odds of strategic errors in list composition and in voting, with potentially frustrating consequences for party lead-

436

Peter Siavelis

ers, candidates, and voters. Second, strategically complex systems may militate against the opening up of the candidate selection processes because of the imperative to balance so delicately the interests of voters and parties against the overarching coalitional goal of seat maximization. The complexity of putting together winning electoral lists provides a disincentive for the democratization of candidate selection. Finally, rather than provide transparency and openness, the unpredictability of strate- gically complex systems and the elite driven candidate selection processes they can produce reduce the legitimacy of the electoral system and of democratic politics in general. Voters perceive that the ultimate victory in elections results from the strate- gic machinations of party elites, rather than an expression of the will of the people.

Electoral reform is proceeding apace across Latin America. While scholars have ana- lyzed the consequences of electoral reform for party systems, few have addressed how electoral reform has the potential to transform candidate selection processes. From the broadest perspective, electoral reform is likely to transform traditional forms of candi- date selection in ways that have a direct bearing on the representative capacity of democracy. Thus, the democratization of Latin America's political system depends not only on the structure of party systems as conditioned by different election methods, but also on the incentives for candidate selection that they help to produce.

NOTES

I am grateful for the comments and suggestions of Andres Allamand, Alejandro Foxley Tapia, and Scott Morgenstern. The William C. Archie Fund of Wake Forest University and the American Political Science Association Research Grant Program provided research support for this project.

1. Two member districts are uncommon, though they exist at the state level in the U.S. Their mechan- ical effects are discussed by Rein Taagepera, "The Effect of District Magnitude and Properties of Two Seat Districts," in Arend Lijphart and Bernard Grofman, eds., Choosing an Electoral System (New York: Praeger, 1984), pp. 1-102; and Gary Cox, "Electoral Equilibrium in Double Member Districts," Public Choice, 44 (1984), 443-51.

2. The party integrative and stabilizing tendencies of the electoral system are underscored by, among others, Eugenio Guzmin, "Reflexiones sobre el sistema binominal," Estudios Pdblicos, 51 (Winter 1993), 303-25; and Rhoda Rabkin, "Redemocratization, Electoral Engineering, and Party Strategies in Chile, 1989-1995," Comparative Political Studies, 29 (June 1996), 335-56. Those who are not convinced that the electoral system possesses these qualities include Peter Siavelis and Arturo Valenzuela, "Electoral Engineering and Democratic Stability: The Legacy of Authoritarian Rule in Chile," in Arend Lijphart and Carlos Waisman, eds., Institutional Design in New Democracies: Eastern Europe and Latin America (Boulder: Westview Press, 1996), pp. 77-100; J. Samuel Valenzuela and Timothy Scully, "Electoral Choices and the Party System in Chile: Continuities and Changes at the Recovery of Democracy," Comparative Politics, 29 (July 1997), 511-27; and Peter Siavelis, "Continuity and Change in the Chilean Party System: On the Transformational Effects of Electoral Reform," Comparative Political Studies, 30 (December 1997), 651-74.

3. See Siavelis and Valenzuela. 4. Reformers relied on Downs's median voter hypothesis as the logic that would produce centripetal

437

Comparative Politics July 2002

and bipolar party competition in Chile. However, as Magar, Rosenblum, and Samuels demonstrate, Downs based his analysis on single member districts, and the bipolar dynamic produced by magnitudes of two differs from that explored by Downs and may even encourage centrifugal competition. See Anthony Downs, An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: HarperCollins, 1957); and Eric Magar, Marc Rosenblum, and David Samuels, "On The Absence of Centripetal Incentives in Double Member Districts: The Case of Chile," Comparative Political Studies, 31 (December 1998), 714-39.

5. This alliance was known as Democracia y Progreso for the 1989 elections and Uni6n por el Progreso de Chile in 1993.

6. Siavelis and Valenzuela; Valenzuela and Scully; Siavelis. 7. "You readjust your load as you proceed down the road." 8. While other coalitions present candidates, these two garnered over 80 percent of the vote in the

1989, 1993, and 1997 elections. 9. National councils are composed of senators, deputies, and representatives elected by each regional

party council. 10. Michael Gallagher, "Introduction," in Michael Gallagher and Michael Marsh, Candidate Selection

in Comparative Perspective (London: Sage, 1988), p. 4. 11. These conclusions are based on interviews during 1999 and 2000 with leaders charged with list

composition in every major party and on anecdotal press accounts. 12. Scott Mainwaring and Timothy Scully, "Introduction," in Scott Mainwaring and Timothy Scully,

eds., Building Democratic Institutions: Party Systems in Latin America (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1985), p. 6.

13. John Carey, "Parties, Coalitions and the Chilean Congress in the 1990's," in Scott Morgenstern and Benito Nacif, eds., Legislatures and Democracy in Latin America (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, forthcoming).

14. Siavelis; Valenzuela and Scully. 15. The Radical Party secured more candidacies than its national level of support suggests that it

should have received. In 1993 the Radicals secured eleven of the 120 Concertaci6n slates (almost ten percent), and won only 3 percent of the vote nationally.

16. See "Las corrientes ocultas tras las negociaciones," La Segunda, Feb., 19, 1993, p. 13. 17. The PS and PPD are treated as a single anchor party for the purposes of this discussion (as would

other parties that agree on the overall number of subpact candidacies for each party before coalition-level negotiations).

18. For a complete breakdown of the Concertacidn's parties (there were other minor parties in addition to the eleven listed in Figure 2), see El Mercurio, May 21, 1989, p. C5.

19. The sixty-five PDC subpact candidacies were distributed as follows: forty-eight for the PDC, eleven for the PR, four for the SD, and two for associated independents. In the PS-PPD subpact they were distributed as follows: twenty-eight for the PS, twenty-five for the PPD, and two for independents. Data from the ministry of the interior, 1993. 20. See "Pifiera al Borde del Si," El Mercurio, Mar. 30, 1997, p. D1. 21. Rabkin, p. 346. 22. Auth, pp. 353-55. 23. An alternative explanation is that larger parties with more negotiating power reserved these dis-

tricts for themselves. 24. I am indebted to Andr6s Allamand for his insights on the evolution of competition on the right. 25. Servicio Electoral de Chile. 26. It is now the Uni6n del Centro Centro Progresista. 27. Interview with Andr6s Allamand, Washington, D.C., July 13, 1998.

438